Research Paper

Write a research paper that analyzes methods used to ethically manage teams and groups within organizations. In your research paper, be sure to include the following elements:

  • Distinguish between a group and a team.
  • Discuss ethical decision-making in team leadership that promotes social responsibility.
  • Discuss leadership styles and traits that are effective for successful management of groups and teams.
  • Include a discussion on any aspect of leadership covered in the course that was of particular interest to you. All topics do not need to be included; yet, followership, ethics, leadership styles, multicultural leadership, and conflicts of interest are all topics that have been studied, and any one (or more) that you found particularly interesting could be incorporated into the discussion.

Your research paper should be a minimum of three pages in length, not including the title and references pages. Utilize the CSU Online Library to locate a minimum of three sources to use as references that support your research paper. All sources used must be cited and referenced according to APA guidelines.

Don't use plagiarized sources. Get Your Custom Essay on
Research Paper
Just from $13/Page
Order Essay

Be sure to include the rubric elements from the guidelines below.

  • Your introduction should engage the reader and clearly present the thesis and a summary of the main points to clarify your point of view.
  • The review of the literature should present a critical analysis and synthesis of the existing research.
  • The discussion should reveal insightful analysis of research.
  • A summary should be present that reviews or summarizes key points and provides a smooth transition between sections.
  • The writing should be clear and concise with proper sentence structure, grammar, and punctuation, and it should be free from spelling errors.
  • The number of academically credible sources should meet the requirements and should be properly cited, per APA standards.

RESEARCH Open Access

Obstacles open the door — Negative
shocks can motivate individuals to focus on
opportunities
Jin Feng, Wenxia Zhou, Shuoyu Li and Mengyi Li*

* Correspondence: ellenli@ruc.edu.
cn
School of Labour and Human
Resources, Renmin University of
China, No.59 Zhongguancun Street,
Beijing 100872, China

  • Abstract
  • By responding to the call for research on negative career shocks and future time
    perspective, this study regarded internal social capital as a tool of resource retention
    which shifts attention to negative career shocks’ positive effects. We test a
    moderated mediation model which illustrates the effect of negative career shocks on
    focus on opportunities—positive dimension of occupational

    future time perspective.

  • Results
  • revealed that internal social capital acts as the mediator between negative
    career shocks and focus on opportunities, and organizational embeddedness
    moderats the mediation effect. The relationship is stronger when individuals are
    highly embedded in organizations.

    Keywords: Career shocks, Future time perspective, Focus on opportunities, Internal
    social capital,

    Organizational embeddedness

    “Whatever does not kill them makes them stronger. —— Friedrich Nietzsche”

    “Trouble is only opportunity in work clothes. —— Henry J. Kaiser”

    Recent career research has argued that career development is becoming more dynamic,

    complex, unpredictable and flexible (Vuori and Okkonen 2012; Baruch 2004). The

    increasingly complex and unpredictable nature of contemporary careers will be accom-

    panied by increased unpredictable career events such as layoffs, bankruptcy or family

    issues that may change individual’s career path. In research, these events are repre-

    sented by terms such as happenstance, serendipity, or chance events (Miller 1983;

    Betsworth and Hansen 1996; Bright et al. 2005; Akkermans et al. 2018). Hirschi (2010)

    indicates that such major events that happen in people’s lives have a significant impact

    on their career paths. Shocks (e.g. an important mentor or colleague’s departure or

    organizational change) have been shown to predict organizational turnover (Hom

    et al. 2017; Lee et al. 2017; Seibert et al. 2013), and better clarify why people leave

    or stay.

    Lee and Mitchell (1994) proposed career shock as a jarring event that evokes a per-

    son to pause and think about the meaning of their jobs and in turn, provokes some

    considerations of leaving their jobs. Recently, Akkermans et al. (2018) described career

    shock as a disruptive and extraordinary event. Shocks can be positive, neutral or

    © The Author(s). 2019 Open Access This article is distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International
    License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium,
    provided you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons license, and
    indicate if changes were made.

    Frontiers of Business
    Research in China

    Feng et al. Frontiers of Business Research in China (2020) 14:1
    https://doi.org/10.1186/s11782-019-0067-9

    http://crossmark.crossref.org/dialog/?doi=10.1186/s11782-019-0067-9&domain=pdf

    http://orcid.org/0000-0001-9873-5109

    mailto:ellenli@ruc.edu.cn

    mailto:ellenli@ruc.edu.cn

    http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/

    negative, expected or unexpected, and personal or organizational (Holtom et al. 2005).

    As one of the most important factors predicting employees’ voluntary turnover, career

    shock has been proven to influence individuals’ work behaviors and career planning

    (Burton et al. 2010; Holtom et al. 2005), and alter employee’s career path (Bright et al.

    2005). However, not enough attention has been paid to individual career trajectories in

    this (Akkermans et al. 2018). Hence, investigating the role of career shocks on individ-

    uals’ career decision-making can help organizations to predict work behaviors such as

    work engagement, performance, and turnover.

    Future time perspective is a core construct in socioemotional selectivity theory

    (Carstensen et al. 1999), and is defined as an individual’s “subjective sense of future

    time” (Carstensen, 2006). From socioemotional selectivity theory, age is the major fac-

    tor to predict future time perspective (Fung et al. 2001), and younger adults focus more

    on opportunities compared to older adults (Zacher & de Lange, 2011). Occupational fu-

    ture time perspective is conceptually distinguished in two related dimensions, “per-

    ceived remaining time” and “focus on opportunities.” Perceived remaining time is

    defined as individuals’ perception of restrictions in future career and concentration on

    losses and limitations. Focus on opportunities is defined as individuals’ perceptions of

    new work-related goals and possibilities that are foreseen in the future (Zacher and

    Frese, 2009). Researchers have supported the relationship between occupational future

    time perspective and job related outcomes, such as career maturity, career planning

    and career decidedness (e.g. Taber and Blankemeyer 2015). The way how individuals

    perceive their future can influence their career decisions, career maturity (Cheng et al.

    2016), job satisfaction (Weikamp and Göritz 2016), occupational self-efficacy, career

    commitment and turnover intention (Park and Jung 2015). However, there is a lack of

    research in how constraining job factors such as negative life events and hindering job

    demands impact employees’ future time perspective (Rudolph et al., 2018). Examining

    and discussing constraining job factors as antecedents can enrich the understanding of

    future time perspective.

    Our study aims to examine the effect of negative career shocks for three reasons.

    First, in daily life, people believe that the more positive life events, the better. However

    events evoke different emotional intensities, so more may not always be better (Seta

    et al. 2008). Researchers suggest that “bad is better than good,” and suggest that nega-

    tive events may exert stronger influence on individual’s career development by provid-

    ing greater motivation compared with positive events (Baumeister et al. 2001; Larsen

    and Ketelaar 1991; Holtom et al. 2012). Second, previous research indicates that, due to

    the effect of mood, each person can react differently towards negative shocks (Weiss

    and Cropanzano 1996), so that rather than reducing work effort, highly embedded em-

    ployees are possible to re-focus on the job and increase organizational citizenship be-

    havior (OCB) after experiencing negative shocks (Burton et al. 2010). Last but not least,

    negative shocks appear more often than positive shocks (Holtom et al. 2012). People

    may not be sensitive to positive shocks, but are sensitive to negative shocks. Therefore,

    discovering the effects of negative shocks can advance the research and theory in career

    development.

    Exploring the predictors of both dimensions of occupational future time perspective

    is very important (Henry et al., 2017; Rudolph et al. 2018). However, the predictors of

    focus on opportunities are lacking in current research. Job complexity and job control

    Feng et al. Frontiers of Business Research in China (2020) 14:1 Page 2 of 17

    are the main antecedents that has been studied so far (Zacher and Frese 2009, 2011;

    Rudolph et al. 2018). In order to find the antecedents of focus on opportunities, we

    proposed and tested a moderated mediation model in which we posit that negative

    shocks indirectly influences people’ s future time perspective through the effect of so-

    cial capital, and organizational embeddedness acts as a boundary condition of this rela-

    tionship. Fig. 1 presents our proposed research model.

  • Conceptual development and hypotheses development
  • The unfolding model of voluntary employee turnover (Lee and Mitchell 1994; Lee et al.

    1996) proposed the construct of career shock from Beach’s (1990) decision-making

    model and image theory, to understand the processes of employees’ decisions to quit.

    According to the image theory, individuals constantly obtain information that could

    potentially lead to changes in their behavior. Some sorts of unexpected events, which

    have been defined as shocks to the system, lead individuals to pause and think about

    the meaning or implication in relation to their job (Lee and Mitchell 1994). Based on

    this unfolding model of voluntary employee turnover, shocks can alter individuals’

    psychological processes. If it recalls prior memory and violates individuals’ value image,

    then people would choose a preexisting plan to leave. Seibert et al. (2013) showed that

    positive shocks instead of negative shocks can motivate individuals to pursue to gradu-

    ate education, which helps to understand the benefits of shocks. Also, job embedded-

    ness has been proven to buffer the negative effect of negative shocks during the

    workplace (Holtom and Inderrieden 2006; Burton et al., 2010; Holtom et al. 2012).

    These studies enable us to analyze the benefits of negative shocks and address the

    research question: How can negative shocks motivate employees?

    Hobfoll’s (1988, 1989) model of conservation of resources proposes that individuals

    strive to retain, protect, and build resources, and then apply them to improve well-

    being and personal development over time. Resources are defined as assets and goods

    that people value, with an emphasis on objects, states, and conditions; almost anything

    good can be considered a resource (Gorgievski et al. 2011). Job security (Selenko et al.

    2013), autonomy (Chen et al. 2009), social support (Zimmermann et al. 2011; Liu et al.

    2013; Diestel and Schmidt 2012), self-esteem, self-efficacy, locus of control, and core

    self-evaluation (Chen et al., 2009; Xanthopoulou et al., 2009) are examples of psycho-

    logical resources reported in the organizational literature. Therefore, to open the black

    box of negative shocks’ impact, resource loss and retrieval can be considered as critical

    for analyzing the psychological process.

    Fig. 1 Proposed research model

    Feng et al. Frontiers of Business Research in China (2020) 14:1 Page 3 of 17

    Mediating influence of internal social capital

    When people experience negative shocks which threaten their resources and diminish

    their well-being, they are likely to have a sense of insecurity and lack of support,

    making people feel that they lose important psychological resources (Koopmann et al.,

    2016). According to conservation of resources theory, in the face of stressful resource

    loss, individuals may use other resources to offset net loss and attempt to conserve

    remaining resources (cf. Pearlin et al. 1981; Halbesleben 2010; Halbesleben and

    Wheeler 2011). An effective strategy to mitigate the situation is very important to one’s

    career path. During career shocks, social capital provides an effective way to shift atten-

    tion to career management strategies (Seibert et al. 2001; Wayne et al. 1999). Social

    capital can be used to help employees find new job alternatives or positions both inside

    and outside the organization (Granovetter, 1973; Marsden & Hurlbert, 1988; Zippay,

    2001).

    The construct of internal social capital is a critical dimension of political skill and

    refers to developing and using networks of people (Ferris et al. 2005). It mainly indi-

    cates establishment of social ties within the organization, especially among supervisors

    or managers, and advances career success inside the company. Individuals with high

    level of internal social capital easily develop friendship and build strong and beneficial

    alliances and coalitions. They ensure that they are well positioned in order to both cre-

    ate and take advantage of opportunities (Pfeffer 1992). Through internal social capital,

    people retain, protect, and build valued social capital resources by developing relation-

    ships with others who have the potential to assist them in their careers (Forret and

    Dougherty 2004). Therefore, internal social capital can meet individuals’ needs and serve

    as intrinsic motivation to achieve their innate goal. In this paper, internal social capital is

    considered as resources in Hobfoll’s model (Hobfoll 1988, 1989).

    When individuals have more friends and build good relationship with influential

    colleagues through internal social capital, they gain social support (Diestel and Schmidt

    2012) and build a resource-rich environment beneficial for career development. Social

    support has been shown to be an effective strategy to deal with stressful life events, and

    close dyadic relationships offer well-established psychological benefits (Collins and Feeney

    2000), which protect individuals’ valued identities (Petriglieri, 2011) and strengthen their

    career goals. This reasoning is in line with the process known as a “gain cycle” from the

    conservation of resources model (Hobfoll 1989). Based on the social support in the work

    environment, individuals would be better able to predict their future career development.

    The more resource-rich the work environment, the more opportunities an individual per-

    ceives for their future work (Rudolph et al. 2018). Therefore, we propose that:

    Hypothesis 1: Internal social capital mediates the relationship between negative shocks

    and focus on

    opportunities.

    Moderating influence of organizational Embeddedness

    Mitchell et al. (2001) used three dimensions for job embeddedness: links, fit and sacrifice.

    Links describes the number of ties employees have within the organization, i.e., the formal

    or informal connections between a person and institutions or other people. Fit means the

    compatibility or comfort between employees and the organization, or environment. While

    Feng et al. Frontiers of Business Research in China (2020) 14:1 Page 4 of 17

    sacrifice stands for the potential cost or benefits of leaving the job, this construct has later

    been developed more broadly to indicate organizational and community embeddedness

    (Ng and Feldman 2010a). Crossley et al. (2007) proposed a reflective measure for job em-

    beddedness which has better psychometric properties, as a measure for organizational em-

    beddedness. This measure has equivalent prediction in comparison with the original one

    (Lee et al., 2014), and has been adopted to predict social capital and human capital (Ng

    and Feldman 2010a).

    Studies show that organizational identification has a positive influence on individuals’

    emotions (Avanzi et al. 2015; Avanzi et al. 2018; Frisch et al. 2014), and on turnover

    (e.g. Van Dick et al. 2004; Lee et al. 2015). However, as we concentrate on the adverse

    impact of negative career shocks and organizational embeddedness has shown to have

    a buffer effect (Burton et al. 2010; Holtom et al. 2012), we decide to include

    organizational embeddedness in our model.

    Organizational embeddedness represents a broad constellation of influences on

    employee retention (Lee et al. 2014; Mitchell et.al., 2001). In this study, we focus on

    organizational embeddedness that is more closely related to individuals’ career develop-

    ment, and it shows a strong link between career plans and the present job (Ng & Feld-

    man, 2010a). Employees who are highly embedded in organizations will have more job

    security, employment stability and professional success (Ng and Feldman 2007) and re-

    duced likelihood of looking for alternative jobs (Holtom and Inderrieden 2006). In

    order to reduce the negative influence of turnover, researchers study the buffer effect

    of organizational embeddedness (Holtom and Inderrieden 2006; Burton et al. 2010;

    Holtom et al. 2012). Therefore, high level of organizational embeddedness could help

    to reduce turnover and turnover intention, or improve job related outcomes such as

    core task performance and citizenship behaviors (Crossley et al. 2007; Wijayanto and

    Kismono 2004).

    From the escalation of commitment literature (Brockner 1992; Staw 1981), highly

    embedded individuals will continue to exert efforts, increase their efforts to cement

    their relationship with the organization even under negative shocks (Burton et al.

    2010). Highly embedded individuals tend to set goals within their organizations, are

    motivated to stay and work in their organizations, and have a high degree of fit with

    their organization. Thus, these individuals have a higher degree of interconnectedness

    with their peers, and more social capital leading to increase in focus on opportunities.

    In addition, when individuals develop a high degree of fit with their organizations and

    perceive higher cost of leaving, they may be motivated to deploy skills that could help

    them stay, and therefore reduce the effect of negative shocks and shift the attention to

    opportunities.

    Hypothesis 2 : Organizational embeddedness moderates the strength of the mediated

    relationship between negative shocks and focus on opportunities through internal social

    capital such that the mediated relationship is stronger when organizational

    embeddedness is high.

    Hypothesis 3 : Organizational embeddedness moderates the strength of the

    mediated relationship between negative shocks and focus on opportunities through

    internal social capital such that the mediated relationship is weaker when

    organizational embeddedness is low.

    Feng et al. Frontiers of Business Research in China (2020) 14:1 Page 5 of 17

  • Method
  • Sample and procedure

    We conducted a time-lagged study in which we collected two-wave data in June (wave 1)

    and December (wave 2) 2018. In wave 1 (T1) we measured negative career shocks and

    demographic varibles, and in wave 2 (T2) we measured internal social capital,

    organizational embeddedness and occupational future time perspective. Since we were in-

    terested in career shocks and future time perspective of general population in China, we

    avoided collecting data within companies in case to obtain a biased sample. Instead, we

    used a snowball sampling method through a Chinese social network App (Wechat).

    Wechat was created in 2011 by a Chinese Internet giant Tencent as a chat App with fea-

    tures and functionality similar to WhatsApp. According to Wechat data report (2018, re-

    leased by Wechat official), about 1.08 billion of which 63 million were over 55 years old

    are monthly active users of Wechat.

    We received a total of 352 responses in T1. Each participant received RMB5 for par-

    ticipation. Six months later, the T2 survey invitation was sent to same participants,

    each participant receive another RMB5 as gratitude. After matching the telephone

    number, email address and name, our samples contained 230 participants. In order to

    ensure the quality of survey, we set three testing questions in both surveys which were

    “if you are answering the questions carefully, please choose 5 (strongly agree)” “if you

    are answering the questions carefully, please choose 4 (relatively agree)” and “if you are

    answering the questions carefully, please choose 3 (sometimes).” 20 responses that

    failed these testing questions were eliminated and the final sample size was 210.

    Average age was 31.48 years old (SD = 5.63) and 31.80% of them were female. Average

    tenure with the current employer was 8.10 years (SD = 6.09). The participants worked in

    varied organizations such as state-owned enterprises (23.20%), party and government

    organizations or public institutions (22.70%), private enterprises (19.10%), institutions of

    higher learning (15.00%), foreign-owned enterprises (8.60%), strategic response unit

    (2.30%) among others (9.10%). 56.80% of the participants in our sample had a bachelor

    degree, 28.60% had a master degree, 5.90% had a doctor degree, still 8.60% among others.

    Measures

    Negative career shocks

    We use the career shocks scale developed by Seibert et al. (2013) mainly because this

    scale was specifically related to individual’s career management. The scale contains four

    items to measure both positive shocks and negative shocks. In this study, since we only

    focus on negative shocks, only the two items about negative career shocks were used

    (see

  • Appendix
  • ). Participants were asked whether they experienced the career shock or

    not (coded as 1 or 0), since a career shock is a formal construct that implies employees’

    turnover intention. In order to test the validity, we conducted the regression effect on

    participants’ turnover intention (β = 0.47, p < 0.01). The result supported the use of this

    measure for career shocks by definition and in accordance with previous research.

    Internal social capital

    We used three items out of the six items from the Political Skill Inventory which is

    measured on a 5-point Likert-format scale (from 1 = strongly disagree to 5 = strongly

    Feng et al. Frontiers of Business Research in China (2020) 14:1 Page 6 of 17

    agree) (Ferris et al. 2005). Before the wave 1 survey (T1), we pruned several items to

    simplify our questionnaire. As a result, we used three high loading items to measure

    internal social capital (see Apendix). The Cronbach’s α was acceptable at 0.71.

    Organizational embeddedness

    We used the global organizational embeddedness scale (Crossley et al. 2007) (see Appendix).

    The original scale consisted of seven items, we deleted one item (“I feel tied to this

    organization”) for semantic repetition with other items such as “I am tightly connected to this

    organization”. All items were measured on a 5-point Likert scale (from 1 = strongly disagree

    to 5 = strongly agree). This scale had an acceptable reliability of 0.76.

    Focus on opportunities

    We measured focus on opportunities with three items from Zacher and Frese’s (2009)

    occupational future time perspective scale (see Appendix). Participants were asked to

    rate on a 5-point scale (from 1 = strongly disagree to 5 = strongly agree) with a Cron-

    bach’s α = 0.75. Some researchers found that perceived remaining time may be an ante-

    cedent of focus on opportunities (Kooij et al. 2014). In addition, perceived remaining

    time and focus on opportunities were counterparts, so in this study we controlled for

    the effect of perceived remaining time (see Appendix). To test whether perceived

    remaining time and focus on opportunities were two distinct dimensions, we conducted

    confirmatory factor analyses (CFA) comparing results of one-factor and two-factor

    model. The two-factor model fit the dataset better, with χ2/df = 1.49, TLI = 0.95, CFI =

    0.97, RMSEA = 0.05, SRMR = 0.03. This result indicated that the two dimensions should

    be distinguished.

    Control variables

    Individual characteristics are important sources of occupational future time perspective

    (for a review see Kooij et al. 2018; Rudolph et al. 2018). Among all the antecedents of

    occupational future time perspective, age was highly important (Froehlich et al. 2016;

    Zacher and Frese 2009). Because people in different life stages have different percep-

    tions of time and this would end up in various perspectives about future (Lang and

    Carstensen 2002), in this study we controlled for demographic characteristics such as

    gender, age, organizational tenure and education. Other demographic characteristics

    such as company size and company type were not controlled because they were not

    personal resources or time-related characteristics.

    Data analysis

    We used SPSS 22.0 to conduct descriptive statistics and correlation analysis. Before

    testing the hypotheses and the model, CFA was conducted using Mplus 7.0. In

    order to test indirect effects, Preacher and Hayes (2004) recommended a resam-

    pling method such as bootstrapping to increase power and decrease Type I error.

    We performed bootstrapping using Model 14 of Process bootstrapping approach

    provided by Hayes (http://www.afhayes.com/spss-sasand-mplus-macros-and-code.

    html) to test direct, indirect, and moderated mediation model.

    Feng et al. Frontiers of Business Research in China (2020) 14:1 Page 7 of 17

    http://www.afhayes.com/spss-sasand-mplus-macros-and-code.html

    http://www.afhayes.com/spss-sasand-mplus-macros-and-code.html

    Results
    Descriptive statistics and correlations

    Table 1 presented the means, standard deviations and correlations for main variables.

    We found that negative career shocks were positively related with focus on opportun-

    ities (r = 0.16, p < 0.05) and internal social capital (r = 0.19, p < 0.01). Internal social cap-

    ital was positively related with focus on opportunities (r = 0.27, p < 0.001).

    Organizational embeddedness was not significantly related with focus on opportunities

    (r = −0.13, p > 0.05). Finally, the results showed internal social capital had a stronger re-

    lation with focus on opportunities compared with other factors.

    Confirmatory factor analysis

    CFA was used to test discriminant validity of the multi-dimension scale (internal

    social capital, organizational embeddedness and focus on opportunities). Before

    CFA, we conducted the Kaiser-Meyer-Olkin (KMO) test and the Bartlett’s test of

    sphericity. The KMO value of 0.72 and the result of Bartlett’s test sphericity (p <

    0.001) indicated that the sample was suitable for factor analysis.

    Following established practice (Byrne 2013; Hu and Bentler 1999), we used various fit

    indices to evaluate the fit of the model: χ2/df should be less than 3.00, SRMR (Standard-

    ized Root-Mean-Square Residual) should be close to 0.08, CFI (Comparative Fit Index)

    and TLI (Tucker-Lewis Index) should be close to 0.95, and RMSEA (Root Mean Square

    Error of Approximation) should be close to 0.06.

    In this study, we used item pairs to conduct CFA for higher reliability (Cattell and Burdsal

    Jr 1975; Kishton and Widaman 1994), normal distribution (Bagozzi and Heatherton 1994)

    and less idiosyncratic variance (Little et al. 2002). The results of CFA were shown in Table 2.

    The three-factor model fit the data best compared with two-factor model and one-factor

    model. This result suggested that hypothesized model of three factors was better than

    others. Distinctiveness of all scales used in this study was ensured.

    Test of hypotheses

    Hypothesis 1 indicated that internal social capital mediates the effect of negative career

    shocks on focus on opportunities. Table 3 showed the result of indirect effect. For the

    Table 1 Descriptive statistics and correlations (N = 210)a

    Mean SD 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

    1 Gender 1.69 0.47 1.00

    2 Age 31.28 5.44 −0.01 1.00

    3 Tenure 7.88 5.89 −0.02 0.92** 1.00

    4 Education 3.35 1.29 0.04 0.22** −0.02 1.00

    5 Company scale 3.33 0.73 0.07 −0.12 −0.09 −0.04 1.00

    6 Company type 3.30 2.04 −0.04 −0.21** −0.15* −0.25** 0.11 1.00

    7 NCS 0.81 0.39 −0.09 −0.11 −0.11 0.00 0.08 0.18** 1.00

    8 ISC 3.47 0.82 −0.06 −0.10 −0.09 −0.11 −0.05 0.13 0.19** 1.00

    9 FTP-O 3.45 0.92 −0.03 −0.23** −0.24** 0.03 −0.04 0.12 0.16* 0.27** 1.00

    10 OE 3.37 0.77 0.04 0.03 0.04 0.01 0.11 −0.06 −0.15* 0.01 −0.13 1.00
    aNotes. NCS = negative career shocks. ISC = internal social capital. FTP-O = focus on opportunities of future time
    perspective. OE = organizational embeddedness. *p < 0.05, **p < 0.01, ***p <0 .001

    Feng et al. Frontiers of Business Research in China (2020) 14:1 Page 8 of 17

    total effect, negative shocks can not predict focus on opportunities (β = 0.21, 95%CI =

    [−0.002, 0.63]). Internal social capital positively predicted focus on opportunities

    (β = .27, 95%CI = [0.03, 0.41]). The indirect effect of negative shocks on focus on oppor-

    tunities was significant (β = .10, 95%CI = [0.02, 0.25]). The explained variance changed

    from .06 to .13. This result indicated that internal social capital mediates the effect of

    negative career shocks on focus on opportunities. Thus, Hypothesis 1 was supported.

    Hypotheses 2 and 3 proposed that organizational embeddedness moderates the

    strength of the mediated relationship between negative shocks and focus on opportun-

    ities through internal social capital. We further conducted the simple slope test to illus-

    trate this result according to Aiken and West (1991). Table 4 showed the moderated

    mediation results. Fig. 2 depicted the relationship between internal social capital levels

    and focus on opportunities at both low and high levels of organizational embeddedness.

    The results showed that when organizational embeddedness was higher (one SD above

    the mean), the relationship between internal social capital and focus on opportunities

    was stronger (β = 0.16, 95% CI = [0.03, 0.36]), and when organizational embeddedness

    was lower (one SD below the mean), the relationship became non-significant (β = 0.03,

    95% CI = [−0.03, 0.16]). Thus the relationship between internal social capital and focus

    on opportunities is only significant when organizational embeddedness was high. This

    result provided support for Hypothesis 2 but not for Hypothesis 3.

  • Discussion
  • There has been studies on how career shocks influence voluntary turnover. We examine

    the effects of career shocks on occupational future time perspective because the study

    about antecedents of occupational future time perspective is especially rare and the

    underlying mechanism is not clear. This results support a model in which internal social

    capital mediates the effect of negative career shocks on the dimension of focus on oppor-

    tunites. Even negative shocks can not directly predict future time perspective, but they do

    Table 2 CFA of the items (N = 210)

    χ2 df χ2/df SRMR CFI TLI RMSEA

    CFA-three factors 39.75 24 1.66 0.05 0.96 0.94 0.06

    CFA-two factors 247.63 26 9.52 0.14 0.41 0.19 0.20

    CFA-one factor 284.64 27 10.54 0.16 0.32 0.09 0.21

    Table 3 Regression results for testing mediation in Hypothesis 1a

    Variable and statistic Outcome: Internal social capital Outcome: Focus on opportunities

    Constant 3.43*** 2.86***

    Gender −0.08 −0.02

    Age 0.02 −0.02

    Tenure −0.03 −0.01

    Education −0.15 0.10

    Negative career shocks 0.38** 0.21

    Internal social capital 0.27***

    F 2.48 5.22

    R2 0.06 0.13
    aNotes. Bootstrap sample size = 5000. Results were reported after controlling for age, gender, tenure, education and
    perceived remaining time. *p < 0.05, **p < 0.01, ***p < 0.001

    Feng et al. Frontiers of Business Research in China (2020) 14:1 Page 9 of 17

    still relate with focus on opportunities which may help to find other mechanisms in the

    future. As individuals become more embedded in the organization, this mediation effect

    would be stronger. However, for people less embedded within their organization, there is

    no effect. The result could be seen as in line with the previous studies showing that

    organizational embeddedness could buffer the negative effect of negative shocks (Burton

    et al. 2010; Holtom et al. 2012).

    Implications for theory development

    We obtain a novel result showing that negative career shocks can motivate people to

    be open for future career development through internal social capital. This positive

    effect was unexpected since negative career shocks usually generate negative effects

    such as turnover (Holtom et al. 2005).

    This research shows the mechanisms by which negative career shocks motivate indi-

    viduals to focus on opportunities and under what circumstances this effect exists. We

    incorporated negative career shocks within a conservation of resources theory frame-

    work in response to a calls for the use of this theory to study career shocks (Akkermans

    et al. 2018). We demonstrate the significance of internal social capital as a mediator of

    the negative relationship of career shocks to focus on opportunities by using the con-

    servation of resource theory to explain the resource loss and retention.

    Table 4 Moderated mediation results for career shocks across levels of organizational
    embeddednessa

    Moderator Level Effect Boot SE Boot LLCI Boot ULCI

    Organizational embeddedness −1 SD (−.77) 0.03 0.05 −0.03 0.16

    0.00 0.09 0.05 0.02 0.23

    + 1 SD (.77) 0.16 0.08 0.03 0.36
    aNotes. Bootstrap sample size = 5000. Results were reported after controlling for age, gender, tenure, education and
    perceived remaining time

    Fig. 2 Interactive effect between internal social capital and organizational embeddedness on focus on
    opportunities Notes. Low organizational embeddedness and low internal social capital were defined as at
    least one standard deviation below the mean; high organizational embeddedness and high internal social
    capital were defined as at least one standard deviation above the mean. High numbers indicated more
    focus on opportunities. ISC = internal social capital

    Feng et al. Frontiers of Business Research in China (2020) 14:1 Page 10 of 17

    Moreover, while social links are important antecedents of employees’ attachment to

    the current organization (Mitchell et al., 2001), only few studies has examined the role

    of social links on career shocks. Based on the unfolding model of voluntary employee

    turnover (Lee and Mitchell 1994; Lee et al. 1996), shocks can alter individuals’ psycho-

    logical processes by recalling prior memories and violating individuals’ value image. In

    this case people would probably choose a preexisting plan to leave. Our result offers a

    new explanation of the initial process of the unfolding model of voluntary employee

    turnover and addresses the buffering effect of negative shocks by introducing the role

    of internal social capital, showing the importance of social capital in the workplace.

    Furthermore, organizational embeddedness plays an important role in why people

    stay, as a supplement to turnover research. It explains a lot of variance in the turnover

    decision (Hom et al. 2017; Mitchell and Lee 2001). In prior studies, organizational

    embeddedness has been studied as a moderator or mediator and plays an important

    role in improving individuals’ work outcomes (Lee et al. 2014). Empirical studies have

    already shown that organizational embeddedness can attenuate shocks’ deleterious

    consequences such as employee turnover and job performance (Burton et al. 2010. Ng

    and Feldman 2010a, 2010b). Our results show that in terms of individuals’ career devel-

    opment, the more they are embedded, the more likely they are to focus on opportun-

    ities through internal social

    capital.

    Although researchers recommend studying occupational future time perspective in

    two separate dimensions, rather than combining into one (Rudolph et al., 2018; Cate

    and John 2007; Henry et al., 2017), there has been very little research focusing on this

    construct in detail. We mainly integrate conservation of resources theory and the

    unfolding model of voluntary employee turnover to analyze how negative career shocks

    alter employees’ occupational future time perspective, especially how negative shocks

    motivate employees to focus on opportunities. This study shows that as a contextual

    factor, negative career shocks motivate employees to be optimistic through the influ-

    ence of social links. The study also expands the research of occupational future time

    perspective to career studies.

    Limitations and future research

    The first limitation is that our research is conducted in Chinese culture. Since China is a

    highly collectivistic country, relationship or guanxi plays an important role in workplace. In-

    ternal social capital and organizational embeddedness both are crucial for employees. This

    may help to support the effects whereas in other individualist countries this mechanism

    may not work. Future studies can test this mechanism in other cultures, exploring whether

    building social relationships is useful for retaining psychological resources. In addition, our

    study only focuses on internal social capital, while external social capital can also be a sup-

    plemental resource to individuals. Based on a perspective within the organization, this study

    concerns only individuals’ internal social capital so as to discuss the moderating effect of

    organizational embeddedness on the relationship between internal social capital and focus

    on opportunities. Future studies should be conducted from a different perspective to under-

    stand the functions of external social capital in the process of career shocks.

    Lee and Mitchell (1994) defined a shock as “an event that generates information or

    has meaning about a person’s job. A shock must be interpreted and integrated into the

    Feng et al. Frontiers of Business Research in China (2020) 14:1 Page 11 of 17

    person’s system of beliefs and images.” In this sense, whether a shock is positive or

    negative should depend on individuals’ perception of it. If a negative career shock could

    be perceived as a motivating factor, then it is inappropriate to define it as negative. As

    career shocks matter a lot to employees’ turnover intentions or behaviors and company

    operations, more research should be done to clarify its definition and effects. Career

    shocks can often “jar an individual into psychological process of reappraising the trajec-

    tory of their current career path” (Seibert et al. 2013) or “jar employees toward deliber-

    ate judgements about their careers” (Slay et al., 2004). However, we did not discuss the

    psychological process aroused by negative career shocks and this process may serve as

    a mediator between negative career shocks and internal social capital. Future studies

    should take these mechanisms into account to better explain that in what psychological

    state individuals will conduct social capital development behaviors.

    Future research can expand to the whole turnover process to uncover the mecha-

    nisms present throughout the process and contribute to our understanding of turnover.

    Once employees focus on opportunities, they are more likely to have job search behav-

    iors, therefore increasing the likelihood of voluntary turnover.

    We collect the second wave data 6 months after the first wave; a two-wave study

    could avoid common method variance to a certain degree. However, occupational

    future time perspective is part of an individual’s cognition which may not be altered in

    the short term. Future research can expand the lagging period to at least 1 year, trying

    to depict the varying picture of occupational future time perspective. For example,

    future research could follow up individuals’ reactions on shocks in different career

    periods. Another limitation of the study is our use of snowball or chain referral

    sampling method to collect data, which leads to 91% of our sample holding a bachelor’s

    degree. Although snowball sampling is often applied when objects are not easily avail-

    able or the focus of study is on a sensitive issue (Noy 2008), it is obviously a drawback

    that research results may suffer by relatively greater homogeneity of participants.

    Highly educated individuals may influence the future time perspective even experien-

    cing the negative shocks, so the result may be difficult to generalize to different kinds

    of population (Biernacki and Waldorf 1981).

  • Conclusion
  • This research responds to the call for study in career shocks using conservation of re-

    sources theory (Akkermans et al. 2018), and separating future time perspective into

    two separate dimensions (Rudolph et al., 2018; Cate and John 2007; Henry et al., 2017).

    While negative career shocks may not directly motivate individuals to focus on oppor-

    tunities, internal social capital could mediate the effect, with highly organizationally

    embedded employees experiencing this indirect effect more strongly.

    Appendix
    Career shocks scale (Seibert et al. 2013)

    1. Visible job success. (measuring positive career shocks, not used)

    2. Quick raise or promotion. (measuring positive career shocks, not used)

    3. Had a mentor or colleague that was important to you leave the company.

    Feng et al. Frontiers of Business Research in China (2020) 14:1 Page 12 of 17

    4. Your organization went through a significant negative event such as a reduction-

    in-workforce, bankruptcy, or major ethical scandal.

    Items measuring internal social capital from political skill inventory (Ferris et al. 2005)

    1. I spend a lot of time and effort at work networking with others.

    2. I am good at building relationships with influential people at work.

    3. At work, I know a lot of important people and am well connected.

    4. I spend a lot of time at work developing connections with others. (not used

    because of

    relatively lower loading)

    5. I am good at using my connections and network to make things happen at work.

    (not used because of relatively lower loading)

    6. I have developed a large network of colleagues and associates at work whom I can

    call on for support when I really need to get things done. (not used because of

    relatively lower loading)

    In their paper, Ng and Feldman (2010a, 2010b) used 6 items in Political Skill Inventory

    (Ferris et al. 2005) to measure internal social capital development behaviors. In this study,

    we chose three items with higher loadings out of those six items to measure internal social

    capital.

    Global organizational embeddedness scale (Crossley et al. 2007)

    1. I feel attached to this organization.

    2. It would be difficult for me to leave this organization.

    3. I’m too caught up in this organization to leave.

    4. I simply could not leave the organization that I work for.

    5. It would be easy for me to leave this organization.

    (reverse coded)

    6. I am tightly connected to this organization.

    7. I feel tied to this organization. (not used because of semantic repetition)

    Occupational future time perspective scale (Zacher and Frese 2009)

    Focus on opportunities:

    1. Many opportunities await me in my occupational future

    2. I expect that I will set many new goals in my occupational future

    3. My occupational future is filled with possibilities

    Perceived remaining time:

    1. Most of my occupational life lies ahead of me. (reverse coded)

    2. My occupational future seems infinite to me. (reverse coded)

    3. As I get older, I begin to experience time in my occupational future as limited.

    (reverse coded)

  • Acknowledgements
  • Not applicable.

    Feng et al. Frontiers of Business Research in China (2020) 14:1 Page 13 of 17

  • Authors’ contributions
  • In preparing this manuscript, JF and ML worked together to propose the research topic and developed the theoretical
    model. In addition, JF provided the preliminary research design, conducted the literature review, offered explanation
    of the hypotheses, collected data and demonstrated the limitations and implications of this study. ML analysed the
    data. WZ drafted the manuscript and improved the introduction and discussion sections dramatically. SL participated
    in the discussion of the research model and helped to draft the manuscript, updated the literature and hypotheses
    development. All authors read and approved the final manuscript.

  • Funding
  • No funding was received.

  • Availability of data and materials
  • The datasets used and/or analysed during the current study are available from the corresponding author on
    reasonable request.

  • Competing interests
  • The authors declare that they have no competing interests.

    Received: 17 July 2019 Accepted: 29 November 2019

  • References
  • Aiken, L. S., & West, S. G. (1991). Multiple regression: Testing and interpreting interactions. Newbury Park: Sage. https://doi.org/10.

    1037/0021-9010.84.6.897.
    Akkermans, J., Seibert, S. E., & Mol, S. T. (2018). Tales of the unexpected: Integrating career shocks in the contemporary careers

    literature. SA Journal of Industrial Psychology, 44, 1–10. https://doi.org/10.4102/sajip.v44i0.1503.
    Avanzi, L., Fraccaroli, F., Castelli, L., Marcionetti, J., Crescentini, A., Balducci, C., & van Dick, R. (2018). How to mobilize social

    support against workload and burnout: The role of organizational identification. Teaching and Teacher Education, 69, 154–
    167. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.tate.2017.10.001.

    Avanzi, L., Schuh, S. C., Fraccaroli, F., & van Dick, R. (2015). Why does organizational identification relate to reduced employee
    burnout? The mediating influence of social support and collective efficacy. Work and Stress, 29(1), 1–10. https://doi.org/
    10.1080/02678373.2015.1004225.

    Bagozzi, R. P., & Heatherton, T. F. (1994). A general approach to representing multifaceted personality constructs: Application
    to state self-esteem. Structural Equation Modeling: A Multidisciplinary Journal, 1(1), 35–67. https://doi.org/10.1080/
    10705519409539961.

    Baruch, Y. (2004). Transforming careers: From linear to multidirectional career paths: Organizational and individual
    perspectives. Career Development International, 9(1), 58–73. https://doi.org/10.1108/13620430410518147.

    Baumeister, R. F., Bratslavsky, E., Finkenauer, C., & Vohs, K. D. (2001). Bad is stronger than good. Review of General Psychology,
    5(4), 323–370. https://doi.org/10.1037/1089-2680.5.4.323.

    Beach, L. R. (1990). Image theory: Decision making in personal and organizational contexts. Wiley. https://doi.org/10.1002/job.
    4030130509.

    Betsworth, D. G., & Hansen, J. I. C. (1996). The categorization of serendipitous career development events. Journal of Career
    Assessment, 4(1), 91–98. https://doi.org/10.1177/106907279600400106.

    Biernacki, P., & Waldorf, D. (1981). Snowball sampling: Problems and techniques of chain referral sampling. Sociological
    Methods & Research, 10 (2), 141–163. https://doi.org/10.1177/004912418101000205.

    Bright, J. E., Pryor, R. G., & Harpham, L. (2005). The role of chance events in career decision making. Journal of Vocational
    Behavior, 66(3), 561–576. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jvb.2004.05.001.

    Brockner, J. (1992). The escalation of commitment to a failing course of action: Toward theoretical progress. Academy of
    Management Review, 17(1), 39–61. https://doi.org/10.5465/AMR.1992.4279568.

    Burton, J. P., Holtom, B. C., Sablynski, C. J., Mitchell, T. R., & Lee, T. W. (2010). The buffering effects of job embeddedness on
    negative shocks. Journal of Vocational Behavior, 76(1), 42–51. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jvb.2009.06.006.

    Byrne, B. M. (2013). Structural equation modeling with Mplus: Basic concepts, applications, and programming. Routledge. https://
    doi.org/10.4324/9780203807644.

    Carstensen, L. L. (2006). The influence of a sense of time on human development. Science, 312(5782), 1913–1915. https://doi.
    org/10.1126/science.1127488.

    Carstensen, L. L., Isaacowitz, D. M., & Charles, S. T. (1999). Taking time seriously: A theory of socioemotional selectivity.
    American Psychologist, 54(3), 165. https://doi.org/10.1037//0003-066X.54.3.165.

    Cate, R. A., & John, O. P. (2007). Testing models of the structure and development of future time perspective: Maintaining a
    focus on opportunities in middle age. Psychology and Aging, 22 (1), 186–201. https://doi.org/10.1037/0882-7974.22.1.186.

    Cattell, R. B., & Burdsal Jr., C. A. (1975). The radial parcel double factoring design: A solution to the item-vs-parcel controversy.
    Multivariate Behavioral Research, 10(2), 165–179. https://doi.org/10.1207/s15327906mbr1002_3.

    Chen, S., Westman, M., & Eden, D. (2009). Impact of enhanced resources on anticipatory stress and adjustment to new
    information technology: A field-experimental test of conservation of resources theory. Journal of Occupational Health
    Psychology, 14(3), 219–230. https://doi.org/10.1037/a0015282.

    Cheng, C., Yang, L., Chen, Y., Zou, H., Su, Y., & Fan, X. (2016). Attributions, future time perspective and career maturity in
    nursing undergraduates: Correlational study design. BMC Medical Education, 16 (1),26. https://doi.org/10.1186/s12909-
    016-0552-1.

    Collins, N. L., & Feeney, B. C. (2000). A safe haven: An attachment theory perspective on support seeking and caregiving in
    intimate relationships. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 78(6), 1053–1073. https://doi.org/10.1037/0022-3514.78.
    6.1053.

    Feng et al. Frontiers of Business Research in China (2020) 14:1 Page 14 of 17

    Crossley, C. D., Bennett, R. J., Jex, S. M., & Burnfield, J. L. (2007). Development of a global measure of job embeddedness and
    integration into a traditional model of voluntary turnover. Journal of Applied Psychology, 92(4), 1031–1042. https://doi.org/
    10.1037/0021-9010.92.4.1031.

    Diestel, S., & Schmidt, K. H. (2012). Lagged mediator effects of self-control demands on psychological strain and absenteeism.
    Journal of Occupational and Organizational Psychology, 85(4), 556–578. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.2044-8325.2012.02058.x.

    Ferris, G. R., Treadway, D. C., Kolodinsky, R. W., Hochwarter, W. A., Kacmar, C. J., Douglas, C., & Frink, D. D. (2005). Development
    and validation of the political skill inventory. Journal of Management, 31, 126–152. https://doi.org/10.1177/
    0149206304271386.

    Forret, M. L., & Dougherty, T. W. (2004). Networking behaviors and career outcomes: Differences for men and women?
    Journal of Organizational Behavior, 25, 419–437. https://doi.org/10.2307/4093697.

    Frisch, J. U., Häusser, J. A., van Dick, R., & Mojzisch, A. (2014). Making support work: The interplay between social support and
    social identity. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology, 55, 154–161. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jesp.2014.06.009.

    Froehlich, D. E., Beausaert, S., & Segers, M. (2016). Aging and the motivation to stay employable. Journal of Managerial
    Psychology, 31(3), 756–770. https://doi.org/10.1108/JMP-08-2014-0224.

    Fung, H. H., Lai, P., & Ng, R. (2001). Age differences in social preferences among Taiwanese and mainland Chinese: The role of
    perceived time. Psychology and Aging, 16(2), 351–356. https://doi.org/10.1037//0882-7974.16.2.351.

    Gorgievski, M. J., Halbesleben, J. R., & Bakker, A. B. (2011). Expanding the boundaries of psychological resource theories.
    Journal of Occupational and Organizational Psychology, 84, 1–7. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.2044-8325.2010.02015.x.

    Granovetter, M. S. (1973). The strength of weak ties. American Journal of Sociology, 78(6), 1360–1380. https://doi.org/10.1086/
    225469.

    Halbesleben, J. R. (2010). The role of exhaustion and workarounds in predicting occupational injuries: A cross-lagged panel
    study of health care professionals. Journal of Occupational Health Psychology, 15(1), 1–16. https://doi.org/10.1037/
    a0017634.

    Halbesleben, J. R., & Wheeler, A. R. (2011). I owe you one: Coworker reciprocity as a moderator of the day-level
    exhaustion-performance relationship. Journal of Organizational Behavior, 32, 608–626. https://doi.org/10.1002/
    job.748.

    Henry, H., Zacher, H., & Desmette, D. (2017). Future time perspective in the work context: a systematic review of quantitative
    studies. Frontiers in Psychology, 8, Article 413. https://doi.org/10.3389/fpsyg.2017.00413.

    Hirschi, A. (2010). The role of chance events in the school-to-work transition: The influence of demographic, personality and
    career development variables. Journal of Vocational Behavior, 77, 39–49. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jvb.2010.02.002.

    Hobfoll, S. E. (1988). The ecology of stress. Washington, DC: Hemisphere Publishing Corp.
    Hobfoll, S. E. (1989). Conservation of resources: A new attempt at conceptualizing stress. American Psychologist, 44(3), 513–

    524. https://doi.org/10.1037/0003-066X.44.3.513.
    Holtom, B. C., Burton, J. P., & Crossley, C. D. (2012). How negative affectivity moderates the relationship between

    shocks, embeddedness and worker behaviors. Journal of Vocational Behavior, 80(2), 434–443. https://doi.org/10.
    1016/j.jvb.2011.12.006.

    Holtom, B. C., & Inderrieden, E. J. (2006). Integrating the unfolding model and job embeddedness model to better
    understand voluntary turnover. Journal of Managerial Issues, 18, 435–452. http://link.galegroup.com/apps/doc/
    A158388761/GPS?u=wash_main&sid=GPS&xid=d427ed31.

    Holtom, B. C., Mitchell, T. R., Lee, T. W., & Inderrieden, E. J. (2005). Shocks as causes of turnover: What they are and how
    organizations can manage them. Human Resource Management, 44, 337–352. https://doi.org/10.1002/hrm.20074.

    Hom, P. W., Lee, T. W., Shaw, J. D., & Hausknecht, J. P. (2017). One hundred years of employee turnover theory and research.
    Journal of Applied Psychology, 102(3), 530–545. https://doi.org/10.1037/apl0000103.

    Hu, L., & Bentler, P. M. (1999). Cutoff criteria for fit indexes in covariance structure analysis: Conventional criteria versus new
    alternatives. Structural Equation Modeling, 6(1), 1–55. https://doi.org/10.1080/10705519909540118.

    Kishton, J. M., & Widaman, K. F. (1994). Unidimensional versus domain representative parceling of questionnaire items: An
    empirical example. Educational and Psychological Measurement, 54(3), 757–765. https://doi.org/10.1177/
    0013164494054003022.

    Kooij, D. T., Kanfer, R., Betts, M., & Rudolph, C. W. (2018). Future time perspective: A systematic review and meta-analysis.
    Journal of Applied Psychology, 103(8), 867–893. https://doi.org/10.1037/apl0000306.

    Kooij, D. T. A. M., Bal, P. M., & Kanfer, R. (2014). Future time perspective and promotion focus as determinants of
    intraindividual change in work motivation. Psychology and Aging, 29, 319–328. https://doi.org/10.1037/a0036768.

    Koopmann, J., Lanaj, K., Bono, J., & Campana, K. (2016). Daily shifts in regulatory focus: The influence of work events and implications
    for employee well‐being. Journal of Organizational Behavior, 37(8), 1293–1316. https://doi.org/10.1002/job.2105.

    Lang, F. R., & Carstensen, L. L. (2002). Time counts: Future time perspective, goals, and social relationships. Psychology and
    Aging, 17, 125. https://doi.org/10.1037/0882-7974.17.1.125.

    Larsen, R. J., & Ketelaar, T. (1991). Personality and susceptibility to positive and negative emotional states. Journal of
    Personality and Social Psychology, 61, 132–140. https://doi.org/10.1037/0022-3514.61.1.132.

    Lee, E. S., Park, T. Y., & Koo, B. (2015). Identifying organizational identification as a basis for attitudes and behaviors: A meta-
    analytic review. Psychological Bulletin, 141(5), 1049–1080. https://doi.org/10.1037/bul0000012.

    Lee, T. W., Burch, T. C., & Mitchell, T. R. (2014). The story of why we stay: A review of job embeddedness. Annual
    Review of Organizational Psychology and Organizational Behavior, 1, 199–216. https://doi.org/10.1146/annurev-
    orgpsych-031413-091244.

    Lee, T. W., Hom, P. W., Eberly, M. B., Li, J. J., & Mitchell, T. R. (2017). On the next decade of research in voluntary employee
    turnover. Academy of Management Perspectives, 31, 201–221. https://doi.org/10.5465/amp.2016.0123.

    Lee, T. W., & Mitchell, T. R. (1994). An alternative approach: The unfolding model of voluntary employee turnover. Academy of
    Management Review, 19, 51–89. https://doi.org/10.5465/amr.1994.9410122008.

    Lee, T. W., Mitchell, T. R., Wise, L., & Fireman, S. (1996). An unfolding model of voluntary employee turnover. Academy of
    Management Journal, 39, 5–36. https://doi.org/10.5465/256629.

    Little, T. D., Cunningham, W. A., Shahar, G., & Widaman, K. F. (2002). To parcel or not to parcel: Exploring the question,
    weighing the merits. Structural Equation Modeling, 9(2), 151–173. https://doi.org/10.1207/S15328007SEM0902_1.

    Feng et al. Frontiers of Business Research in China (2020) 14:1 Page 15 of 17

    Liu, J., Kwan, H. K., Fu, P. P., & Mao, Y. (2013). Ethical leadership and job performance in China: The roles of workplace friendships
    and traditionality. Journal of Occupational and Organizational Psychology, 86, 564–584. https://doi.org/10.1111/joop.12027.

    Marsden, P. V., & Hurlbert, J. S. (1988). Social resources and mobility outcomes: A replication and extension. Social Forces,
    66(4), 1038–1059. https://doi.org/10.1093/sf/66.4.1038.

    Miller, M. J. (1983). The role of happenstance in career choice. Vocational Guidance Quarterly, 32, 16–20. https://doi.org/10.
    1002/j.2164-585X.1983.tb01552.x.

    Mitchell, T. R., Holtom, B. C., Lee, T. W., Sablynski, C. J., & Erez, M. (2001). Why people stay: Using job embeddedness to predict
    voluntary turnover. Academy of Management Journal, 44(6), 1102–1121. https://doi.org/10.5465/3069391.

    Mitchell, T. R., & Lee, T. W. (2001). The unfolding model of voluntary turnover and job embeddedness: Foundations for a
    comprehensive theory of attachment. Research in Organizational Behavior, 23, 189–246. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0191-
    3085(01)23006-8.

    Ng, T. W., & Feldman, D. C. (2010a). The effects of organizational embeddedness on development of social capital and
    human capital. Journal of Applied Psychology, 95(4), 696–712. https://doi.org/10.1037/a0019150.

    Ng, T. W., & Feldman, D. C. (2010b). The impact of job embeddedness on innovation-related behaviors. Human Resource
    Management, 49(6), 1067–1087. https://doi.org/10.1002/hrm.20390.

    Ng, T. W. H., & Feldman, D. C. (2007). Organizational embeddedness and occupational embeddedness across career stages.
    Journal of Vocational Behavior, 70(2), https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jvb.2006.10.002.

    Noy, C. (2008). Sampling knowledge: The hermeneutics of snowball sampling in qualitative research. International Journal of
    Social Research Methodology, 11(4), 327–344. https://doi.org/10.1080/13645570701401305.

    Park, I. J., & Jung, H. (2015). Relationships among future time perspective, career and organizational commitment,
    occupational self-efficacy, and turnover intention. Social Behavior and Personality: An International Journal, 43(9), 1547–
    1561. https://doi.org/10.2224/sbp.2015.43.9.1547.

    Pearlin, L. I., Menaghan, E. G., Lieberman, M. A., & Mullan, J. T. (1981). The stress process. Journal of Health and Social Behavior,
    22(4), 337–356. https://doi.org/10.2307/2136676.

    Petriglieri, J. L. (2011). Under threat: Responses to and the consequences of threats to individuals’ identities. Academy of
    Management Review, 36(4), 641–662. https://doi.org/10.5465/amr.2009.0087.

    Pfeffer, J. (1992). Managing with power. Boston: Harvard Business School Press.
    Preacher, K. J., & Hayes, A. F. (2004). SPSS and SAS procedures for estimating indirect effects in simple mediation models.

    Behavior Research Methods, Instruments, & Computers, 36(4), 717–731. https://doi.org/10.3758/BF03206553.
    Rudolph, C. W., Kooij, D. T., Rauvola, R. S., & Zacher, H. (2018). Occupational future time perspective: A meta-analysis of

    antecedents and outcomes. Journal of Organizational Behavior, 39(2), 229–248. https://doi.org/10.1002/job.2264.
    Seibert, S. E., Kraimer, M. L., Holtom, B. C., & Pierotti, A. J. (2013). Even the best laid plans sometimes go askew: Career self-

    management processes, career shocks, and the decision to pursue graduate education. Journal of Applied Psychology,
    98 (1), 169–182. https://doi.org/10.1037/a0030882.

    Seibert, S. E., Kraimer, M. L., & Liden, R. C. (2001). A social capital theory of career success. Academy of Management Journal,
    44, 219–237. https://doi.org/10.2307/3069452.

    Selenko, E., Mäkikangas, A., Mauno, S., & Kinnunen, U. (2013). How does job insecurity relate to self-reported job
    performance? Analysing curvilinear associations in a longitudinal sample. Journal of Occupational and Organizational
    Psychology, 86, 522–542. https://doi.org/10.1111/joop.12020.

    Seta, J. J., Haire, A., & Seta, C. E. (2008). Averaging and summation: Positivity and choice as a function of the number and
    affective intensity of life events. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology, 44(2), 173–186. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jesp.
    2007.03.003.

    Slay, H. S., Taylor, M. S., & Williamson, I. O. (2004). Midlife transition decision processes and career success: The role of identity,
    networks, and shocks. Austin: In annual meeting of the Academy of Human Resource Development http://citeseerx.ist.psu.
    edu/viewdoc/download?doi=10.1.1.574.1046&rep=rep1&type=pdf.

    Staw, B. M. (1981). The escalation of commitment to a course of action. Academy of Management Review, 6(4), 577–587.
    https://doi.org/10.2307/257636.

    Taber, B. J., & Blankemeyer, M. S. (2015). Time perspective and vocational identity statuses of emerging adults. The Career
    Development Quarterly, 63(2), 113–125. https://doi.org/10.1002/cdq.12008.

    Van Dick, R., Christ, O., Stellmacher, J., Wagner, U., Ahlswede, O., Grubba, C., et al. (2004). Should I stay or should I go?
    Explaining turnover intentions with organizational identification and job satisfaction. British Journal of Management, 15(4),
    351–360. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-8551.2004.00424.x.

    Vuori, V., & Okkonen, J. (2012). Knowledge sharing motivational factors of using an intra-organizational social media platform.
    Journal of Knowledge Management, 16(4), 592–603. https://doi.org/10.1108/13673271211246167.

    Wayne, S. J., Liden, R. C., Kraimer, M. L., & Graf, I. K. (1999). The role of human capital, motivation, and supervisor sponsorship
    in predicting career success. Journal of Organizational Behavior, 20(5), 577–595. https://doi.org/10.2307/3100430.

    Weikamp, J. G., & Göritz, A. S. (2016). Organizational citizenship behavior and job satisfaction: The impact of occupational
    future time perspective. Human Relations, 69(11), 2091–2115. https://doi.org/10.1177/0018726716633512.

    Weiss, H. M., & Cropanzano, R. (1996). Affective events theory: A theoretical discussion of the structure, causes and
    consequences of affective experiences at work. Research in Organizational Behavior, 18, 1–74.

    Wijayanto, B. R., & Kismono, G. (2004). The effect of job embeddedness on organizational citizenship behavior: The mediating
    role of sense of responsibility. Gadjah Mada International Journal of Business, 6(3), 335–354. https://doi.org/10.22146/
    gamaijb.5554.

    Xanthopoulou, D., Bakker, A. B., Demerouti, E., & Schaufeli, W. B. (2009). Work engagement and financial returns: A diary study
    on the role of job and personal resources. Journal of Occupational and Organizational Psychology, 82, 183–200. https://
    doi.org/10.1348/096317908X285633.

    Zacher, H., & de Lange, A. H. (2011). Relations between chronic regulatory focus and future time perspective: Results of a
    cross-lagged structural equation model. Personality and Individual Differences, 50(8), 1255–1260. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.
    paid.2011.02.020.

    Zacher, H., & Frese, M. (2009). Remaining time and opportunities at work: Relationships between age, work characteristics,
    and occupational future time perspective. Psychology and Aging, 24(2), 487–493. https://doi.org/10.1037/a0015425.

    Feng et al. Frontiers of Business Research in China (2020) 14:1 Page 16 of 17

    Zacher, H., & Frese, M. (2011). Maintaining a focus on opportunities at work: The interplay between age, job complexity, and
    the use of selection, optimization, and compensation strategies. Journal of Organizational Behavior, 32(2), 291–318.
    https://doi.org/10.1002/job.683.

    Zimmerman, B. K., Dormann, C., & Dollard, M. F. (2011). On the positive aspects of customers: Customer-initiated support and
    affective crossover in employee–customer dyads. Journal of Occupational and Organizational Psychology, 84(1), 31–57.
    https://doi.org/10.1111/j.2044-8325.2010.02011.x.

    Zippay, A. (2001). The roles of social capital in reclaiming human capital: A Longitudinal study of occupational mobility
    among displaces steelworkers. Journal of Sociology and Social Welfare, 28, 99.

  • Publisher’s Note
  • Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

    Feng et al. Frontiers of Business Research in China (2020) 14:1 Page 17 of 17

    © 2019. This work is published under
    http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/(the “License”). Notwithstanding

    the ProQuest Terms and Conditions, you may use this content in accordance
    with the terms of the License.

      Abstract
      Conceptual development and hypotheses development
      Mediating influence of internal social capital
      Moderating influence of organizational Embeddedness
      Method
      Sample and procedure
      Measures
      Negative career shocks
      Internal social capital
      Organizational embeddedness
      Focus on opportunities
      Control variables
      Data analysis
      Results
      Descriptive statistics and correlations
      Confirmatory factor analysis
      Test of hypotheses
      Discussion
      Implications for theory development
      Limitations and future research
      Conclusion
      Appendix
      Career shocks scale (Seibert et�al. 2013)
      Items measuring internal social capital from political skill inventory (Ferris et�al. 2005)
      Global organizational embeddedness scale (Crossley et�al. 2007)
      Occupational future time perspective scale (Zacher and Frese 2009)
      Acknowledgements
      Authors’ contributions
      Funding
      Availability of data and materials
      Competing interests
      References
      Publisher’s Note

    InternationalJournal of Information, Business and Management, Vol. 12, No.2, 2020

    ISSN 2076-9202

    185

    THEORETICAL ANALYSIS OF MANAGING CORPORATE SOCIAL

    RESPONSIBILITY IN DEVELOPING COUNTRIES

    Huguette Bura Sifa
    1

    and Corneille Luboya Tshiunza
    2

    1 School of Economics, Management and Business Administration, Central China Normal University,

    Wuhan, China (huguettebura@yahoo.com)

    2. School of Education, Educational Economy and Management, Central China Normal University,

    Wuhan, China (Corneilleluboya@outlook.fr)

    Abstract

    A Corporate Social Responsibility, generally noted by “CSR”, refers to a corporation’s initiatives to
    assess and take responsibility for the company’s effects on environmental and social well-being. It
    generally applies to efforts that go beyond what may be required by regulators or environmental
    protection groups. Governments seeking to advance sustainable development are increasingly turning to
    policies and strategies that encourage, support, mandate, or directly demonstrate more socially and
    environmentally sound business practices. A central component of these policies involves promoting
    increased transparency of economic activities. The purpose of this study is to analyze how companies i

    n

    developing countries manage their business processes to produce an overall positive impact on
    society. This is to evaluate the sustainability, social impact and ethics, and done correctly should be
    about core business and to determine how companies make their money, not just add-on extras such
    as philanthropy. The documentary research is the most method used to conduct this study. The results
    showed that CSR in developing countries is a rich and fascinating area of enquiry, which is
    becoming ever more important in managing a CSR theory and practice. The findings also showed
    that managing CSR in developing countries is a tremendous opportunity for improving knowledge
    and getting a profoundly understanding about social responsibility of an organization or a corporate.

    Key words: corporate social responsibility, ethics, stakeholders, shareholders, marketplace.

    1. Introduction

    Corporate social responsibility is a movement aimed at encouraging companies to be more aware of
    the impact of their business on the rest of society, including their own stakeholders and the environment
    (Financial Times Definition, 2018). Since many years ago, the social groups are confronted with several
    problems that threaten the world till now and can lead it to the ruin. We can hold up as an example: the
    corruption, the nepotism, the patronage, absence of democracy and fairness, the impunity, ethnical
    conflicts, bad management of enterprises, fraud, theft, and so one. All these phenomena are based
    generally on the good management of spending to realize and receipts to collect in order to improve the
    living conditions of populations and to respond to their societal demands in the eyes of their degradation.
    Each society needs more useful strategies and resources to reply on collective needs. This issue remains
    difficult to reach for countries, commonly called “developing countries” that are very far from reaching
    these objectives.

    As the opening vignette illustrates, determining how to conduct business in a corporate appropriately
    can be challenging. Wrong doing by businesses has focused public attention, managers and government
    involvement to encourage more acceptable business conduct. Any business decision may be judged as
    right or wrong, ethical or unethical, legal or illegal, responsible or not.

    In this writing, the aim of this study is to analyze the social responsibility of managing corporate in
    developing countries. This is to have a look at the role of ethics and social responsibility in business

    International Journal of Information, Business and Management, Vol. 12, No.2, 2020

    ISSN 2076-9202

    186

    decision making. The challenge for corporate social responsibility (CSR) in developing countries is
    framed by a vision that was distilled in 2000 into the Millennium Development Goals ‘a world with less
    poverty, hunger and disease, greater survival prospects for mothers and their infants, better educated
    children, equal opportunities for women, and a healthier environment’ (UN, 2006, p.3). Unfortunately,
    these global aspirations remain far from being met in many developing countries today.

    This research is undertaken in three stages: First, making a state of the literature places related to this
    study. This is to investigate whether any similar studies had been conducted before, determine the nature
    of any existing documents and gain an overview of the main arguments. Second, data is collected in a
    program drawing on the views of key commentators and practitioners and propose a set of indices for
    CSR auditing. Finally, data analysis is conducted using an established scientific approach.

    The methodology used as the basis of this study is the qualitative approach, which is defined as the
    discovery of theory from data systematically obtained from social research (Glaser and Strauss 1967).
    This method was chosen because of its capacity to generate theoretical explanations from largely
    qualitative information of the sort captured from reports and other documents. It is also a robust scientifi

    c

    approach that provides results from diverse and unstructured data.

    Therefore, to achieve this purpose, this study would like to answer the following main research
    question: What is the role of business in tackling the critical issues of human development and
    environmental sustainability in developing countries?

    2. Critical analysis on Managing a corporate social responsibility

    2.1.Conceptual framework of analysis

    Corporate social responsibility (CSR) is a business approach that contributes to sustainable
    development by delivering economic, social and environmental benefits for all stakeholders. The way it is
    understood and implemented differs greatly for each company and country. Moreover, CSR is a very
    broad concept that addresses many and various topics such as human rights, corporate governance, health
    and safety, environmental effects, working conditions and contribution to economic development.

    In fact, the broadest definition of CSR is concerned with what is or should be the relationship
    between global corporations, governments of countries and individual citizens. More locally, this is
    concerned with the relationship between a corporation and local society in which it resides or operates.
    Another definition is concerned with the relationship between a corporation and its stakeholders.

    There is no clear or agreed definition of Corporate Social Responsibility (CSR), so this raises the
    question as to “what exactly can be considered to be corporate social responsibility.”

    According to the European Commission (2002, p.347) manages CSR is “the responsibility of
    enterprises for their impacts on society.” In other words, “…CSR is a concept whereby companies
    integrate social and environmental concerns in their business operations and in their interaction with their
    stakeholders on a voluntary basis.”

    Carroll (1991) presented CSR as a multi-layered concept that consists of four interrelated aspects:
    economic, legal, ethical and philanthropic responsibilities. For her, companies are created to provide
    goods and services to the public and to make a profit. CSR is an equally contested concept (Moon,
    2002b).

    Whatever the definition is, the purpose of managing a CSR is to drive change towards sustainability.
    Although some companies may achieve remarkable efforts with unique CSR initiatives, it is difficult to be
    on the forefront on all aspects of CSR.

    To begin with, it is worth clarifying the use of the terms developing countries and CSR. There is an
    extensive historical and generally highly critical debate in the development literature about the
    classification of countries as developed and less developed or developing. Without reviving that debate
    here, suffice to say that the study use developing countries because it is still a popular term used to
    collectively describe nations that have relatively lower per capita incomes and are relatively less
    industrialized.

    From the outset , the study uses CSR in developing countries to represent ‘the formal and informal

    International Journal of Information, Business and Management, Vol. 12, No.2, 2020

    ISSN 2076-9202

    187

    ways in which business makes a contribution to improving the governance, social, ethical, labor and
    environmental conditions of the developing countries in which they operate, while remaining sensitive to
    prevailing religious, historical and cultural contexts’ (Visser et al., 2007). Considering this, the example
    below provides good practices on one aspect of CSR environmental sustainability.

    Figure 1: Diagram of Managing a corporate social responsibility

    Source: Mallen Baker on CSR (2004).

    Social responsibility has become an important topic on the corporate agenda in the light of corporate
    scandals, concerns about globalization and a growing mistrust of business. It pays attention to all
    stakeholders who are affected by their actions. Today, special interest groups continue to be one of the
    largest stakeholders concerns that companies face. Environmental responsibility has become a primary
    issue as both business and the public acknowledge the damage that has been done to our natural
    environment. The most important stakeholders known are the government and the community, which
    have become increasingly important in recent years. On one hand, most corporations exist only under the
    proper charter and license, and operate within the limits of safety laws, environmental protection
    requirements, antitrust regulations, antibribery legislation and other types of laws and regulations in the
    government sector. On the other hand, the community includes local government, the natural and physical
    environments and the quality of life for residents.

    Thus, companies need to answer to two aspects of their operations: (i) the quality of their
    management both in terms of people and processes (the inner circle), (ii) the nature of, and quantity of
    their impact on society in the various areas.

    Outside stakeholders are taking an increasing interest in the activity of the company. Most look to
    the outer circle what the company has actually done, good or bad, in terms of its products and services, in
    terms of its impact on the environment and on local communities, or in how it treats and develops its
    workforce. Out of the various stakeholders, it is financial analysts who are predominantly focused as well
    as past financial performance on quality of management as an indicator of likely future performance.

    2.2.Overview on CSR in the world

    2.2.1. Dimensions of CSR
    Business and academic researchers have shown increasing levels of interest in Corporate

    Social

    Responsibility (CSR) during recent years (Maignan, 2002). The theme of environmental and social
    responsibility appears in a number of political and legal documents and is gaining ever-greater
    importance at the international level. Today, corporate leaders face a dynamic and challenging task in
    attempting to apply societal ethical standards to responsible business practice. Companies, especially
    those operating in global markets, are increasingly required to balance the social, economic and
    environmental components of their business, while building shareholder value.

    Management is responsible for creating and sustaining conditions in which people are likely to
    behave themselves. Managers must take active steps to ensure that the company stays on an ethical

    International Journal of Information, Business and Management, Vol. 12, No.2, 2020

    ISSN 2076-9202

    188

    footing. This management should consider the Ethical and social responsibility business practices. These
    depend on individual managers and the organization’s values, policies, and practices. So, managers must
    use the three pillars that support an ethical organization: ethical individuals, ethical leadership and
    organizations, structures and systems.

    The socio economic view stated that management’s social responsibility of a corporate goes beyond
    making: (i) profits to include protecting and improving society’s welfare, (ii) corporations are not
    independent entities responsible only to stockholders: complex set of goals, (iii) firms have a moral
    responsibility to larger society to become involved in social, legal and political issues, (iv) to do the right
    thing and (v) the myth of shareholder capitalism.

    The management of CSR covers a wide range of issues which are ambiguous as to what is right or
    wrong. What about two companies engaged in intense competition? Is it socially responsible for a strong
    company to drive a weak company out of business? A company’s environmental impact must also be
    taken in consideration. The table below presents some arguments “for” and “against” social
    responsibility:

    Table 1: Arguments for and against social responsibility in an organization

    Arguments “for” Social Responsibility Arguments “against” Social Responsibility

    Public expectation Violation of profit maximization
    Long-run profits Dilution of purpose

    Public image Costs
    Better environment Too much power

    Government regulation Lack of skills
    Responsibility and power Lack of accountability

    Stockholder interest
    Possession of resources
    Prevention over cures

    Source: Author adapted from Maignan, 2002
    In the visualization of the above table, the main concern of this point is to determine whether social

    responsibility in managing a corporate pays or not. The following reasons below explain the advantages
    and disadvantages of driving a social responsibility in a business company: (i) positive relationship
    between social involvement and the economic performance of firms, but the (ii) difficulties in defining
    and measuring “social responsibility” and “economic performance raise issues of validity and causation in
    the studies, (iii) mutual funds using social screening in investment decisions slightly outperformed other
    mutual funds, (iv) firm’s social actions do not harm its long-term performance and (v) align values and
    competences= social responsibility enlightened self-interest. Doing well by doing good (Michael Porter).
    This means that “managing social responsibility in an organization” implies:

    International Journal of Information, Business and Management, Vol. 12, No.2, 2020

    ISSN 2076-9202

    189

    Figure 2: Managing Social Responsibility paths

    Source: Author adapted from Maignan, 2002.

    2.2.2. Corporate Social Responsibility Audit and its Steps

    Many successful companies have become world-renowned for incorporating social causes and social
    initiatives into their cultures, their values, and business strategies. Increased customer preference for
    social responsibility points to the importance of understanding how this type of philosophy can enhance
    your business. The audit helps to measure the company’s actual social performance against the social
    objectives it has set for itself. In other words, “Is your company a good global citizen? How do you know?
    What can you do to improve your positioning?” This is to evaluate the integrating business strategy and
    corporate social responsibility contributes to: (i) positive brand awareness, (ii) increased

    employee

    satisfaction, (iii) reduced operating costs, (iv) improved community relations and (v) corporate
    accountability. This means that corporate social audit is: 1. Tool for the evaluation of social responsibility
    effectiveness; 2. Formal and thorough analysis and 3. Conducted by task force.

    When making payroll and finding your next customer are top priorities, it may at times seem
    difficult, if not impossible, to focus on your corporate social responsibilities. But there is no better time to
    integrate a socially responsible corporate culture into your organization than right now. This is especially
    true in early-stage companies and start-ups, when business practices and organizational norms are just
    being formed.

    In other words, the major perception of CSR is that it can be an excellent tool for enhancing the
    legitimacy of the firm among its stakeholders and the development of a positive corporate image. A key
    vehicle for enhancing corporate image is the social report (Hess 1999). The value of the social report is
    perceived as residing in the creation of social transparency as well as in institutionalizing responsible
    decision-making and creative thinking in management. Effective development of social reporting can be
    seen in the recent success of non-mandatory environmental auditing.

    Building on this progress, Hess (1999) argues that there is a need to establish an audit system that
    includes all aspects of a firm’s social performance. On the evidence discovered to date in the literature,
    CSR seems to be perceived by many as the social strand of sustainable development, including the World
    Business Council for Sustainable development, and the European Parliament. However, there is far less
    agreement regarding its measurement. The literature review indicates that developing an applied CSR

    International Journal of Information, Business and Management, Vol. 12, No.2, 2020

    ISSN 2076-9202

    190

    auditing procedure will be a challenging task. This is mainly due to the lack of formal study of the topic,
    despite the widespread debate it has engendered. However, several current measurement procedures for
    CSR exist, which gives a promising indication that there is sufficient experience to develop appropriate
    methods and indices for a comprehensive auditing system. Chronologically, this study consists of: (i)
    define social goals, (ii) analyze resources devoted to each goal, (iii) determine degree of achievement for
    each goal and (iv) make recommendations for the future.

    2.3.Overview on Managing Corporate Social Responsibility in developing countries

    The rationale for focusing on CSR in developing countries as distinct from CSR in the developed

    world is fourfold: (1) Developing countries represent the most rapidly expanding economies, and hence

    the most lucrative growth markets for business (IMF, 2006); (2) Developing countries are where the

    social and environmental crises are usually most acutely felt in the world (WRI, 2005; UNDP, 2006); (3)

    Developing countries are where globalization, economic growth, investment, and business activity are

    likely to have the most dramatic social and environmental impacts (both positive and negative) (World

    Bank, 2006); (4) Developing countries present a distinctive set of CSR agenda challenges which are

    collectively quite different to those faced in the developed world.

    2.3.1. Classification of literature on CSR in developing countries

    In part, this reflects the fact that corporate social responsibility is the preferred term in the literature

    to describe the role of business in developing countries, as opposed to, say, business ethics, corporate

    citizenship, corporate sustainability, or stakeholder management. More than this, however, social issues

    are generally given more political, economic, and media emphasis in developing countries than

    environmental, ethical, or stakeholder issues (Schmidheiny, 2006). And there is also still a strong

    emphasis on the philanthropic tradition in developing countries, which is often focused on community

    development (figure 5 et 6).

    Source: Author adapted from World Bank, 2006.

    Lockett et al. (2006) also classify CSR papers by epistemological approach and find a roughly even split

    between theoretical and empirical research, which is also the case in the literature on CSR in developing

    International Journal of Information, Business and Management, Vol. 12, No.2, 2020

    ISSN 2076-9202

    191

    countries, although the latter has a slight weighting towards empirical work. What is interesting is that,

    whereas Lockett et al. (2006) find that 89%of theoretical CSR papers are non-normative, in the CSR in

    developing countries literature; the balance is far more evenly split. This is largely due to the relatively

    large number of papers on the role of business in development, which tend to adopt a normative, critical

    perspective (Blowfield and Frynas, 2005).

    Figure 7: Global context of CSR in developing countries

    By analysis level

    Source: Author adapted from World Bank, 2006.

    In terms of empirical research, there are also differences. According to Lockett et al. (2006), the

    CSR literature is dominated by quantitative methods (80%). In contrast, CSR papers on developing

    countries are more likely to be qualitative.

    There is very little empirical research on the nature and extent of CSR in developing countries. One

    notable exception is Baskin’s (2006) research on the reported corporate responsibility behavior of 127

    leading companies from 21 emerging markets across Asia, Africa, Latin America, and Central and Eastern

    Europe, which he compares with over 1,700 leading companies in high-income OECD

    countries.

    2.3.2. Current trends in CSR

    Corporate reporting whether mandated or voluntary on environmental, social, labor and human

    rights issues is a relatively new phenomenon. While a small number of firms have irregularly published

    information on their nonfinancial performance, more systematic and standardized systems of social and

    environmental reporting only emerged in the late-1980s and early-1990s.

    Since the 1980s, governments, firms, and NGOs around the world have developed a wide range of

    reporting systems with goals as diverse as reducing pollution, mitigating health and safety risks,

    spotlighting (and thus rooting out) corruption, improving public service delivery, and protecting civil

    rights. With each new initiative in public reporting, public demands for fuller information and a deeper

    “right-to-know” appear to solidify.

    These initiatives have been driven by a range of pressures and demands from: consumers, NGOs,

    unions, investors, governments, community members, and firms themselves.

    2.3.3. Drivers of CSR in developing countries

    There are several types of CSR’ drivers in developing countries, regrouped in two main categories

    International Journal of Information, Business and Management, Vol. 12, No.2, 2020

    ISSN 2076-9202

    192

    such as:

    1. Internal drivers

    These are : (i) the Political reform. The CSR in developing countries cannot be divorced from the

    socio-political reform process, which often drives business behavior towards integrating social and ethical

    issues. (ii) The Crisis response can be analyzed by various kinds of crises associated with developing

    countries. These often have the effect of catalyzing CSR responses. These crises can be economic, social,

    environmental, health-related, or industrial. Catastrophic events with immediate impact are often more

    likely to elicit CSR responses, especially of the philanthropic kind. The corporate response to the Asian

    tsunami is a classic case in point (Fernando, 2007). However, industrial accidents may also create

    pressure for CSR. (iii) The Cultural tradition: many believe CSR is a Western invention (and this may

    be largely true in its modern conception). CSR in developing countries draws strongly on deep-rooted

    indigenous cultural traditions of philanthropy, business ethics, and community embeddedness. Indeed,

    some of these traditions go back to ancient times. (iv) the Socioeconomic priorities: CSR in developing

    countries is most directly shaped by the socio-economic environment in which firms operate and the

    development priorities this creates. (v) the Governance gaps: CSR as a form of governance or a response

    to governance challenges is discussed elsewhere in this book (Levy and Kaplan, Chapter 19). However, of

    particular relevance for developing countries is the fact that CSR is often seen as a way to plug the

    ‘governance gaps’ left by weak, corrupt, or under-resourced governments that fail to adequately provide

    various social services (housing, roads, electricity, health care, education, etc.). This as part of a wider

    trend in developing countries with weak institutions and poor governance, in which responsibility is often

    delegated to private actors, be they family, tribe religion, or, increasingly, business. Furthermore, ‘as

    many developing country government initiatives to improve living conditions falter, proponents of [CSR

    and bottom of the pyramid] strategies argue that companies can assume this role’. The Market access:

    The flipside of the socio-economic priorities driver is to see these unfulfilled human needs as an untapped

    market. This notion underlies the now burgeoning literature on ‘bottom of the pyramid’ strategies, which

    refer to business models that focus on turning the four billion poor people in the world into consumers

    (Prahalad and Hammond, 2002; London and Hart, 2004; Rangan et al., 2007). As study has previously

    noted, this straying of business into the development arena is not without its critics or problems

    (Hardcourt, 2004). CSR may also be seen as an enabler for companies in developing countries trying to

    access markets in the developed world.

    2. External drivers

    These are (i) the International standardization: Despite the debate about the Western imposition of

    CSR approaches on the global South, there is ample evidence that CSR codes and standards are a key

    driver for CSR in developing countries. Codes are also frequently used as a CSR response in sectors that

    are prevalent in developing countries, such as horticulture (Dolan and Opondo, 2005), cocoa (Schrage and

    Ewing, 2005), and textiles (Kaufman et al., 2004), as well as to deal with pressing social issues in

    developing countries, such as child labor (Kolk and Van Tulder, 2002) or the role of women in the

    workplace (Prieto-Carron, 2004). Often, CSR is driven by standardization imposed by multinationals

    International Journal of Information, Business and Management, Vol. 12, No.2, 2020

    ISSN 2076-9202

    193

    striving to achieve global consistency among its subsidiaries and operations in developing countries; (ii)

    The Supply chain: another significant driver for CSR in developing countries, especially among small

    and medium-sized companies, is the requirements that are being imposed by multinationals on their

    supply chains. This trend began with various ethical trading initiatives (Blowfield, 2003, 2004), which led

    to the growth of fair trade auditing and labeling schemes for agricultural products sourced in developing

    countries (Dolan and Opondo, 2005; Schrage and Ewing, 2005). Allegations of poor labor conditions and

    human rights abuses in several high profile multinational supply chains in the sporting and clothing

    sectors were also a significant catalyst for greater attention to CSR requirements (Hussain-Khaliq, 2004;

    Kaufman et al., 2004; Nielsen, 2005). One response has been the development of certifiable standards

    like SA 8000, which is now widely used as a screening mechanism for multinationals in selecting their

    suppliers in developing countries (Kolk and Van Tulder, 2002). Major change has also been achieved

    through sector-based initiatives such as the Forest Stewardship Council for sustainable forestry and the

    Marine Stewardship Council for sustainable fishing. More recently, this driver has been scaled up due to

    the so called ‘Wal-Mart effect’ whereby major global and national retailers are committing to promoting

    sustainability and responsibility through their suppliers (Johnson, 2004). (iii) the Investment incentives:

    the belief that multinational investment is inextricably linked with the social welfare of developing

    countries is not a new phenomenon (Gabriel, 1972). However, increasingly these investments are being

    screened for CSR performance. Hence, socially responsible investment (SRI) is becoming another driver

    for CSR in developing countries. As one indicator of this, Baskin (2006) notes that approximately 8% of

    emerging market companies on the Dow Jones World Index are included in the Dow Jones Sustainability

    Index, compared with around 13% of high-income companies. Exchange also launched its own tradable

    SRI Index, the first of its kind in an emerging market (Sonnenberg et al., 2004). and (iv) the Stakeholder

    activism: in the absence of strong governmental controls over the social, ethical, and environmental

    performance of companies in developing countries, activism by stakeholder groups has become another

    critical driver for CSR. Lund-Thomsen (2004) describes this as ‘an outcome of micro-level struggles

    between companies and communities over the distribution of social and environmental hazards which are

    created when global political and economic forces interact with local contexts around the world’ (p. 106).

    In developing countries, four stakeholder groups emerge as the most powerful activists for CSR,

    namely development agencies (Jenkins, 2005), trade unions (Kaufman et al., 2004), international

    NGOs

    (Christian Aid, 2005), and business associations (WBCSD, 2000). These four groups provide a platform

    of support for local NGOs, which are not always well developed or adequately resourced to provide

    strong advocacy for CSR. The media is also emerging as a key stakeholder for promoting CSR in

    developing countries (Vivarta and Canela, 2006). Stakeholder activism in developing countries takes

    various forms, such as civil regulation, litigation against companies, and international legal instruments.

    2.3.4. Metric aspects of CSR in developing countries

    1. Meaning of Metric aspects of CSR

    Clark et al. (1975) stated that the attraction of CSR, as defined, is that of a systems approach which states

    that the problem is defined and the systems boundary delineated so that all important influences on

    resolving the problem are taken into consideration to the issue of business in society. With hundreds of

    International Journal of Information, Business and Management, Vol. 12, No.2, 2020

    ISSN 2076-9202

    194

    corporation now producing reports, a wide range of laws being implemented around the world, and

    dozens of non-governmental initiatives on transparency and reporting emerging, there is staggering

    variation in what is reported, in what forms, and for which audiences.

    The definition that is most appealing is the stakeholder definition, as put forward by Hopkins: “CSR is

    concerned with treating the stakeholders of the firm ethically or in a socially responsible manner.

    Stakeholders exist both within a firm and outside. The aim of social responsibility is to create higher and

    higher standards of living, while preserving the profitability of the corporation, for its stakeholders both

    within and outside the corporation”. (Hopkins, 2003). Indeed, this definition begs the question what is

    meant by ‘ethical’ and what is meant by ‘stakeholder’.

    On one hand, this study defined corporate social responsibility (CSR) and, on the other hand, it sets up a

    framework to measure it. To date, the measurement systems used and the various concepts of CSR have

    no systematic basis. Indicators seem to be chosen on the whim of the moment. However, at least some

    data now exist to measure progress on social aspects of corporate behavior. In fact, it is even possible to

    use some of the available data that companies now make available in order to hazard a guess to whether

    CSR is getting better or worse.

    Unfortunately, the measurement systems used (of CSR, corporate responsibility or corporate

    sustainability or business ethics or business in society or corporate citizenship) have no systematic

    conceptual basis, rarely define concepts and choose indicators based on the whim of the moment. On the

    other hand, at least some data now exist to measure progress on social aspects of corporate behavior.

    In fact, the measurement of CSR has much improved since the late 1990s, as purported by Hopkins

    (1997). It is even possible to use some of the data that companies now make available to hazard a guess as

    to whether CSR is getting better or worse. However, firstly, it is important to have a look at what is meant

    by a conceptual framework and, then, examine some of the major indicator sets in some detail.

    2. Major indicator sets of CSR measurement

    The Global Reporting Initiative “GRI” carried out an extensive consultation of specialists to define

    indicators to measure progress on social reporting. It recognizes that developing a globally accepted

    reporting framework is a long-term endeavor. It notes that, in comparison, financial reporting is well over

    half a century old and still evolving amidst increasing public attention and scrutiny. The methodology is

    extensively and clearly presented in their report. In fact, the GRI uses the term ‘sustainability reporting’

    synonymously with citizenship reporting, social reporting, triple-bottom line reporting and other terms

    that encompass the economic, environmental, and social aspects of an organization’s performance.

    The table 2 below summarizes the main indicator systems and the study takes Cisco Company as a

    case study example. It is not easy to get in behind the methodologies and indicator sets used by analysts

    and one can wonder what is really being measured.

    Table 2: Main indicator systems of CSR measurement “Workplace, Diversity and Social impact

    indicators”

    Indicat

    ors

    FY05 FY06 FY07 FY08 FY09

    WORKPLACE

    International Journal of Information, Business and Management, Vol. 12, No.2, 2020

    ISSN 2076-9202

    195

    Employee

    satisfaction

    Percentage of

    employee who

    agreed with seven

    statements about

    Cisco as a place to

    work (average)

    81% 85% 86% 87% 90%

    Voluntary

    employee

    attrition

    Total voluntary

    attrition as

    percentage of

    ending headcount

    4.59% 5.45% 4.52% 5.01% 3.22%

    Health and

    Safety

    (operations

    only US and

    Canada)

    Number of nonfatal

    injuries and

    illnesses

    129 107 93 137 145

    DIVERSITY

    Women Women as

    percentage of

    total global

    employees

    21.8% 22.1% 23% 23.5% 23.4%

    Women in

    VP positions

    or above as

    percentage of

    global VP

    and above

    employees

    13.2% 14.0% 12.7% 15.5% 15.5%

    Ethnic

    minorities

    (US only)

    Ethnic

    minorities as

    percentage of

    total US

    employees

    42.3% 42.8% 43.7% 44.7% 45.6%

    Ethnic

    minorities in

    VP positions

    and above as

    percentage of

    total US. VP

    and above

    17.6% 17.5% 15.6% 22.2% 20.8%

    International Journal of Information, Business and Management, Vol. 12, No.2, 2020

    ISSN 2076-9202

    196

    employees

    SOCIAL IMPACT

    Social

    investment

    Total corporate

    wide and

    foundation cash

    and in-kind

    contributions

    $65

    million

    $115.5

    millio

    n

    $116.8

    million

    $92

    million

    $128.6

    million
    Employee

    volunteerism

    Number of

    active students

    in

    Cisco

    networking

    academy

    courses

    235,00

    0

    160,0

    00

    130,000 88,870 78,000

    Cisco
    networking
    academy

    Cisco leaders

    who share their

    expertise with

    nonprofit

    organizations

    596,84

    0

    597,0

    85

    637,304 716,936 810,000

    Leadership

    fellows

    Number of

    countries or

    regions where

    Cisco currently

    invests or

    manages

    programs

    5 8 17 20 13

    Social and

    economic

    investment

    Significant

    collaborations

    with corporate

    partners,

    nonprofits and

    NGOs

    160 160+ 160+ 160+ 165+

    Strategic

    partners

    31 36 34 41 58

    Source: Corporate Social Responsibility Report (2009), “CSR Key Performance Indicators”, Cisco

    Systems, Inc.

    International Journal of Information, Business and Management, Vol. 12, No.2, 2020

    ISSN 2076-9202

    197

    Table 3: Main indicator systems of CSR measurement “Environmental management; GHG

    emissions; energy and electricity usage; product return and recycling; and water consumption

    indicator”

    Indicators FY06 FY07 FY08 FY09

    ENVIRONMENTAL MANAGEMENT

    Number of Cisco sites with ISO

    14001 EMS certification

    19 25 25 26

    Employee base covered by ISO

    14001 EMS certification

    75% 73% 71% 68%

    GHG EMISSIONS

    Total gross GHG emissions:

    Scope 1 (metric tonne CO2 c)

    27,586 52,496 52,084 53,216

    Total gross GHG emissions:

    Scope 2 (metric tonne CO2 c)

    317,666 467,478 550,312 579,183

    Total contractual GHG emissions:

    Scope 2 (metric tonne CO2 c)

    316,893 403,188 310,961 226,733

    Total air travel GHG emissions:

    Scope 3 (metric tonne CO2 c)

    190,940 205,797 197,872 115,995

    Change in air travel GHG emissions

    from FY06 (CGI global goal: 10%

    absolute reduction against FY06

    baseline)

    +8% +4% +3%

    Total contractual GHG emissions:

    Scope 1, 2 and 3 1 metric tonne CO2

    c

    535,419 661,483 560,917 395,944

    Change in Scope 1, 2 and 3 from

    FY07 (EPA global 26% absolute

    reduction against CY07 baseline)

    – – -15% -40% (goal

    year is

    2012)

    ENERGY AND ELECTRICITY USAGE

    Energy usage (GWh) 889
    tc

    1281 1438 1507

    Electricity usage (GWh) 749
    tc

    1053 1203 1275

    PRODUCT RETURN AND RECYCLING

    Product return (million pounds) – – 22.1 23.6

    Materials to landfill (percent of

    returned product not reused or

    recycled)

    – – 0.46% 0.44%

    WATER CONSUMPTION

    Total water consumption (m
    3
    ) Not

    available

    1,726,618 1,570,831 1,654,030

    International Journal of Information, Business and Management, Vol. 12, No.2, 2020

    ISSN 2076-9202

    198

    Source: Corporate Social Responsibility Report (2009), “CSR Key Performance Indicators”, Cisco
    Systems, Inc.

    Although data are not generally available for many companies at once individual companies often

    present comprehensive sets no consistent pattern of data collection and presentation has emerged. As the

    CSR community has become more watchful and social investment funds more demanding, the need for

    an overall index of progress on CSR has emerged. Several of the above-mentioned data systems have

    attempted to provide indices and rankings of companies.

    Initial attempts to measure progress on CSR based upon these indices have also emerged. However,

    the indices that have emerged measure averages across companies. And, as noted in this paper,

    consistency of application remains a problem. Moreover, the challenge that is more and more being

    presented is how to embed the ideas of CSR throughout an organization. This is the problem that many

    companies face. It is possible to obtain indicators that show a good record ‘on average’ but difficult to

    embed the ideas of CSR throughout an organization and no one to date has produced disaggregated

    indicators across the company. The lack of indicators of a consistent and disaggregated level leads to poor

    monitoring and evaluation systems. That is probably why scandals will continue to erupt in supposedly

    ‘clean’ organizations.

    For organizations to have relatively good data on the economic aspects but very poor information

    on the social dimensions implies that the basic conceptual model has been weak. Hence, for the future, a

    better model of social data, to be based upon hard or interval scale data is a necessary requisite. Much of

    today’s information is founded upon weaker nominal or, at best, ordinal scale data and the proposed

    framework is no exception. Therefore, in order to ensure the same type of robust yardsticks found in

    economics, such as profit, sales, costs and so on though problems can arise with these it is important to

    develop, through a significant effort for the social arena, new conceptual models from which harder data

    can be derived. For corporate social responsibility, it is still the early days of relevant performance

    measurement and ‘metrics’ in societal terms.

    2.4.Challenges of CSR in developing countries

    There are a number of major challenges to making CSR reporting effective. Questions remain in

    different sectors and countries on what to report, in what form, to what level of detail, to what audiences,

    and for what uses. There are also weaknesses and problems with current systems of CSR reporting, and

    important barriers to expanding public disclosure systems around the world. These include problems of: (i)

    metrics and Materiality; (ii) timeliness and Usefulness of Information; (iii) incentives to Disclose; (iv)

    supply Chain Monitoring; (v) costs to Information Producers and Users; and (vi) analyzing and

    Translating Information for end users.

    3. Theoretical and empirical Evidences of CSR in developing countries

    3.1.Theoretical model of CSR in developing countries

    Indeed, taking into account two main variables of this study (CSR and developing countries), the

    study proposed a theoretical model adapted to these two variables. This model is used to analyze the

    management of CSR in developing countries as a tools and strategies of sustainable development and also

    International Journal of Information, Business and Management, Vol. 12, No.2, 2020

    ISSN 2076-9202

    199

    to the data available to meet the concerns of the study. Thus, the theoretical model proposed by Carroll

    could be presented as the figure below is presented. This consists of four-part model construct that can be

    useful to look at how CSR is manifested in a developing country context:

    Figure 9: Model construction of CSR in developing countries (Carroll, 1991)

    Source: Author adapted from Carroll, 1991

    3.1.1. Economic responsibilities

    It is well known that many developing countries suffer from a shortage of foreign direct investment,

    as well as from high unemployment and widespread poverty. It is no surprise, therefore, that the economic

    contribution of companies in developing countries is highly prized, by governments and communities

    alike. This should not be seen in a negative light, but rather as a more development-oriented approach to

    CSR that focuses on the enabling environment for responsible business in developing countries and that

    brings economic and equity aspects of sustainable development.

    Hence, in developing countries, CSR tends to stress the importance of ‘economic multipliers’,

    including the capacity to generate investment and income, produce safe products and services, create jobs,

    invest in human capital, establish local business linkages, spread international business standards, support

    technology transfer and build physical and institutional infrastructure (Nelson, 2003).

    For this reason, companies that operate in developing countries increasingly report on their

    economic responsibilities by constructing ‘economic value added’ statements. It is worth re-emphasizing

    as a caveat that economic responsibility has two faces economic contribution on the one side and

    economic dependence on the other.

    When communities or countries become overly dependent on multinationals for their economic

    welfare, there is the risk of governments compromising ethical, social, or environmental standards in

    order to retain their investment, or suffering huge social disruption if those businesses do decide to

    disinvest.

    International Journal of Information, Business and Management, Vol. 12, No.2, 2020

    ISSN 2076-9202

    200

    3.1.2. Philanthropic responsibilities

    Although philanthropy generally gets an even higher priority as a manifestation of CSR,

    philanthropic responsibility tends more often to be more compulsory via the legal framework than

    discretionary acts of successful companies or rich capitalists as USA. This is a result of strong indigenous

    traditions of philanthropy in developing countries. There are several other reasons as well:

    Firstly, the socio-economic needs of the developing countries in which companies operate are so

    great that philanthropy is an expected norm it is considered the right thing to do by business.

    Secondly, companies realize that they cannot succeed in societies that fail, and philanthropy is seen

    as the most direct way to improve the prospects of the communities in which their businesses operate. For

    example, the HIV/AIDS disease is a case in point, where the response by business is essentially

    philanthropic (it is not an occupational disease), but clearly in companies’ own medium- to long-term

    economic interest.

    Thirdly, over the past 50 years, many developing countries have become reliant on foreign aid or

    donor assistance. Hence, there is often an ingrained culture of philanthropy.

    And a final reason for developing countries’ prioritization of philanthropy is that they are generally

    still at an early stage of maturity in CSR, sometimes even equating CSR and philanthropy, rather than

    embracing the more embedded approaches now common in developed countries.

    3.1.3. Legal responsibilities

    In developing countries, legal responsibilities generally have a lower priority than in developed

    countries. This does not necessarily mean that companies flaunt the law, but there is far less pressure for

    good conduct. This is because, in many developing countries, the legal infrastructure is poorly developed,

    and often lacks independence, resources, and administrative efficiency.

    Many developing countries are also behind the developed world in terms of incorporating human

    rights and other issues relevant to CSR into their legislation (Mwaura 2004). Admittedly, there are

    exceptions and some developing countries have seen significant progress in strengthening the social and

    environmental aspects of their legislation (Visser, 2005b). However, government capacity for enforcement

    remains a serious limitation, and reduces the effectiveness of legislation as a driver for CSR.

    Hence, several scholars argue that tax avoidance by companies is one of the most significant

    examples of irresponsible business behavior in developing countries, often contradicting their CSR claims

    of good conduct (Christensen and Murphy, 2004).

    3.1.4. Ethical Responsibilities

    In developing countries, however, ethics seems to have the least influence on the CSR. This is not to

    say that developing countries have been untouched by the global trend towards improved governance

    (Reed, 2002). For example, the 1992 and 2002 King Reports on Corporate Governance in South Africa

    have both led the world in their inclusion of CSR issues (IoD, 1992, 2002). On one hand, the 1992 King

    Report was the first global corporate governance code to talk about ‘stakeholders’ and to stress the

    importance of business accountability beyond the interests of shareholders. On the other hand, the 2002

    revised King Report was the first to include a section on ‘integrated sustainability reporting’, covering

    International Journal of Information, Business and Management, Vol. 12, No.2, 2020

    ISSN 2076-9202

    201

    social, transformation, ethical, safety, health, and environmental management policies and practices.

    This progress is certainly encouraging, but in general, it is still the exception rather than the rule.

    For instance, in “Transparency International’s annual Corruption Perception Index and Global Corruption

    Barometer”, developing countries usually make up the bulk of the most poorly ranked countries.

    Furthermore, survey respondents from these countries generally agree that corruption still affects business

    to a large extent. The World Bank’s (2005) Investment Climate Survey paints a similar picture. For

    example, the corruption in developing countries has been the “UK-led Extractive Industries Transparency

    Initiative (EITI)”, which aims to increase transparency over payments by companies to governments and

    government-linked entities, as well as transparency over revenues by those host country governments.

    This is clearly a step in the right direction, but the refusal of countries like Angola to even

    participate shows that there is still a long way to go in embedding ethical responsibilities in developing

    countries.

    3.2.Government implication on CSR in developing countries

    To date, CSR in developing countries has largely been driven from the north, often by large

    multinational firms, private investors, or non-governmental organizations. Nonetheless, there are

    important roles for governments, and particularly developing country governments, to play in further

    advancing reporting systems. The World Bank has previously grouped government roles in supporting

    corporate social responsibility into five categories of action: mandating, facilitating, partnering, endorsing,

    and demonstrating.

    Each of these strategies of action can support improvements of CSR in developing countries.

    Governments, and their citizens, however, must decide how they can most effectively support an

    environment for socially responsible business, and specifically advance CSR reporting.

    3.2.1. Pilot project on CSR in developing countries

    There is clear potential for government action, particularly in developing countries, to advance and

    strengthen CSR reporting. However, in thinking about designing an appropriate and effective disclosure

    system in a developing country, it is also critical to recognize that there are no perfect systems, no easily

    replicable programs, and no one-size-fits-all standards for reporting.

    By starting with a small set of core indicators, verifying that they are material to stakeholders,

    evaluating uses of the information, and soliciting feedback on the quality of the data, it would be possible

    to gradually expand and deepen CSR indicators to include sector specific issues. By having reporting be

    driven by local concerns and capacities, it would also be possible to gradually connect to and compare

    against global reporting schemes.

    Government agencies and NGOs could play a key role in verifying CSR reporting information in

    developing countries, and gradually working to improve the credibility and accountability of reporting.

    Finally, a government agency could work to aggregate data, and to produce a national CSR report.

    This information would support future comparisons of country-level performance on CSR issues. The

    program could also help local firms establish and demonstrate their social and environmental performance,

    and facilitate socially and environmentally responsible firms connecting into high value supply chains.

    International Journal of Information, Business and Management, Vol. 12, No.2, 2020

    ISSN 2076-9202

    202

    Nowadays, governments take steps to advance CSR in developing countries or to experiment with

    reporting as strategy of governance and economic development. This study is meant as a starting point for

    thinking about steps needed to pilot test CSR reporting in a developing country. Countries interested in

    CSR reporting might: (i) Interview local stakeholders and investors about the information: they need to

    make critical decisions; (ii) establish a central coordinating office to set guidelines for reporting, then

    collect, collate, quality check, and compare information on facility performance; (iii) require firms to

    publicly disclose locations of factories; (iv) require firms to annually report performance criteria in a

    standardized format; (v) establish a central database accessible over the internet which would contain

    performance information on factories and simple means for comparing firms along selected criteria, such

    as wages, health and safety, labor practices, environmental performance, etc.; (v) create mechanisms for

    public comparison of firm performance; (vi) publish lists of “best practices” and the firms that employ

    them; (vi) publish a CSR sourcing book of leading local firms and distribute this to multinational

    corporations, investors and trade associations for assistance in matching MNCs with local suppliers that

    meet their CSR standards; (vii) Use publicity to motivate firms to improve performance to match the best

    practices identified in their industry; (viii) support capacity building of non-governmental groups to verify

    reporting; (ix) aggregate firm level performance data to show overall compliance rates, regional

    variations, improvements over time, and best practices in social and environmental performance within

    the country in investment marketing to foreign firms.

    An effective pilot project should be designed as an open system that invites key stakeholders to take

    part in discussions about measures of performance and systems of reporting. For the sake of providing a

    starting point for further discussions, firms might disclose a number of standards “core indicators” of

    facility performance, and indicators specific to sectorial issues and concerns (World Bank, 2005).

    3.2.2. Toward the Strategies for improving CSR in developing countries

    There are some basic principles which can support efforts to advance and improve CSR reporting: (i)

    reporting initiatives should seek to increase the quality of information disclosed; (ii) they should work to

    increase the uses of the information and the benefits to users; (iii) they should create mechanisms for

    learning and continuously improving disclosure systems.

    These goals can be supported through explicit efforts to target information to specific stakeholders

    and decision-making processes. Information should be reported in formats useful to specific users. And

    efforts should be made to verify that information is used by stakeholders to inform their decisions.

    1. Standardized metrics

    Continued work is needed on standardized metrics and indicators for reporting. However, metrics in

    general should be: (i) Agreed upon by key stakeholders (representing what matters to them); (ii) Factual,

    accurate, and verifiable; (iii) Reported at regular intervals in relatively simple language or data; (iv)

    Comparable across locations, firms, and products; (v) Flexible/dynamic, so that metrics can change over

    time; (vi) Usable by key stakeholders; (vii) Easily accessible.

    2. Incentives for continuous improvement

    International Journal of Information, Business and Management, Vol. 12, No.2, 2020

    ISSN 2076-9202

    203

    Efforts are also needed to support continuous improvements in reporting. As mentioned,

    intermediary groups are critical to analyzing and deploying information, and perhaps more importantly, to

    creating demands for improved reporting.

    Stakeholder groups with built-in incentives for using, analyzing, and monitoring the quality of the

    information are central to the long-term sustainability of reporting schemes. In financial disclosure,

    investors play this role of demanding high quality, verifiable information upon which to base their

    investments. In environmental disclosure (such as the TRI), environmental groups use the data, translate it

    for wider consumption, and keep pressure on the government and firms to improve reporting. No

    equivalent group currently exists for CSR in developing countries, or indeed social reporting. Disclosure

    systems can also be designed to create incentives and benefits for leading disclosers. Governments can

    foster certain kinds of disclosure through a range of traditional economic incentives, and through

    regulatory flexibility mechanisms.

    Finally, in any system of disclosure it is critical to establish mechanisms to track changes in

    practices over time, their impacts, and whether learning is occurring from reporting. All of these strategies

    can be supported or directly advanced through government actions.

    3. Possible “core indicators”

    These are: (i) name and location of factory and number of employees; (ii) incidence of violations of

    local laws, penalties, legal proceedings, etc. in the last year; (iii) wages and benefits paid to workers

    (averages, minimum, highest), and incidence of violations of minimum wage laws; (iv) working hours

    and overtime worked: incidence of violations of maximum working hour laws and overtime pay laws; (v)

    policies for identification and elimination of harassment and discrimination: data on diversity in

    management and work areas; (vi) policies for identification and elimination of child, forced , and

    compulsory labor (including system for determining accurate age of workers); (vii) indicators of respect

    for workers’ rights to freedom of association: percent of workers in a union, union-management relations,

    work stoppages, lock-outs, strikes, etc.; (viii) health and safety performance: rates of accident, injuries,

    occupational diseases and deaths; (ix) policies for monitoring compliance with local laws and codes of

    conduct.

    4. An ideal CSR’ management for developing countries

    The descriptive approach adopted in the previous sections was used to illustrate how CSR actually

    manifests in developing countries, rather than presenting an aspirational view of what CSR in developing

    countries should look like. For example, it is not proposed that legal and ethical responsibilities should

    get such a low priority, but rather that they do in practice.

    By contrast, if the study is to work towards an ideal CSR model for CSR in developing countries,

    we would argue that improved ethical responsibilities, incorporating good governance, should be assigned

    the highest CSR priority in developing countries. It is my contention that governance reform holds the

    key to improvements in all the other dimensions, including economic development, rule of law, and

    voluntary action. Hence, embracing more transparent, ethical governance practices should form the

    foundation of CSR practice in developing countries, which in turn will provide the enabling environment

    International Journal of Information, Business and Management, Vol. 12, No.2, 2020

    ISSN 2076-9202

    204

    for more widespread responsible business (figure 8).

    Figure 8: Map of CSR in developing countries

    Source: World Bank’s (2005)

    4. Conclusion

    From the outset, it should be recalled that this study focused on the demonstration of the

    management of a CSR in developing countries across the world for a sustainable development. The

    results gathered from this research allow us to highlight the essential ideas closely related to the two

    essential aspects of the field of the study analysis. As we can see from above, it has been about presenting,

    analyzing and interpreting the results to allow us to test the central research question and their different

    research hypotheses.

    According to the different findings, this study is summarizing CSR in developing countries in the

    five distinctive characteristics: (i) CSR tend to be less formalized or institutionalized in terms of the CSR

    benchmarks commonly used in developed countries, i.e. CSR codes, standards, management systems and

    reports; (ii) where formal CSR is practiced, this is usually by large, high profile national and

    multinational companies, especially those with recognized international brands or those aspiring to global

    status; (iii) formal CSR codes, standards, and guidelines that are most applicable to developing countries

    tend to be issue specific (e.g. fair trade, supply chain, HIV/AIDS) or sector-led (e.g. agriculture, textiles,

    mining); (iv) In developing countries, CSR is most commonly associated with philanthropy or charity, i.e.

    through corporate social investment in education, health, sports development, the environment, and other

    community services and (v) making an economic contribution is often seen as the most important and

    effective way for business to make a social impact, i.e. through investment, job creation, taxes, and

    technology transfer.

    Business often finds itself engaged in the provision of social services that would be seen as

    government’s responsibility in developed countries, for example, investment in infrastructure, schools,

    hospitals, and housing.

    The issues being prioritized under the CSR banner are often different in developing countries, for

    example, tackling HIV/AIDS, improving working conditions, provision of basic services, supply chain

    integrity, and poverty alleviation. Many of the CSR issues in developing countries present themselves as

    International Journal of Information, Business and Management, Vol. 12, No.2, 2020

    ISSN 2076-9202

    205

    dilemmas or trade-offs, for example, development versus environment, job creation versus higher labor

    standards, and strategic philanthropy versus political governance.

    The spirit and practice of CSR is often strongly resonant with traditional communitarian values and

    religious concepts in developing countries, for example, African humanism (ubuntu) in South Africa and

    harmonious society (xiaokang) in China. The focus on CSR in developing countries can be a catalyst for

    identifying, designing and testing new CSR frameworks and business models, for example, Praha lad’s

    Bottom of the Pyramid model and Visser’s CSR Model for Developing Countries.

    References

    Baker, M. (2004) Corporate Social Responsibility: What does it mean? Available

    at: http://www.mallenbaker.net/csr/definition.php

    Baskin, J. (2006). Corporate Responsibility in Emerging Markets. Journal of Corporate Citizenship, 24, winter: 29–47.

    Blowfield, M. and Frynas, J. G. (2005). ‘Setting New Agendas: Critical Perspectives on Corporate Social Responsibility in the

    Developing World’. International Affairs, 81(3): 499–513.

    Clark, J., Cole, S., Curnow, R. and Hopkins, M. (1975) Global Simulation Models, John Wiley, New York.

    Carroll, A. B. (1991). ‘The Pyramid of Corporate Social Responsibility: Toward the Moral Management of Organizational

    Stakeholders’. Business Horizons, 34: 39–48.

    Christensen, J., and Murphy, R. (2004). ‘The Social Irresponsibility of Corporate Tax Avoidance: Taking CSR to the Bottom

    Line’. Development, 47(3): 37–44.

    Dolan, C. S., and Opondo, M. (2005). Seeking Common Ground: Multi-stakeholder Processes in Kenya’s Cut Flower Industry’.

    Journal of Corporate Citizenship, 18, summer: 87–98.

    Fig, D. (2005). Manufacturing Amnesia: Corporate Social Responsibility in South Africa’. International Affairs, 81(3): 599–

    617.

    Frynas, J. G. (2006). Corporate Social Responsibility in Emerging Economies’. Journal of Corporate Citizenship, 24, winter:

    16–19.

    Gabriel, P. P. (1972). ‘MNCs in the Third World: Is Conflict Unavoidable?’ Harvard Business Review. 50(4): 93–102.

    Glaser, B.G. and Strauss, A.L.: 1967, The discovery of Grounded Theory: strategy for Qualitative Research (Weidenfed and

    Nicolson).

    Graves, S. and Waddock, S. (1999) Beyond Built to Last … Stakeholder Relations in ‘Built-to-Last’ Companies, Boston

    College Carroll School of Management, Chestnut Hill, MA.

    Hardcourt, W. (2004). ‘Editorial: Is CSR Rewriting Development?’ Development, 47(3): 1–2.

    Hoffman, A. J. (2005). ‘Climate Change Strategy: The Business Logic Behind Voluntary Greenhouse Gas Reductions’.

    California Management Review, 47(3): 21–46.

    International Journal of Information, Business and Management, Vol. 12, No.2, 2020

    ISSN 2076-9202

    206

    Hess, D.: 1999 ‘Social Reporting: A reflexive law approach to corporate social responsiveness’ Journal of Corporate Law, Fall,

    25 (1), 41-85.

    Hopkins, M. (1997) ‘Defining indicators to assess socially responsible enterprises’, Futures, Vol. 29, No. 7, pp.581–603.

    Hopkins, M. (1999) The Planetary Bargain – Corporate Social Responsibility Comes of Age, Macmillan Press, Basingstoke.

    Hopkins, M. (2003) The Planetary Bargain – Corporate Social Responsibility Matters, Earthscan, London.

    Hopkins, M.: 2000, ‘The measurement of corporate social responsibility’ MHC International Limited News November 2000.

    IMF (2006). World Economic Outlook: Financial Systems and Economic Cycles. Brussels: International Monetary Fund.

    IoD (1992). King Report on Corporate Governance in South Africa. Johannesburg: Institute of Directors in Southern Africa.

    – (2002). King Report on Corporate Governance in South Africa. Johannesburg: Institute of Directors in Southern Africa.

    Ite, U. E. (2004). ‘Multinationals and Corporate Social Responsibility in Developing Countries: A Case Study of Nigeria’.

    Corporate Social Responsibility and Environmental Management, 11(1): 1–11.

    Jenkins, R. (2005). ‘Globalization, Corporate Social Responsibility and Poverty’. International Affairs, 81(3): 525–40.

    Johnson, M. (2004). ‘Marks & Spencer Implements an Ethical Sourcing Program for its Global Supply Chain’. Journal of

    Organizational Excellence, 23(2): 3–16.

    Kaufman, A., Tiantubtim, E., Pussayapibul, N., and Davids, P. (2004). ‘Implementing Voluntary Labour Standards and Codes

    of Conduct in the Thai Garment Industry’. Journal of Corporate Citizenship, 13, spring: 91–9.

    Kolk, A., and Van Tulder, R. (2002). ‘Child Labour and Multinational Conduct: A Comparison of International Business and

    Stakeholder Codes’. Journal of Business Ethics, 36: 291–301.

    Lockett, A., Moon, J., and Visser, W. (2006). ‘Corporate Social Responsibility in Management Research: Focus, Nature,

    Salience, and Sources of Influence’. Journal of Management Studies, 43(1): 115–36.

    London, T., and Hart, S. L. (2004). ‘Reinventing Strategies for Emerging Markets: Beyond the Transnational Model’. Journal

    of International Business Studies, 35(5): 350–70.

    Lund-Thomsen, P. (2004) Towards a Critical Framework on Corporate Social and Environmental Responsibility in the South:

    The Case of Pakistan. Development, 47(3): 106–113.

    Malan, D. (2005) Corporate Citizens, Colonialists, Tourists or Activists? Ethical Challenges facing South African Corporations

    in Africa. Journal of Corporate Citizenship, 18, summer: 49–60.

    Moon, J. (2002b). ‘Corporate Social Responsibility: An Overview. In C. Hartley, The International Directory of Corporate

    Philanthropy. London and New York: Europa Publications, 3–14.

    Mwaura, K. (2004). Corporate Citizenship: The Changing Legal Perspective in Kenya. Interdisciplinary CSR Research

    Conference, Nottingham, International Centre for Corporate Social Responsibility (ICCSR).

    International Journal of Information, Business and Management, Vol. 12, No.2, 2020

    ISSN 2076-9202

    207

    Nielsen, M. E. (2005). ‘The Politics of Corporate Responsibility and Child Labour in the Bangladeshi Garment Industry’.

    International Affairs, 81(3): 559–80.

    Okana, “Course of Management”, Catholic University of Congo, Kinshasa, 2011-2012.

    Prahalad, C. K., and Hammond, A. (2002). ‘Serving the World’s Poor, Profitably’. Harvard Business Review, 80(9): 48–57.

    Prasad, B. C. (2004). ‘Globalisation, Free Trade and Corporate Citizenship in Pacific Forum Island Countries’. Journal of

    Corporate Citizenship, 13, spring: 65–76.

    Prieto-Carron, M. (2004). ‘Is there Anyone Listening? Women Workers in Factories in Central America, and Corporate Codes

    of Conduct’. Development, 47(3): 101–5.

    Rangan, V. K., Quelch, J. A., Herrero, G., and Barton, B. (eds.) 2007. Business Solutions for the Global Poor: Creating Social

    and Economic Value. San Franciso: Jossey-Bass.

    Reed, D. (2002). ‘Corporate Governance Reforms in Developing Countries’. Journal of Business Ethics, 37: 223–47

    Schmidheiny, S. (2006). ‘A View of Corporate Citizenship in Latin America’. Journal of Corporate Citizenship, 21, spring:

    21–4.

    Schrage, E. J., and Ewing, A. P. (2005). ‘The Cocoa Industry and Child Labour’. Journal of Corporate Citizenship, 18,

    summer: 99–112.

    UN, (2006). Millennium Development Goals Report 2006. Brussels: United Nations.

    UNDP, (2006). Beyond Scarcity: Power, Poverty and the Global Water Crisis. Brussels: United Nations Development

    Programe.

    Visser, W.:

    – (2005a). ‘Corporate Citizenship in South Africa: A Review of Progress Since Democracy’. Journal of Corporate

    Citizenship, 18, summer: 29–38.

    – (2005b). ‘Is South Africa World Class in Corporate Citizenship?’ in A. Freemantle (ed.), The Good Corporate Citizen.

    Johannesburg: Trialogue.

    – (2006a). ‘Research on Corporate Citizenship in Africa: A Ten-Year Review (1995–2005). In Visser et al. (2000b).

    – (2006b). ‘Revisiting Carroll’s CSR Pyramid: An African Perspective’. In Pedersen and Huniche (2006), 29–56.

    – (2007b). ‘Revisiting Carroll’s CSR Pyramid’. In Crane and Matten.

    Visser, W. and Macintosh, A. (1998) A Short Review of the Historical Critique of Usury’. Accounting, Business & Financial

    History, 8(2): 175–89.

    Vivarta, V., and Canela, G., (2006). Corporate Social Responsibility in Brazil: The Role of the Press as Watchdog. Journal of

    Corporate Citizenship, 21, spring: 95–106.

    International Journal of Information, Business and Management, Vol. 12, No.2, 2020

    ISSN 2076-9202

    208

    WBCSD (2000). Corporate Social Responsibility: Making Good Business Sense. Geneva: WBCSD.

    Willi, A. (2014). Corporate Social Responsibility in Developing Country: An illustrate analysis”, University of Bath,

    September.

    Wood, D. (1994) Business and Society, Harper Collins, New York.

    World Bank (2005). Investment Climate Survey. Washington: World Bank.

    – (2006) World Development Report 2007: Development and the Next Generation. Washington: World Bank.

    WRI (2005). World Resources 2005: The Wealth of the Poor: Managing Ecosystems to Fight Poverty. Washington: D.C.,

    World Resources Institute, UNDP, UNEP, World Bank.

    Reproduced with permission of copyright owner. Further reproduction
    prohibited without permission.

    Vol:.(1234567890)

    Experimental Economic

    s

    (2020) 23:154–180
    https://doi.org/10.1007/s10683-019-09604-3

    1 3

    O R I G I N A L PA P E R

    Strategic decisions: behavioral differences between CEOs
    and other

    s

    Håkan J. Holm1  · Victor Nee2 · Sonja Opper1

    Received: 17 March 2018 / Revised: 16 February 2019 / Accepted: 19 February 2019 /
    Published online: 25 February 2019
    © The Author(s) 2019

    Abstract
    We study whether CEOs of private firms differ from other people with regard to
    their strategic decisions and beliefs about others’ strategy choices. Such differ-
    ences are interesting since CEOs make decisions that are economically more rel-
    evant, because they affect not only their own utility or the well-being of household
    members, but the utility of many stakeholders inside and outside of the organization.
    They also play a central role in shaping values and norms in society. We expect
    differences between both groups, because CEOs are more experienced with strate-
    gic decision making than comparable people in other professional roles. Yet, due to
    the difficulties in recruiting this high-profile group for academic research, few stud-
    ies have explored how CEOs make incentivized decisions in strategic games under
    strict controls and how their choices in such games differ from those made by oth-
    ers. Our study combines a stratified random sample of 200 CEOs of medium-sized
    firms with a carefully selected control group of 200 comparable people. All subjects
    participated in three incentivized games—Prisoner’s Dilemma, Chicken, Battle-of-
    the-Sexes. Beliefs were elicited for each game. We report substantial and robust dif-
    ferences in both behavior and beliefs between the CEOs and the control group. The
    most striking results are that CEOs do not best respond to beliefs; they cooperate
    more, play less hawkish and thereby earn much more than the control group.

    A preliminary version of this paper has been presented at the Department of Sociology at Cornell
    University, the ESA European Meeting in Prague, the Nordic Conference on Behavioral and
    Experimental Behavior in Aarhus, the Department of Economics at the University of Würzburg,
    the Meeting of the French Experimental Economic Association in Paris, the Department of
    Economics at the University of Rostock, the Berlin Behavioral Economics Seminar at WZB and
    at the Workshop on Experimental Economics and Entrepreneurship at CBS in Copenhagen. We
    are grateful for valuable comments from the audience on these presentations. Financial support is
    gratefully acknowledged from the Jan Wallander’s and Tom Hedelius’ Foundation, the Crafoord
    Foundation, the Knut Wicksell Center of Financial Studies, The Swedish Competition Authority,
    and the John Templeton Foundation.

    Electronic supplementary material The online version of this article (https ://doi.org/10.1007/s1068
    3-019-09604 -3) contains supplementary material, which is available to authorized users.

    Extended author information available on the last page of the article

    http://orcid.org/0000-0001-5783-2463

    http://crossmark.crossref.org/dialog/?doi=10.1007/s10683-019-09604-3&domain=pdf

    https://doi.org/10.1007/s10683-019-09604-3

    https://doi.org/10.1007/s10683-019-09604-3

    155

    1 3

    Strategic decisions: behavioral differences between CEOs…

    Keywords CEOs · Strategic decision-making · Belief elicitation

    JEL Classification C70 · C90 · D22 · L26

    1 Introduction

    One aim of game theory is to understand the strategic decisions of important actors
    in the economy (e.g., Von Neumann and Morgenstern 1944; Tirole 1988). Yet, only
    a few experimental studies have employed subject pools representing important
    decision-makers. In this paper, we focus on business leaders and compare their strat-
    egy choices and beliefs with those of a control group of other professionals. The
    study of CEOs’ strategic decisions is a natural choice given their prominent role in
    economic decision making as firm leaders whose actions have significant implica-
    tions for other stakeholders (employees, suppliers, clients, and the local economy at
    large).1 They are also likely to play an important role in transmitting values, norms
    and beliefs to other economic actors (e.g., employees, politicians and business part-
    ners).Their greater experience in strategic performance would suggest that they
    could differ in their strategic decision making from other people. For sure, people
    who are not CEOs also make strategic decisions, but the type and impact of these
    decisions tend to be more limited, influencing the well-being of individuals living in
    the same household rather than a large number of external stakeholders.

    Whether and how CEOs differ behaviorally from others is an empirical question.2
    A priori, one can think of many mechanisms that might make a CEO’s strategic
    behavior different from that of other people. Overall, one would expect that com-
    petitive forces weed out irrational CEOs so that surviving CEOs choose strategies
    which are best responses to each other; that is, they constitute Nash equilibria. Such
    a mechanism is plausible if the Nash equilibria are evolutionary stable strategies
    (Maynard Smith 1982). There are also strategic situations (e.g., prisoner’s dilemmas)
    where individually rational choices according to the non-cooperative Nash paradigm
    lead to a detrimental outcome for the involved parties, and where instead prosocial
    or efficiency-oriented choices are favored (Bowles and Gintis 2011). Examples of
    situations where the benefit of cooperation and prosocial behavior are evident for
    CEOs include joint ventures and investments in infrastructure. Hence, another mech-
    anism is social norms favoring efficient strategy choices that maximize the sum of
    the involved parties’ payoffs. Such behavior can be sustained by welfare-maximizing

    1 Although this paper investigates differences between CEOs and others, we do not claim that CEOs
    comprise a homogenous group, for of course CEOs differ from each other in various respects, including
    management style, and that this may affect how they run their firms (e.g., Bertrand and Schoar 2003). We
    also alert readers who associate the term “CEO” with an externally recruited top manager to the fact that
    most of our CEOs, in contrast, both own and have founded their firms.
    2 It is not difficult to find two opposing perspectives: one warm and bright—portraying business lead-
    ers as socially responsible actors who contribute to social welfare —and, one cold and dark, portraying
    entrepreneurs as selfish profiteers (e.g., Van de Ven et al. 2007; Benabou and Tirole 2010).

    156 H. J. Holm et al.

    1 3

    norms in close-knit groups (Ellickson 1991) and/or altruistic preferences through
    assortative matching (Bergstrom 2002; Alger and Weibull 2013).

    Various empirical studies have investigated the strategic decision making of
    professionals (e.g., Cooper et  al. 1999; Palacios-Huerta and Volij 2008, Fréchette
    2015); but because high-level professionals are hard to recruit, few studies (e.g.,
    Fehr and List 2004) investigate incentivized choices in well-defined strategic games
    with CEOs. The present study is the first to investigate CEOs’ choices in not just one
    but several incentivized strategic situations that capture fundamental problems of
    cooperation and coordination in business. In addition, this study is also the first to
    combine group comparisons with belief elicitations allowing us to study the impact,
    accuracy of beliefs and best responses to beliefs. This will allow us to test if expe-
    rienced CEOs best respond to their own beliefs, which is a fundamental implicit
    assumption in many modern models of industrial organization. Our sampling strat-
    egy lends high credibility to the results presented here. In contrast to earlier studies
    that use convenience samples (for the obvious reason that business leaders are dif-
    ficult to recruit to perform experimental tasks), we use a stratified random sample of
    CEOs managing firms with ten or more full-time employees. The control group of
    other professionals was sampled to match core demographics of the CEOs. Finally,
    our samples are relatively large compared to earlier studies.

    For our study, we have data for 200 CEOs from private firms in two cities in the
    Yangzi delta region of China and 200 control group individuals from the same cit-
    ies. To capture the multiple dimensions of strategic behavior, we used three differ-
    ent games to observe aspects of cooperativeness (Prisoner’s Dilemma), coordination
    (Battle-of-the-Sexes) and anti-coordination (Chicken). We also included incentiv-
    ized elicitations of beliefs about others’ choices, asking the subjects to guess the
    behavior of others in their respective group.

    Our first main result is that in all games the behavior of the CEOs differed sub-
    stantially from the behavior of the control group. The CEOs cooperated more in the
    Prisoner’s Dilemma game and played less hawkishly in the Battle-of-the-Sexes and
    Chicken games. This result is significant in all games not only when we make raw
    comparisons of proportions of the strategy choices between the groups but also when
    we include control variables in regressions. When calculating the expected payoffs,
    the differences are substantial between the groups, with CEOs earning from 11 to 44
    percent more than the control group in these games. Remarkably, however, CEOs
    did not out-compete the control-group members by being more rational (in the nar-
    row textbook sense) or more selfish, but by being more cooperative and less aggres-
    sive. Furthermore, CEOs believed in significantly higher cooperation levels than the
    control group in the Prisoner’s Dilemma game. Overall and again contradicting the
    rational “textbook CEO”, beliefs were frequently inconsistent with behavior. Under
    the assumption of selfish preferences, compared to the control group, CEOs did not
    best respond more frequently to their beliefs. However, the CEOs’ beliefs about
    other CEOs’ behavior were on average more accurate than the corresponding beliefs
    the control group held about other control-group members’ behavior.

    The aim of this paper is to study the strategic behavior and beliefs of CEOs com-
    pared to others. We perceive the identification of underlying causal mechanisms as
    a natural second step and beyond the scope of the present paper. Nevertheless, our

    157

    1 3
    Strategic decisions: behavioral differences between CEOs…

    research design comparing the behavior of two distinct groups invites methodologi-
    cal questions about the subjects’ background characteristics, their selection into the
    study and other factors that could hypothetically bias our results. We have therefore
    scrutinized our findings with a large battery of robustness tests exploring the influ-
    ence of recruitment method, income differences, the definition of CEO and other
    factors. Results of these tests consistently confirm our baseline results.

    2 Related literature

    This paper connects to two different strands of research. First, there is a growing
    body of literature that explores how market transactions shape individual behavior
    and preferences (see Bowles 1998 for a review). Some research in this area suggests
    that property rights and market integration play an important role in the develop-
    ment of efficient and prosocial behavior (Henrich et al. 2001),3 which would lead us
    to think that CEOs—being more intensely involved with the market than others—
    should display distinctly efficient and prosocial behavioral strategies. On the other
    hand, it has also been observed that specific market mechanisms may trigger dis-
    regard for third parties, which is normally seen as anti-social (e.g., Falk and Szech
    2013; Bartling et al. 2015). Partly, these seemingly contradictory results are due to
    different definitions of prosociality, but they may also be associated with the differ-
    ent research methods used.4 Economic transactions take place in very different mar-
    ket environments that can have diverse mediating impacts on individual behavior.
    In the ‘idealized’ competitive market where anonymous buyers and sellers transact,
    there is no obvious room for prosocial behavior, and this may encourage ethically
    questionable conduct (Shleifer 2004). In real-world market environments, how-
    ever, transactions are typically personalized and anonymity absent. Repeat transac-
    tions and cultivation of long-time business relations clearly represent the standard
    rather than the exception for corporate transactions. Hence, this paper contributes to
    research on the potential impact of non-anonymous market activities by studying if
    and how experienced business leaders differ from people otherwise sharing the same
    cultural and local setting, but not the same extent of market exposure.

    Secondly, our study relates to the literature about behavioral preferences of busi-
    ness leaders and entrepreneurs. This research area includes theories about why these

    3 The finding by Ockenfels and Weimann (1999) that student subjects who grew up in socialist Eastern
    Germany contributed less in a public good game and showed less solidarity than similar subjects who
    grew up in market-oriented West Germany is in the same spirit.
    4 For instance, higher accepting rates in the ultimatum game in Henrich et al. (2001) are interpreted as
    cooperative and prosocial, whereas a higher accepting rate (at a given price) in the double auction in Falk
    and Szech (2013) increases the efficiency in terms of the monetary reward for the two bidders, but since
    the third party (the mouse) is worse off when a bid is accepted, it is interpreted as a sign of moral ero-
    sion. The method used by Henrich et al. (2001) is based on comparing behavior in experimental games
    of widely different groups in the field relying on the hypothesis that different habits and cultures “spill
    over” into the groups’ behavior in the games, whereas Falk and Szech (2013) and Bartling et al. (2015)
    induce different “institutional” settings in strictly controlled laboratory experiments of given and rela-
    tively homogenous subject pools.

    158 H. J. Holm et al.

    1 3

    groups should differ from other people (e.g., Kihlstrom and Laffont 1979; Van de
    Ven et  al. 2007) and studies investigating whether such differences can be empiri-
    cally established (e.g., Van Praag and Cramer 2001; Holm et  al. 2013; Hvide and
    Panos 2015; Åstebro et  al. 2014; Koudstaal et  al. 2016). The latter literature is
    extensive but typically focuses on personality characteristics such as risk and uncer-
    tainty preferences, overconfidence, the locus of control and desire for achievement.

    Only a few studies have explored CEOs’ strategic behavior in controlled settings
    using incentivized games, where behavior is interactive and where the outcome is
    predicted by the theoretical concepts of equilibrium. If we use a ‘generous’ defi-
    nition including not only CEOs but also high-ranking managers and professionals,
    we obtain a small set of eight studies on strategic behavior with similarities to the
    present one (see Table  1). These studies compare the behavior of business leaders
    under various definitions (e.g., CEOs, entrepreneurs, managers, self-employed) with
    control-group members (e.g., students, salary workers) in distinct controlled and
    incentivized strategic settings. Most closely related to ours is a study by Fehr and
    List (2004), who conducted a trust game experiment with CEOs in the Costa Rican
    coffee industry and undergraduate students. They found that the CEOs were more
    trusting and reciprocated more than the students.

    While the results of the studies listed in Table  1 naturally vary due to differ-
    ences in design and subject groups, one can draw some highly tentative conclusions.
    For one, the self-employed tend to be more willing to take decisions on their own
    (Cooper and Saral 2013; Masclet et  al. 2009). Furthermore, managers are more
    willing to cooperate (in team production and in trust relations) than control sub-
    jects (Fehr and List 2004; Holm et al. 2013; Montmarquette et al. 2004). However,
    Cooper and Saral (2013) detect no differences in free-riding.

    Our study contributes to this literature in a number of ways. None of the above
    studies links behavior to general theoretical constructs (like Nash equilibrium)
    across more than one game. By having three different games in our design, we put
    any theoretical hypothesis about differences between CEOs and the control group
    to a tougher test, since the set of theoretical mechanisms that are consistent with
    an observed pattern of differences shrinks the more potential differences we can
    observe. Furthermore, the present study is the first that elicits subjects’ beliefs about
    others’ choices, which allows us to identify to what extent behavior is associated
    with specific beliefs regarding others’ behavior. The belief elicitations also make it
    possible to study the accuracy of beliefs and whether actions are best responses to
    beliefs.

    We also make a methodological contribution by using a stratified random sam-
    pling technique for recruiting CEOs and the comparison group. By including CEOs
    from five different manufacturing industries, we reduce the risk of industry-specific
    results, yet limit the risk of noise linked to different background conditions. Further,
    by excluding CEOs operating very small firms, we ascertain that our subjects are
    used to exercising strategic decisions that have a certain economic relevance. Many
    of the above studies use specific comparison groups (most often students) who dif-
    fer significantly from the CEOs along multiple dimensions (e.g., age, professional
    experience, income). We have reduced these differences substantially by matching
    the CEOs more closely with the control group in terms of age, gender, education and

    159

    1 3
    Strategic decisions: behavioral differences between CEOs…

    Ta
    bl

    e
    1

    S
    tu

    di
    es

    o
    n

    st
    ra

    te

    gi

    c
    de

    ci
    si

    on
    s

    w
    ith

    b
    us

    in
    es

    s
    le

    ad
    er

    s

    A
    a

    bs
    tr

    ac
    t f

    ra
    m

    e,
    F

    fi
    el

    d
    fr

    a

    m
    e,

    S
    A

    s
    em

    i a
    bs

    tr
    ac

    t f
    ra

    m
    e,

    N
    R

    n
    on

    -r
    an

    do
    m

    s
    am

    pl
    e,

    S
    R

    s
    tr

    at
    ifi

    ed
    ra

    nd
    om

    , U
    u

    nd
    er

    gr
    ad

    ua
    te

    , S
    E

    s
    el

    f-
    em

    pl
    oy

    ed
    )

    Pa
    pe

    r
    Fo

    cu
    s

    gr
    ou

    p
    C

    om
    pa

    ri
    so

    n
    gr

    ou
    p

    G
    am

    e
    Fr

    am
    e

    B
    el

    ie
    f e

    lic
    it.

    Sa
    m

    p-
    lin

    g
    M

    ai
    n

    fin
    di

    ng

    C
    oo

    pe
    r e

    t a
    l.

    (1
    99

    9)
    M

    an
    ag

    er
    s

    an
    d

    fo
    re

    m
    en

    in

    te
    xt

    ile
    in

    du
    st

    ry

    (N
    =

    1
    50

    ,

    C
    hi

    na
    )

    U
    . s

    tu
    de

    nt
    s

    (N
    =

    1
    60

    ,

    C

    hi
    na

    )
    R

    at
    ch

    et
    e

    ff
    ec

    t

    g
    am

    e
    A

    +
    F

    N
    o

    N
    R

    Fi
    el

    d

    co

    nt
    ex

    t i
    nc

    re
    as

    es

    m
    an

    ag
    er

    s’
    b

    ut
    n

    ot
    s

    tu

    de
    nt

    s’
    s

    tr
    at

    eg
    ic

    p
    la

    y
    C

    oo
    pe

    r

    (

    20

    06
    )

    E
    xe

    cu
    tiv

    e
    M

    B
    A

    s
    tu

    de
    nt

    s

    (N

    =
    1

    9,
    U

    SA
    )

    U
    . s
    tu
    de
    nt
    s
    (N
    =

    2
    0,

    U

    SA
    )

    W
    ea

    ke
    st

    li
    nk

    g
    am

    e
    SA

    N
    o
    N
    R
    E
    xe

    c.
    M

    B
    A
    s
    tu
    de
    nt

    s
    be

    tte
    r

    at
    o

    ve
    rc

    om
    in

    g
    co

    or
    di

    na

    tio
    n

    fa
    ilu

    re
    s

    C
    oo

    pe
    r a

    nd
    S

    ar
    al

    (2
    01

    3)
    SE

    (N
    =

    4
    4,

    U
    SA

    )
    St

    ud
    en

    ts
    , a

    lu
    m

    ni

    (N
    =

    1
    40

    , U
    SA

    )
    Te

    am
    p

    ro
    du

    ct
    io

    n
    A

    N
    o
    N
    R

    SE
    le

    ss
    w

    ill
    in

    g
    to

    jo
    in

    te

    am
    , n

    o
    di

    ff
    er

    en
    ce

    in

    fr
    ee

    -r
    id

    in
    g

    E
    ls

    to
    n

    et
     a

    l.
    (2

    00
    6)

    SE
    v

    is
    ito

    rs
    a

    t a
    c

    on
    ve

    n-
    tio

    n
    (N

    =
    8

    2,
    U

    SA
    )

    N
    on

    -S
    E

    v
    is

    ito
    rs

    a
    t a

    co

    nv
    en

    tio
    n
    (N
    =

    9
    0,

    U
    SA
    )

    M
    ar

    ke
    t e

    nt
    ry

    g
    am
    e
    A
    N
    o
    N
    R

    Pa
    rt

    -t
    im

    e
    SE

    le
    ss

    w
    ill

    in
    g

    to
    c

    om
    pe

    te

    Fe
    hr

    a
    nd

    L
    is

    t (
    20

    04
    )

    C
    E

    O
    s

    fr
    om

    c
    off

    ee
    in

    du
    s-

    tr
    y

    (N
    =

    7
    6)

    St
    ud

    en
    ts

    (N
    =

    1
    26

    )
    Tr

    us
    t g

    am
    e

    A
    N

    o
    N

    R
    C

    E
    O

    s
    m

    or
    e

    tr
    us

    tin
    g

    an
    d
    tr
    us

    tw
    or

    th
    y

    H
    ol

    m
    e

    t a
    l.
    (2
    01

    3)
    C

    E
    O

    s
    fr

    om
    fi

    ve
    d

    iff
    er

    en
    t

    in
    du

    st
    ri

    es
    (N

    =
    7

    00
    ,

    C
    hi
    na
    )

    Su
    bj

    ec
    ts

    s
    am

    pl
    ed

    to

    m
    at

    ch
    C

    E
    O
    s
    (N

    =
    2

    00
    ,
    C
    hi
    na
    )

    Tr
    us

    t e
    lic

    ita
    tio

    n
    +

    W
    ill


    in

    gn
    es

    s
    to

    c
    om

    pe
    te

    A
    N

    o
    SR

    C
    E
    O
    s

    m
    or

    e
    tr

    us
    tin

    g
    an

    d
    m

    or
    e
    w
    ill
    in
    g
    to
    c
    om
    pe
    te

    M
    as

    cl
    et

    e
    t a

    l.
    (2

    00
    9)

    SE
    (N

    =
    1

    4,
    F

    ra
    nc

    e)
    Sa

    la
    ry

    w
    or

    ke
    rs

    a
    nd

    st

    ud
    en

    ts
    (N

    =
    1

    30
    ,

    Fr
    an

    ce
    )

    R
    is

    k-
    ta

    ki
    ng

    d
    ec

    is
    io

    n
    on

    th

    ei
    r o

    w
    n

    or
    in

    g
    ro

    up
    A

    N
    o
    N
    R

    SE
    p

    ay
    m

    or
    e

    fo
    r t

    ak
    in

    g
    de

    ci
    si
    on
    s

    on
    th

    ei
    r o

    w
    n

    M
    on

    tm
    ar

    qu
    et

    te
    e

    t a
    l.

    (2
    00

    4)
    M

    an
    ag
    er
    s
    fr
    om

    p
    ha

    r-
    m

    ac
    eu

    tic
    al

    c
    om

    pa
    ny

    (N

    =
    3

    6,
    F

    ra
    nc

    e,

    G
    er

    m
    an

    y)

    St
    ud
    en
    ts
    (N
    =

    7
    2,

    C

    an
    ad

    a,
    F

    ra
    nc

    e)
    Te

    am
    e

    ff
    or

    t t
    as

    k
    A

    N
    o
    N
    R

    M
    an

    ag
    er
    s
    m
    or
    e

    co
    op

    er
    a-

    tiv
    e

    th
    an

    s
    tu
    de
    nt
    s

    160 H. J. Holm et al.

    1 3

    residential living area. The present samples of CEOs and control group subjects are
    also relatively large compared to most previous studies.5

    3 Theory and hypotheses

    We analyze decisions in three simple 2 × 2 games—Prisoner’s Dilemma, Battle-of-
    the Sexes, and Chicken (see Tables  2, 3 and 4)—that capture situations requiring
    cooperation, coordination and anti-coordination.

    These three games involve strategic elements that differ along important dimen-
    sions and are likely to be more important in the context of running a firm than in
    other settings. Because these situations occur at a higher frequency for CEOs and
    are also likely to have greater economic consequences for them than for other pro-
    fessionals, we expect on average different behavioral strategies between CEOs and
    the control group (henceforth denoted as “CG”). At this early stage, the identifica-
    tion of the exact causal mechanism explaining different strategies goes beyond the
    scope of this paper. Potential mechanisms include self-selection of distinct types
    into professional roles, a weeding out of distinct behavioral strategies through com-
    petitive pressure, or social learning through repeat experience in similar or related
    situations. In the following subsections, we discuss in more detail why each of the
    games was chosen and why the CEOs’ behavior may differ from responses by other
    professional groups.

    3.1 Prisoner’s Dilemma

    Situations analogous to the Prisoner’s Dilemma (henceforth denoted as PD) are
    common between the CEO and employees, where free-riding opportunities fre-
    quently co-exist with possible benefits of cooperation. Similar strategic situations
    emerge between firms horizontally, e.g., in terms of price-setting (collusion),
    recruitment and joint investments. A priori, one can think of different mechanisms
    that would make a CEO’s strategic behavior different from that of other people in
    PD—recognizing, however, that these alternative mechanisms imply both more and
    less defection in such a game.

    From a traditional economic perspective, one can argue that competitive forces
    ought to weed out irrational CEOs so that surviving CEOs choose strategies that
    constitute Nash equilibria.6 As noted in the introduction such a mechanism is plau-
    sible when the Nash equilibria are evolutionary stable strategies (Maynard Smith

    6 It is well-known (e.g., Fehr and Schmidt 1999; Engelmann and Strobel 2004) that the Nash equilibrium
    prediction is contingent on the underlying (possibly social) preferences assumed. To simplify the presen-
    tation and theoretical conceptualization, we assume standard selfish materialistic preferences (i.e., play-
    ers only care about their own payoff) when referring to Nash equilibrium and socially optimal outcomes.

    5 The only larger sample of CEOs on incentivized strategic decision-making besides the present study
    is in Holm et al. (2013), which is based on data from a study conducted in 2009 containing two strategic
    situations (in terms of trust and willingness to compete). However, the objective there was to investigate
    differences between CEOs and a control group in behavior relating to uncertainty preferences.

    161

    1 3
    Strategic decisions: behavioral differences between CEOs…

    1982). However, social norms favoring efficient strategy choices that maximize the
    sum of the involved parties’ payoffs might constitute an alternative mechanism.
    Such behavior can be sustained by the development of welfare-maximizing norms
    in well-defined social groups characterized by mutual monitoring and social reward
    and punishment (Ellickson 1991; Bowles and Gintis 2011) and/or altruistic prefer-
    ences through assortative matching (Bergstrom 2002; Alger and Weibull 2013). If
    this is the case one can expect that CEOs will be more cooperative in their strategic
    decision making than others and that the population as a whole consists of different
    strategic ‘types’ (e.g., Kurzban and Houser 2005). Assuming that these two mecha-
    nisms are more prominent for CEOs than for others, we can expect differences in
    behavior between CEOs and others on average. In PD these alternative mechanisms
    have both straightforward (diametrically opposite) predictions since there is a unique
    Nash equilibrium (both players Defect) and a unique social optimum (both players
    Cooperate).

    3.2 Battle‑of‑the‑sexes

    The Battle-of-the-Sexes game (henceforth denoted as BSS) captures situations
    where subjects can choose to act more or less aggressively, while coordination
    would lead to preferable outcomes. From a general management perspective coor-
    dination problems are fundamental. Inside the organization, leadership tasks for the
    CEO include the management of beliefs (Foss 2001) and the alignment of incentives
    with the adoption of new information (Bolton et  al. 2013) in order to solve aris-
    ing coordination problems. In inter-organizational dilemmas, coordination situations
    with the flavor of BSS are likely to emerge with upstream and downstream firms,
    specifically if decisions involve the implementation of new technology, (re-)loca-
    tion, and changes of market linkages.

    In BSS coordinating on one of the two pure Nash-equilibria, where both players
    choose the same strategy (A, A) or (B, B), is obviously preferable for both players.
    At the same time, (player) Row prefers coordination on Strategy A and (player) Col-
    umn prefers coordination on Strategy B. Hence, the players need to strike a balance
    between coordination and “domination” motives. In the following, we will also refer
    to Strategy A (B) for Row (and Column, respectively) as the “hawkish” strategy,
    since by choosing this strategy the player has excluded all outcomes where he is
    dominated by his opponent in terms of payments. With the same logic, we will also
    refer to Strategy B (A) for Row (and Column, respectively) as the “dovish” strat-
    egy, since this strategy will always give the opponent at least as much payoff as the
    player himself.

    The motives of coordination and domination would most likely be reflected in a
    negotiation between the Row and Column player if they could communicate. How-
    ever, in our game communication is not possible and there are no obvious coor-
    dination devices. Given the difficulty of coordination on the pure strategy Nash
    equilibria, it is reasonable to expect that players with selfish preferences play the
    unique mixed strategy where Row and Column play A with probability 0.6 and 0.4,
    respectively.

    162 H. J. Holm et al.

    1 3

    There are reasons to believe that CEOs differ in the way they play BSS com-
    pared to others. For one thing, leading business people may have a strong preference
    for relative domination. Alfred Marshall (1890/1920, p. 23) claimed that “a manu-
    facturer or a trader is often stimulated much more by the hope of victory over his
    rivals than by the desire to add something to his fortune.” If this holds for our CEOs,
    we would expect more hawkish play among them in BSS than among those in CG.
    Other possible mechanisms relate to the experience, skill and, motive to coordinate
    mentioned above. If CEOs as leaders of private firms are more exposed and experi-
    enced than others in detecting and handling coordination situations compared to oth-
    ers they may well differ from others in how they form beliefs and act in BSS.

    Our research focus is not on focal points. We will simply assume that the players
    do not intend to coordinate through focal points.7 As a consequence, all our subjects

    Table 2 The prisoner’s dilemma

    The payoffs to the subjects in Chinese Yuan, CNY

    Defect Cooperate

    Defect 100, 100 400, 50
    Cooperate 50, 400 250, 250

    Table 3 The Battle-of-the-sexes

    The payoffs to the subjects in Chinese Yuan, CNY

    Strategy A Strategy B

    Strategy A 600, 400 0, 0
    Strategy B 0, 0 400, 600

    Table 4 Chicken

    The payoffs to the subjects in Chinese Yuan, CNY

    Hawk Dove

    Hawk 0, 0 600, 150
    Dove 150, 600 300, 300

    7 The analysis of BSS is more complicated since it is an asymmetric game. In a standard matching pro-
    tocol (e.g. in a computer lab) half the subjects would have been randomly assigned the Row and Column
    player role. In such a setting it would be possible to calculate if they were able to coordinate by the
    use of coordination cues (i.e., focal points) like strategy labels (see Schelling, 1960). Although, it has
    been shown that focal points based on strategy labels are successfully used in symmetric (pure) coordina-
    tion games, when introducing asymmetries as in the BSS, the coordination through focal points more or
    less vanishes (see Crawford et al. 2008 and Parravano and Poulsen 2015). Furthermore, the use of focal
    points is often context or culture-specific. We can not rule out that some try to use “A” as a focal point
    since it is the first letter in the alphabet. However, given results from the cited literature and noting that
    our Chinese subjects do not have an alphabet similar to the English, we believe that this focal point is not
    likely to be salient.

    163

    1 3
    Strategic decisions: behavioral differences between CEOs…

    were given the Row player role. (The limited number of opponents matched for real
    payoffs, denoted as X-players, had the Column player role, see Sect. 4).

    3.3 Chicken

    The Chicken game illustrates elements of situations characterized by anti-coordi-
    nation where it is vital (contrary to the coordination games) that the players do not
    choose the same strategy. CEOs are likely to encounter ‘Chicken-like’ situations in
    private markets where some valuable capacity, resource or demand are scarce and
    where there is competition for it. One relevant example would be a market-entry
    decision where it is only profitable for one firm to serve the market.

    In this game, there are two pure equilibria where one of the players plays Hawk
    and the other Dove. If the players could communicate, one would expect that the
    players would try to convince each other (e.g., with threats) that they would play
    Hawk. However, in our game, they cannot communicate, which means that it is rea-
    sonable to expect that the players (with selfish preferences) play the unique mixed
    strategy where Row and Column play Hawk with probability 0.67.

    As in the previous games there are reasons to believe that CEOs may differ in the
    way they play Chicken compared to others and that the direction of this difference
    is not obvious a priori. It has been argued that private business leaders and entrepre-
    neurs are more optimistic than others or may even be overconfident. The theoretical
    literature draws on this to explain excessive market entry (see e.g., Bernardo and
    Welch, 2001; Hayward et  al. 2006; Wu and Knott, 2006). These arguments would
    suggest that CEOs are more hawkish in Chicken games than other comparable peo-
    ple. At the same time, if CEOs will be more used to and trained to handle such situ-
    ations, it may be that they have learned the cost of hawkishness the hard way and
    therefore will be more inclined to guarantee a non-zero payoff by playing Dove than
    others with less experience. In addition, Dove would also be an attractive strategy
    for less selfish subjects with a strong preference for fairness, since it can lead to the
    non-zero equal payoff (300, 300).

    3.4 Hypotheses

    In the preceding sections, we have discussed some potential mechanisms that would
    lead to behavioral differences between CEOs and CGs. However, as there were no
    unambiguous directional predictions we use the null hypothesis that there are no dif-
    ferences in behavior or beliefs. Hence our hypotheses are as follows:

    1. On average, the CEOs and the CGs choose strategies similarly in the different
    games.

    2. On average, the CEOs’ beliefs about others’ behavior are similar to those of the
    CGs.

    3. On average, the CEOs’ best responses to their beliefs are similar to those of the
    CGs.

    164 H. J. Holm et al.

    1 3

    4 Research strategy and design

    In this section, we briefly present the research strategy and design of our study in
    terms of tasks, treatments, sampling strategy and implementation.8

    4.1 Tasks and treatments

    Initially, the subjects received general information about the tasks (see Instructions
    in the Appendix provided in the online Supplementary Material) and payments.
    They were also informed that in some tasks they would play against another anony-
    mous person, who was denoted as X. To mitigate potential order effects, the CEOs
    and the CGs were divided into six different treatment groups based on the order
    and frames of the games, so that each game with a given frame had the 1st, 2nd and
    3rd position exactly once (see Appendix  1C). Hence, each subject participated in
    six different tasks (three games and the belief elicitations). One of the games was
    randomly selected at the end of the experimental session as the money-earning task.
    By paying for only one task (a strategy choice in a game or a guess in a belief elici-
    tation), we follow Blanco et al. (2010) to avoid the ‘hedging problem’ of the belief
    elicitations.

    The framing of a game can affect behavior (Tversky and Kahneman 1981; for a
    review Levin et  al. 1998). Increasing awareness of these framing effects has moti-
    vated many researchers to increase the “field content” that subjects are exposed to
    (Harrison and List 2004).9 We investigate this link by presenting each game with
    both an abstract frame and a field frame, which introduces the game as a common
    type of business decision that could also be easily grasped by non-CEOs without
    managerial experience. Both frames were randomly assigned, with half of the sub-
    jects in each group receiving an abstract frame and half a field frame.10 If our results
    are robust with respect to the frame, we can claim that the results generalize beyond
    the situational construct and decision domain.

    The decisions in the three games were to choose between strategies ‘A’ and ‘B’.
    In the abstract frame, the game explanation focused on the payoff information. In the
    field frame, three scenarios preceded the payoff information (see Instructions in the
    Appendix for details). The belief elicitation tasks were to guess the percentage of
    other players who chose either strategy in the game respondents had just played. The
    closer the subject’s guess was to the observed frequency, the higher the earnings.11

    8 Comments on the design and more details are provided in the Appendix.
    9 In fact, Cooper et al. (1999) find that managers (in the textile industry in China) become more strategic
    when exposed to field frames than students. However, the result from Cubitt et al. (2011) appears to go in
    the opposite direction, indicating that experienced subjects tend to be less susceptible to framing.
    10 The descriptions of the frames are available in the Instructions.
    11 To limit the cognitive load and due to time constraints, we used a simple scoring rule rather than a
    proper continuous scoring rule like the quadratic one. Subjects earned 500 CNY if they were ± 2 percent-
    age points from the correct answer; and gradually less the further away the answer was from the correct
    one. While such a simplistic scoring rule may tilt beliefs slightly away from true beliefs, they should do
    so in the same way for all subjects. The choice of scoring rule should therefore be unproblematic in stud-
    ies like ours where the main focus is not point predictions but between-subjects comparisons. Simplistic

    165

    1 3
    Strategic decisions: behavioral differences between CEOs…

    By eliciting beliefs about the percentage of other players choosing a certain strategy
    we get more precise information about beliefs than if we had elicited beliefs about
    the opponent’s binary choice.

    To be able to pay out cash rewards on the spot immediately after the experimental
    tasks, we obtained choices from a small additional group of 11 CEOs and another
    small group of 9 CGs who took the role as X persons in the experiment before we
    approached the 200 CEOs and 200 CGs in the main study.12

    4.2 Sampling and descriptive statistics

    For this study, we recruited 100 CEOs and 100 CGs from each of the two Chinese
    coastal cities of Shanghai and Wenzhou for a total of 400 participants.13 CEOs were
    sampled from firms stratified according to industry.14 Industries range from labor-
    intensive to technology-intensive and include textile, ordinary machinery, vehicle
    and auto parts, medical and pharmaceutical products, and computer and commu-
    nication equipment. So as not to end up with a sample of managers running small-
    scale marginal firms, the sample was stratified by firm size. More specifically, we
    over-sampled ‘large’ (more than 300 employees) and ‘medium-size’ (100–300)
    firms. Finally, to avoid fresh start-ups and self-employed businesses our sampling
    frame included only firms that had survived for at least three years. The CGs were
    randomly selected from household registers to match the CEOs with respect to gen-
    der, age, education. To get a reasonable match with respect to income, we added
    the restriction that CG subjects should live in the residential areas where the CEOs
    themselves lived. In this way, we avoided having a very select control group (for
    instance, a specific group of highly paid professionals), and we avoided having a
    sample of people who differed very much from the CEOs.

    Footnote 11 (continued)
    scoring rules for beliefs are not uncommon in the experimental literature; see, e.g., Gächter and Renner
    (2010).
    12 The behavior of the X subject is of no interest to the study, but is necessary to avoid deception of the
    subjects in the main study. Each X subject was matched to more than one subject. Some information
    given to this group was adapted to their role (e.g., that they got paid after the main study was finalized).
    To test the design, we also had 39 additional CEOs who were matched to the ‘XCEOs’ in a pilot study.
    13 The games employed in this paper were appended to a firm survey conducted in 2012 including 7
    cities and a total of 700 entrepreneurs. Games were conducted in 5 cities, with a total of 500 CEOs (100
    CEOs in each city). For the purpose of a comparative study we recruited 200 CGs in two of the five cit-
    ies. To get a clean design for this paper focusing on differences in strategic behavior between CEOs and
    CGs, the data used here is based on the two cities, in which we have matching CEO and CG data for 200
    subjects. The behaviors of the remaining 300 CEOs (together with the 200 CEOs used in this paper) will
    be used to explore questions of within-subject/within-firm variation and to explore the external validity
    of revealed game behavior. Experimental data collected in connection with an earlier firm survey (2009)
    was analysed in studies by Holm et al. (2013), Opper et al. (2017) and Nee et al. (2018).
    14 Specific aspects of conducting this study in China are commented in the Appendix.

    166 H. J. Holm et al.

    1 3

    Table 5 summarizes the descriptive statistics for the 400 participants in our study
    according to gender, age, income, and education.15 The matching of gender and age
    in the CG worked well. There is also virtually no difference in education between
    the two groups.16 The average household income of the entrepreneurs is—as can
    be expected—more than twice as high compared to the average of the CG. While
    this is a large difference, it would be much larger without a residential selection of
    the control group.17 To minimize the risk that income is driving the results we will
    complement our basic group comparison analysis with regressions where we control
    for income.

    4.3 Execution

    A key to recruiting very busy people for a study like this is to make it easy to par-
    ticipate and to be persistent. We relied on 20 professional interviewers of Shang-
    hai Yihong Business Consulting (a local company specializing on survey research),
    each with multiple years of field experience, to conduct the survey, after making
    individual appointments.18 For the CEOs, the interviews and experimental tasks
    were conducted at the firm site, usually in a conference room or at the CEO’s private
    office, by a team of two interviewers. The CEOs were first asked questions about
    their background (education, demographics) and the firm (start-up capital, firm rev-
    enues, etc.). The CGs were also visited by a team of two interviewers at their private
    residence where they were asked the same set of questions, except for those regard-
    ing the firm and business development.19 Each subject was then presented with the
    three games and the belief elicitation tasks. Both CEOs and the GGs made their
    task choices using a paper-and-pencil format. As interviewers were in charge of col-
    lecting the questionnaires once completed, interviewers were naturally able to see
    their choices, but choices were not observable by others, such as employees and staff
    members or family members in the case of CGs. Hence, the degree of anonymity

    19 The difference of location of the interviews and experimental tasks (at work versus at home) might
    affect results. However, we can exclude this possibility since we find that the subgroup of “CGCEOs”
    who did the interview and tasks at home differ from the other CGs in the same way as the CEOs who
    were visited at their firms (see the robustness check in Sect. 5.3).

    15 These are standard demographic variables often controlled for in empirical studies. There is also evi-
    dence that these variables may matter for incentivized strategic behavior. Earlier research suggests that
    gender affects social and competitive preferences as well as risk preferences (Croson and Gneezy 2009;
    Dohmen et al. 2011). Education and age have been reported to matter for trust, cooperation and ultima-
    tum game behavior (Glaeser et al. 2000; Güth et al. 2007 and Thöni et al. 2012). A subject’s income will
    affect the salience of experimental earnings and the stakes that a subject confronts. Stakes have been
    demonstrated to affect strategic behavior in ultimatum games (Andersen et al. 2011).
    16 When the CGs were just randomly selected from the household registers in the same cities as the
    CEOs, the latter group had significantly more years of education (Holm et al. 2013). In Appendix 5 we
    provide additional detailed information on the matching between the CEOs and the CGs.
    17 In Holm et al. (2013), where the control group was just randomly selected from the household regis-
    ters in the same cities as the entrepreneurs, the median income of the entrepreneur was eight times higher
    than that of one of the CGs.
    18 If a CEO had to cancel a meeting, the assistants would try to reschedule it at some other time. This is
    one reason that it took these 20 assistants over four months to collect the data.

    167

    1 3
    Strategic decisions: behavioral differences between CEOs…

    is the same for the two subject groups and corresponded to a single blind experi-
    ment.20 Afterward, one task was randomly selected as the money-earning task. The
    earnings were calculated and the subject received the payment immediately. The
    average subject in our experiment earned 247 CNY (or USD 39) on the behavioral
    tasks that took only 18  min on average, which corresponds to hourly earnings of
    USD 130.21 The main experiment took place during a period of about four and a half
    months, starting with the first subject on August 25, 2012, and ending with the last
    subject on January 9, 2013.

    5 Results

    In this section, we report observations of the subjects’ behavior on the experimental
    tasks. We start with the strategy choices in the games, after which we analyze the
    subjects’ beliefs.

    5.1 Behavior in the games

    Results presented in Table  6 show significant differences between the average
    behavior of the CEOs and the CGs in terms of strategic choices in each game. The
    differences are also substantial in percentage points, ranging between 13 percentage
    points and 25 percentage points in one game. Clearly, the CEOs are significantly
    more cooperative in PD and play significantly less hawkishly in BSS and Chicken.22
    This suggests that null hypothesis 1, stating that on average the CEOs and the CGs
    will choose strategies similarly in the different games, can be rejected. However, to
    reach a final conclusion we need to confirm that the observed differences between
    the groups are not due to confounding effects. We return to this concern in the fol-
    lowing sections.

    It should be evident from Table  6 that the Nash equilibrium (NE) predictions
    are not always consistent with the groups’ behaviors. The CEOs are close to the
    mixed NE in BSS and the CGs are close to the mixed NE in Chicken, but in PD both
    groups are far from the NE.23 Hence, the groups alternate in being close to the NE,

    20 This is important since the degree of anonymity may be an important factor for social desirable
    behavior (see e.g., Bernheim 1994; Andreoni and Bernheim 2009).
    21 This translates to an average hourly experimental earning of around 220 USD if we correct for pur-
    chasing power according to the Big Mac index (which was 1.68 in January 2014). It should be stressed
    that the income of CEOs in successful firms in China is relatively low from an international perspective,
    which makes it possible to provide salient incentives in the games and belief elicitations at a reasonable
    cost. Though even moderately successful CEOs are a high-income group in China, their median annual
    family income in our sample was only around USD 75,000 (according to the exchange rate 6.38 CNY/
    USD in August 2012).
    22 Note that the game was presented to the subjects in the BSS so that they were Row players (in
    Table  3), which means that Strategy A is interpreted as the hawkish strategy. The X-players had the
    reversed payoffs and the Column player role.
    23 The fact that NE does not point predict one shot behavior in PD is in line with many other studies
    using different subject groups (e.g., Kagel and Roth 1995).

    168 H. J. Holm et al.

    1 3

    and the CGs are closer to the NE in four out of six versions of the games. Therefore
    we cannot convincingly state that CEOs and the CGs differ in how they behave in
    playing NE. In fact, nothing in the data suggests that the CEOs are “more” consist-
    ent with the standard textbook predictions of economics (based on selfishness and
    Nash equilibrium) than are the CGs.

    5.1.1 Probabilities for outcomes and expected payoffs

    We will now elaborate on the relative probabilities of the outcomes for the CEOs
    and CGs end up in given their behavior (in Table 6). This will also help us to under-
    stand the substantial differences in expected payoffs between the groups. By using
    the proportions of chosen strategies among CEOs and CGs, while assuming that
    players are randomly matched (and cannot use any coordination devices etc. as
    explained in Sects.  3.2 and 3.3), it is possible to calculate the probability for the
    various outcomes in the games for the respective group. To simplify the presen-
    tation, we merge the abstract and field frame proportions given in Table  6 (which
    means, e.g., that the proportions playing Defect among CEOs and CGs are 0.42
    and 0.56, respectively). The probability for ending up in an outcome where both
    players play Defect in PD is then given by prob(DD) = q2

    D
    , where qD is the propor-

    tion in the group that play Defect. The probability that both cooperate is given by
    prob(CC) =

    (

    1 − qD
    )2

    and the probability that they play different strategies is given
    by prob(DC, CD) = 2qD

    (

    1 − qD
    )

    . If the probability for each outcome is multiplied
    by the sum of the two players’ payoffs (given in the parentheses in Table  7) and
    these terms are added together we get the expected earnings for a pair of players in
    the game. Clearly, the same logic can be applied when calculating the probabilities
    and expected earnings in BSS and Chicken.

    One general pattern in Table  7 is that the probabilities for CEOs to end up in
    high payoff outcomes are in most cases substantially higher than for the CGs. For
    instance, in PD, the probability that CEOs end up in the outcome where both play-
    ers cooperate is 72% higher than the corresponding probability for CGs. Conversely,
    the probabilities that CGs will have low payoff outcomes are higher compared to
    the CEOs. For instance, in the Chicken game, the probability for the zero payoff
    outcome where both players play Hawk is 85 percent higher for CGs. Naturally,
    these distributions of outcomes are reflected in the expected payoffs of the different

    Table 5 Descriptive
    characteristics of the subjects

    Standard deviations in parentheses

    Variable CEOs Control Group

    Gender (proportion males) .85 (.36) .82 (.39)
    Age (year, mean) 45.77 (7.79) 41.30 (6.80)
    Yearly household income (mil-

    lion CNY, mean)
    .55 (.47) .24 (.25)

    Years in school (mean) 13.64 (3.22) 13.84 (2.78)
    Number of observations 200 200

    169

    1 3
    Strategic decisions: behavioral differences between CEOs…

    groups. Compared to the CGs, the CEOs expected payoffs are 11%, 35%, and 44%
    higher in PD, BSS and Chicken, respectively.

    5.1.2 Regression analysis

    In Table  8 we present marginal effects from logistic regressions where we control
    for likely confounders, such as gender, education, age and income (reported in:
    Glaeser et  al. 2000; Güth et  al. 2007; Croson and Gneezy 2009; Andersen et  al.
    2011; Dohmen et al. 2011; Thöni et al. 2012; see also Table 5).24 We also control for
    location (Shanghai) to take into account possible cultural differences between both
    municipalities.

    All results presented in Table  6 appear robust. The CEOs are more cooperative
    in PD and less hawkish in BSS and the Chicken game compared to the CGs, even
    when we control for conceivable confounding effects. The main variable of interest
    is the dummy variable CEOs, which is significant for PD and BSS at the 5% level
    and at 1% for Chicken. The direction is the one expected from the previous analysis.
    All effects are substantial. Keeping all other variables at their averages, the prob-
    ability for defection in PD decreases by 0.12 when a CEO makes the strategic choice
    compared to the probability for defection by the CGs. The probabilities for Hawk in
    BSS and Chicken are even further reduced, namely by 0.13 and 0.18.

    Except for the CEO variable, none of the other variables is consistently signifi-
    cant. Family income has a significant negative effect on hawkish behavior in BSS,
    which may reflect a higher degree of generosity or lack of care for the experimen-
    tal money in this game. However, there is no significant income effect in the other
    games, suggesting that we should be cautious not to draw too strong conclusions

    Table 6 Average percentage play of strategies in the games

    The suffix letter in the game acronyms indicates frame: A abstract, F field. Number of observations in
    parentheses. Significance levels in Chi square tests, *p value < 0.1; **p value < 0.05; ***p value < 0.01

    Game and frame CEOs: Average playing
    Defect or Hawk

    CGs: Average playing
    Defect or Hawk

    Nash Equilib-
    rium Predic-
    tionNE

    PDA** 44.6 (101) 59.4 (101) 100
    PDF* 39.3 (99) 52.5 (99) 100
    BSSA** 62.4 (101) 75.2 (101) 60
    BSSF*** 61.2 (99) 79.8 (99) 60
    CA*** 48.5 (101) 73.3 (101) 67
    CF* 56.6 (99) 69.7 (99) 67

    24 Note that the effects of these variables could either be direct or indirect. For instance, education might
    correlate with cognitive ability and gender with risk aversion which indirectly can affect the behavior
    in the strategic games. Note that even if we have matched our sample groups insofar as possible with
    respect to these variables, there is still individual variation that might correlate with the dependent vari-
    able.

    170 H. J. Holm et al.

    1 3

    from this observation.25 The frame is insignificant in all games, which suggests that
    the underlying game is more important in explaining individual behavior than the
    framing of the decision.

    5.2 Beliefs

    The observed behavioral differences may simply reflect different preferences.
    Another possibility is that players’ beliefs about others’ choices differ and that sub-
    jects aim to optimize their own choices in response to these beliefs with or with-
    out regard to social preferences. We use data from the belief elicitation task to shed
    some light on the question of what is more likely to guide players’ behavior.

    In Table 9 we present the average percentage the subjects believed that the other
    players choose Defect or Hawk in the respective games.26 Compared to the CGs, the
    CEOs believe that other subjects defect on average less and are less hawkish. Hence,
    the CEOs’ beliefs about others’ behavior differ from the CGs in the same way as
    they play the games. The difference in beliefs is significant in four out of the six
    tasks. The difference is especially strong in PD.

    With regard to the closeness to NE there is no consistent pattern. The beliefs
    of the CEOs and the CGs are on average almost equally close to NE in BSS and
    Chicken when abstractly framed. When there is a significant difference, the CGs’
    beliefs about others’ choices are closer to NE than those of the CEOs.

    5.2.1 Difference in beliefs: a regression analysis

    We now inspect whether these inter-group differences in beliefs about others’ behav-
    ior are robust to the inclusion of the demographic variables introduced earlier. Since
    the dependent variable is proportional, we run a fractional response regression as
    suggested by Papke and Wooldridge (1996).

    Table 10 presents the regression results in terms of average partial effects, which
    have a similar interpretation as linear regression coefficients without compromis-
    ing the non-linear relationship (Gallani et al. 2016). The negative sign for the CEO
    variable indicates that the CEOs generally tend to believe that co-players defect less
    and play less hawkishly than the CG believe, even when we control for demographic

    25 It can also be noted that if family income is interacted with the CEO variable the interaction term is
    insignificant for all games.
    26 In the abstract frame subjects were asked to guess how many percent of subjects chose “Option A” in
    the game they just had played. In the field frame subjects guessed about the corresponding field alterna-
    tives (e.g., “City”). Option A and the paralell field alternatives corresponded to “Cooperate” and “Hawk”
    in PD, BSS, and Chicken, respectively. It is then assumed that the subjects’ believed that the residual
    percentage chose Defect and Dove, respectively. We use “belief of average percentage belief in Defect/
    Hawk” to simplify the presentation, but the reader should know that framing effects may play a role in
    how such questions are formulated. The reader should also know that because of the asymmetry in BSS
    (discussed in Sect.  3.2) it is assumed that if a subject believes that q percent played strategy A (i.e.,
    Hawk) as Row players, it implies that the subject believes that the same percent play strategy B (Hawk)
    as Column players. We do not claim that such an assumption is entirely without complications but we
    think it is the most natural interpretation given how the instructions were formulated.

    171

    1 3
    Strategic decisions: behavioral differences between CEOs…

    factors. The variable is strongly significant in PD, but not significant in the other
    games. The frame appears to have affected beliefs in Chicken substantially, with the
    field frame inducing the players to form more hawkish beliefs. There are no other
    strong predictors of beliefs. The conclusion is that the difference in beliefs between
    CEOs and the CG is a robust finding in PD, and for this game, we can firmly reject
    null hypothesis 2. For the other games, the CEOs’ beliefs appear somewhat less

    Table 7 Probabilities for outcomes and expected payoffs

    2nd, 3rd and 4th column contain probabilities for different possible outcomes and the numbers in paren-
    theses are the sum of both players’ payoffs in the outcome. 5th column contains expected earnings for the
    two-player pair. *Different strategies in BSS presumes that strategies are referred to as hawkish or dovish
    (see Sect. 3.2)

    Game/group Probability that both
    play Defect or Hawk
    (pair payoff, SEK)

    Probability that both
    play cooperate or
    dove

    Probability that play-
    ers choose different
    strategies*

    Expected payoff
    for a pair (SEK)

    PD/CEO 0.176 (200) 0.336 (500) 0.487 (450) 423
    PD/CG 0.314 (200) 0.194 (500) 0.493 (450) 381
    BSS/CEO 0.384 (0) 0.144 (0) 0.471 (1000) 471
    BSS/CG 0.601 (0) 0.051 (0) 0.349 (1000) 349
    C/CEO 0.276 (0) 0.226 (600) 0.499 (750) 509
    C/CG 0.511 (0) 0.081 (600) 0.408 (750) 354

    Table 8 Behavior: marginal
    effects

    Results from logistic regressions. Robust standard errors in paren-
    theses, *p < 0.1, **p < 0.05, ***p < 0.01

    (1) (2) (3)
    Defect Hawk_BSS Hawk_Chicken

    CEO − 0.123**
    (0.056)

    − 0.127**
    (0.051)

    − 0.177***
    (0.054)

    Male 0.044
    (0.067)

    − 0.078
    (0.057)

    − 0.053
    (0.065)

    Age − 0.001
    (0.004)

    0.005
    (0.003)

    − 0.000
    (0.003)

    School − 0.013
    (0.011)

    0.008
    (0.010)

    0.019*
    (0.011)

    Income − 0.006
    (0.008)

    − 0.015***
    (0.006)

    − 0.003
    (0.007)

    Shanghai − 0.010
    (0.065)

    − 0.113*
    (0.060)

    − 0.030
    (0.064)

    Frame Abst 0.064
    (0.051)

    − 0.016
    (0.047)

    − 0.024
    (0.050)

    Wald chi2 13.189 25.414 19.758
    Prob > chi2 0.068 0.001 0.006
    Pseudo R2 0.025 0.049 0.039
    N 400 400 400

    172 H. J. Holm et al.

    1 3

    hawkish compared to the CGs’, but the statistical relationships are too weak to reject
    null hypothesis 2 in these games. It is difficult to know exactly why this difference
    exists, but one possibility is that in PD the trade-off between self-interest and effi-
    ciency is more evident than in BSS and Chicken, where issues of coordination are
    also involved. The additional complexity in the latter situations may blur the rela-
    tionship between beliefs and behavior. We will return to this idea in the next section.

    5.2.2 Beliefs and behavior

    The impact of beliefs on behavior in games is not straightforward but depends on
    underlying motivations and preferences. Hence, the individual response to a cer-
    tain belief depends on preferences and the underlying model of behavior assumed.
    However, when controlling for beliefs in a logit regression, the results indicate that
    beliefs do in fact matter for the behavior in PD and BSS (see Appendix 2A).

    5.2.3 Best responses to beliefs

    One measure of strategic sophistication is a player’s ability to best respond to his
    own beliefs about other players’ strategy choices. Our design with belief elicitation
    allows for non-trivial analyses of best responses in BSS and the Chicken game since
    in these games both strategies are possible best responses contingent on the subject’s
    belief. If selfish preferences are assumed, then Hawk is the best response in BSS if
    the subject believes that less than 60 percent of their co-players play Hawk (given
    the assumptions outlined in Sect.  3.2.). The corresponding number for Chicken is
    67 percent. In BSS only 45 percent of the CEOs and 41 percent of the CGs best
    responded. The percentages for Chicken are 51 and 62, respectively. In Chicken, the
    difference in proportions is significant, which suggest that CEOs best respond less
    frequently than the CGs in Chicken. However, when controlling for other variables

    Table 9 Descriptive data on beliefs

    A abstract, F field. Number of observations in parentheses. Significance levels in the leftmost column
    concern differences in means in beliefs of Defect and Hawk between CEOs and CGs (t-tests). The 2nd
    and 3rd column contain the average percentages the subjects believed that the other players choose
    Defect or Hawk. Significance levels in the rightmost column indicate differences in mean deviation in
    beliefs from NE (t tests). *p value < 0.1; **p value < 0.05; ***p value < 0.01

    Game and frame CEOs: belief of average
    playing Defect or Hawk

    CGs: belief of average play-
    ing Defect or Hawk

    Average deviation
    from NE CEOs/
    CGs

    PDA*** 46.3 (101) 54.2 (101) 53.7/45.8***
    PDF*** 47.0 (99) 55.7 (99) 53.0/44.3***
    BSSA 57.2 (101) 60.0 (101) 14.1/15.8
    BSSF** 56.8 (99) 62.8 (99) 12.6/12.9
    CA 49.7 (101) 50.7 (101) 19.5/19.0
    CF** 54.0 (99) 59.3 (99) 17.8/13.1***

    173

    1 3
    Strategic decisions: behavioral differences between CEOs…

    there is no significant difference in best responses in any of the two games (see
    Appendix  2B). To sum up, the statistical evidence for differences in selfish best
    responses to belief is weak. For a given set of beliefs, there is some evidence that
    neither CEOs nor CGs is especially inclined to selfish best responses. This means
    that hypothesis 3 cannot be rejected.

    5.2.4 Accuracy of beliefs

    In a final step, we compare the accuracy of the CEOs’ beliefs with the accuracy
    of those of the CGs. Accurate beliefs about others’ behavior are essential in order
    to generate realistic business plans and profitable strategies for firms. Our findings
    indicate that the CEOs have more accurate beliefs about their co-player’s behavior
    than the CGs (see Appendix  2C). Here it is important to stress that the beliefs for
    CEOs concerned other CEOs, while beliefs for the CG concerned fellow citizens,
    we are comparing the accuracy of beliefs in reference to different groups. Hence,
    the question posed is whether CEOs have developed behavior and systems of beliefs
    that make them more accurate in their predictions of other CEOs’ strategic behav-
    ior than the CGs are in their predictions about the strategic behavior of the general
    population. Further investigation into this matter (see Appendix  2C) suggests that
    the CEOs’ superiority in accuracy depends on the target group for the beliefs. Thus,
    CEOs are better in predicting the average behavior of their own group, but they are
    not better at predicting the average behavior of society at large. One might think that
    since the CEOs are a more homogenous group the superior accuracy might be linked
    to a substantially higher variance of beliefs in the GG group, but this is not the case.

    5.3 Concerns and robustness tests

    We conduct a number of additional tests to scrutinize the robustness of our main
    findings along various dimensions (tests and results are available online as Sup-
    plementary Material). First, we have explored the potential influence of the defined
    focus groups. As can be expected in a random sample, the CG did also include a
    number of individuals (n = 43) who indicated that they are currently employed as
    CEOs. To test whether our results are robust if we exclude these 43 CEOs from the
    CGs and include them in the sample of CEOs, we run regressions similar to those
    reported in Table  8 above. Our results show that the magnitude of the CEO coef-
    ficients increases for all games, and in BSS the significance level increases from the
    5% level to 1% (see Appendix 3, Table A7). We report similar tests on differences in
    beliefs and find that the results are robust (see Appendix 3, Tables A8 and A9).

    Further, a skeptic may be concerned about a potential ‘location effect’, as CEOs
    ‘played’ the strategic games and made their choices in their workplaces, whereas
    CGs did so in their homes. There were also subtle differences in the way the oppo-
    nent was described, with the CEOs being informed that X “is a CEO of a Chinese
    firm and is a Chinese citizen”, while the CGs were informed that X “is a Chinese
    citizen” (see the instructions). Theoretically, referring to a more exclusive group
    may create stronger in-group emotions, which in principle can drive differences in

    174 H. J. Holm et al.

    1 3

    results. To explore whether these effects are likely to influence our results we have
    compared the behavior of control group CEOs with non-CEO control group mem-
    bers (both interviewed in their home and both stating beliefs regarding other fellow
    citizens), but did not detect substantive differences in comparison with our baseline
    results (see Appendix 4, Table A10–A12).

    Then, we have explored whether differences in average cooperativeness and qual-
    ity of education between both groups may have influenced our results (see Appen-
    dix 5). Yet we can show that both factors are unlikely to have a significant influence
    on our baseline findings. Further, we have ruled out that extreme values (Appen-
    dix 6) or interviewer effects (Appendix 7) explain our findings. Further, we have also
    applied narrower definitions of the CEOs, as many of the subjects are also owners or
    even founders of their companies. A focus on these sub-groups, however, does not
    generate substantively different results (Appendix  8). Finally we have explored the
    possible effect of differences in the CEOs’ competitive environment on the strategic
    choices made in the game but could not identify such association (Appendix 9).

    In sum, we feel confident that our results accurately reflect differences between
    CEO behavior and the behavior of others, less familiar and experienced with strate-
    gically relevant decisions.

    Table 10 Beliefs: average
    partial effects

    Results from fractional response regressions. Belief_PD, Belief_
    BSS, Belief_C represent the subjects’ belief of the proportion play-
    ing Defect (PD) and Hawk (BSS and Chicken), respectively. Coef-
    ficients represent average partial effects. Robust standard errors in
    parentheses, *p < 0.1, **p < 0.05, ***p < 0.01

    (1) (2) (3)
    Belief_PD Belief_BSS Belief_C

    CEO − 0.231***
    (0.051)

    − 0.082
    (0.050)

    − 0.049
    (0.045)

    Male − 0.032
    (0.065)

    − 0.029
    (0.067)

    0.019
    (0.056)

    Age 0.002
    (0.003)

    0.001
    (0.003)

    0.001
    (0.003)

    School − 0.003
    (0.010)

    − 0.001
    (0.011)

    0.013
    (0.009)

    Income 0.039
    (0.084)

    − 0.101
    (0.078)

    − 0.113*
    (0.062)

    Shanghai − 0.089
    (0.056)

    − 0.024
    (0.056)

    0.016
    (0.049)

    Frame_Abst − 0.029
    (0.045)

    − 0.028
    (0.045)

    − 0.159***
    (0.041)

    Wald chi2 25.930 9.178 28.087
    Prob > chi2 0.001 0.240 0.000
    Pseudo R2 0.006 0.002 0.005
    N 400 400 400

    175

    1 3
    Strategic decisions: behavioral differences between CEOs…

    6 Explanations and implications

    One of the strongest results of this study is that CEOs tend to be more oriented
    towards cooperation and non-aggressive behavior than other people, which leads
    to substantial differences in expected earnings. As shown in Table  7, the expected
    payoffs of the CEOs were substantially higher than for the CGs. If these observed
    behavioral differences reflect how CEOs and CGs interact in real strategic settings,
    then this implies the existence of a “CEO culture” of norms and beliefs generating
    substantial returns, not only to the CEOs’ own firms but also to society as a whole.27

    Given that the orientation towards efficiency among CEOs outside experimental
    tasks is real it is natural to ask why this is so. Our data is not designed to offer con-
    clusive answers, but we can speculate as to some possible underlying factors in addi-
    tion to the mechanisms discussed in Sect. 3. First, the observed behavioral difference
    may be linked to market activity per se. Virtually all transactions on private markets
    involve voluntary agreements of at least two parties, which means that such trans-
    actions are inherently prosocial and may generate—or may attract and reinforce—
    a mindset oriented towards identifying efficiency enhancing win–win solutions.28
    The observed behavioral differences may also be related to the CEO’s leadership
    role within an organization. Social image and identification with the organization
    may be crucial for a business leader to mobilize support and loyalty from employees
    and business partners. Such experience may frame a CEO’s mindset and generate
    less aggressive and more prosocial choices in our experimental tasks (Akerlof and
    Kranton 2005; Benabou and Tirole 2006). Finally, CEOs may generally pay more
    attention to the responses of their ‘followers’ to their own actions. If this is the case,
    CEOs may have developed a certain style to lead ‘by example’ or ‘by sacrifice’
    (Hermalin 1998), which can involve costly cooperative or non-hawkish actions.29

    What are the implications of our findings? How do our results inform the lit-
    erature on the interplay between institutions and moral values and norms (Bowles
    1998)? Key ingredients for a successful institutional structure are what Douglass
    North denotes as “informal constraints”, which among other things, consist of
    “conventions and codes of behavior”, including norms (North 1990/2007, p. 4).
    To explain the development of norms is a highly complex problem involving the
    interplay between formal rules and informal constraints. However, as North points
    out: “Even if we do not possess a good explanation for social norms, we can model
    wealth-maximizing norms in a game theoretic context. That is, we can test, empiri-
    cally, what sorts of informal constraints are most likely to produce cooperative

    27 We do not claim that choosing certain strategies in experimental games necessarily reflects how CEOs
    run their firms. It is possible that the game choices reflect personal attitudes, which are unrelated to the
    choices made for their firms. In any case the potential connection between game choices and firm charac-
    teristics and outcomes is an interesting empirical question that ought to be addressed in future research.
    28 It should be stressed that our use of the term “prosocial” and win–win solutions only concerns the
    involved parties. We cannot say anything about potential prosocial behavior if a passive third party is
    affected by a negative externality, as in Falk and Szech (2013) and Bartling et al. (2015).
    29 This mechanism has gotten support in experiments where one player is assigned the leader role and
    the other the follower role (Potters et al. 2007).

    176 H. J. Holm et al.

    1 3

    behavior….” (Ibid., p. 43). We partly follow this approach by using games to study
    cooperative and non-aggressive behavior. We then analyze how the norms indirectly
    revealed by the strategy choices in these games differ between subjects embedded
    in different environments or “cultures”: Those heavily involved in strategic private
    market decisions (the CEOs) and those who are less likely to make socially relevant
    strategic decisions (the CG). While we did not strive to identify a definite causal
    explanation, the findings open the way for hypotheses as to how familiarity with
    strategic decision-making in private markets can affect soft institutions in a society.
    One can hypothesize that a frequent encounter with strategic market decisions fos-
    ters the emergence of norms favoring efficiency. Furthermore, if the within-group
    interaction is more pronounced than the interaction between distinct social groups,
    it would be reasonable to assume that cultures relying heavily on strategic market
    exchange will grow faster than others and may “export” wealth-creating norms to
    the rest of the society.30

    The orientation towards efficiency among our private company CEOs could
    imply that they also, by generating efficient informal constraints and within-group
    norms of cooperation, they can also shape institutions in the rest of the economy
    over time. Our finding may serve as a step in increasing our understanding of how
    economic institutional development can be “channelled” through private markets in
    transition economies such as China.31

    7 Conclusion

    As the health of most economies depends on the aggregate behavior of their busi-
    ness leaders and CEOs, it is a crucial task for economic theory to understand and
    predict the behavior of these individuals. Equally important, it is of interest to learn
    in what way CEOs may influence the norms in the societies they live in. This ques-
    tion can be related to the broader debate as to how private markets and a frequent
    reliance on market exchange affect norms and values.

    We investigate the strategic decision-making of private-firm CEOs in well-
    defined games. In particular, we study whether CEOs differ from that of other com-
    parable subjects, in what we believe to be the most ambitious study of CEO’s behav-
    ior in strategic games thus far. For this research, we recruited a stratified random
    sample of 200 CEOs and a carefully selected sample of 200 control group members
    to participate in three incentivized strategic games, the Prisoner’s Dilemma, the Bat-
    tle-of-the-Sexes, and the Chicken game. We find substantial differences in behavior

    30 This efficiency orientation among private CEOs is likely to be transmitted to actors in the surrounding
    society, both because its relative success may stimulate others to imitate their strategies and also because
    as the private sector grows in importance, its leaders have the ability and power to persuade others to
    accept their own norms and values (e.g., politicians, bureaucrats employees).
    31 Nee and Opper (2012) argue that much of the recent institutional change in China is a bottom up pro-
    cess, driven by private entrepreneurs. This conclusion is supported by a multitude of historical facts, reg-
    istry data and observations from interviews. A more formal agent-based model of this bottom-up process
    is offered in DellaPosta et al. (2017).

    177

    1 3
    Strategic decisions: behavioral differences between CEOs…

    between the CEOs and the control group, but not in the way many would expect.
    The CEOs were not in general closer to the Nash equilibrium prediction (assum-
    ing selfish preferences). On the contrary, the average control group behavior was
    closer to the Nash equilibrium in the majority of the games and did not best respond
    less frequently to their beliefs. The most striking and consistent pattern was that the
    CEOs had higher expected earnings than the comparison group in all the games. The
    CEOs cooperated more and played less hawkishly compared to the control group,
    no matter how the game was framed (abstractly or with a narrative). Compared to
    the control group the CEOs’ also had significantly higher average beliefs that others
    would cooperate in the Prisoner’s Dilemma.

    Open Access This article is distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 Interna-
    tional License (http://creat iveco mmons .org/licen ses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted use, distribution,
    and reproduction in any medium, provided you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the
    source, provide a link to the Creative Commons license, and indicate if changes were made.

    References

    Akerlof, G., & Kranton, R. (2005). Identity and the economics of organizations. Journal of Economic
    Perspectives, 19, 9–32.

    Alger, I., & Weibull, J. W. (2013). Homo moralis—preference evolution under incomplete information
    and assortative matching. Econometrica, 81, 2269–2302.

    Andersen, S., Ertac, S., Gneezy, U., Hoffman, M., & List, J. A. (2011). Stakes matter in ultimatum games.
    American Economics Review, 101, 3427–3439.

    Andreoni, J., & Bernheim, B. D. (2009). Social image and the 50–50 norm: A theoretical and experimen-
    tal analysis of audience effects. Econometrica, 77, 1607–1636.

    Åstebro, T., Herz, H., Nanda, R., & Weber, R. A. (2014). Seeking the roots of entrepreneurship: Insights
    from behavioral economics. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 28, 49–69.

    Bartling, B., Weber, R. A., & Yao, L. (2015). Do markets erode social responsibility? Quarterly Journal
    of Economics, 119, 219–266.

    Benabou, R., & Tirole, J. (2006). Incentives and prosocial behavior. American Economic Review, 96,
    1652–1678.

    Benabou, R., & Tirole, J. (2010). Individual and corporate social responsibility. Economica, 77, 1–19.
    Bergstrom, T. C. (2002). Evolution of social behavior: Individual and group selection. Journal of Eco-

    nomic Perspectives, 16, 67–88.
    Bernardo, A. E., & Welch, I. (2001). On the evolution of overconfidence and entrepreneurs. Journal of

    Economics & Management Strategy, 10, 301–330.
    Bernheim, B. D. (1994). A theory of conformity. Journal of Political Economy, 102, 841–877.
    Bertrand, M., & Schoar, A. (2003). Managing with style: The effect of managers on firm policies. Quar-

    terly Journal of Economics, 118, 1169–1208.
    Blanco, M., Engelmann, D., Koch, A. K., & Normann, H.-T. (2010). Belief elicitation in experiments: Is

    there a hedging problem? Experimental Economics, 13, 412–438.
    Bolton, P., Brunnermeier, M. K., & Veldkamp, L. (2013). Leadership, coordination, and corporate cul-

    ture. The Review of Economic Studies, 80, 512–537.
    Bowles, S. (1998). Endogenous preferences: The cultural consequences of markets and other economic

    institutions. Journal of Economic Literature, 36, 75–111.
    Bowles, S., & Gintis, H. (2011). A cooperative species: Human reciprocity and its evolution. Princeton,

    NJ: Princeton University Press.
    Cooper, D. J. (2006). Are experienced managers experts at overcoming coordination failure? B.E. Jour-

    nal of Economic Analysis & Policy (Advances), 6.
    Cooper, D. J., Kagel, J. H., Lo, W., & Gu, Q. L. (1999). Gaming against managers in incentive systems:

    Experimental results with Chinese students and chinese managers. American Economic Review, 89,
    781–804.

    http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/

    178 H. J. Holm et al.

    1 3

    Cooper, D. J., & Saral, K. J. (2013). Entrepreneurship and team participation: An experimental study.
    European Economic Review, 59, 126–140.

    Crawford, V. P., Gneezy, U., & Rottenstreich, Y. (2008). The power of focal points is limited: Even
    minute payoff asymmetry may yield large coordination failures. American Economic Review, 98,
    1443–1458.

    Croson, R., & Gneezy, U. (2009). Gender differences in preferences. Journal of Economic Literature, 47,
    1–27.

    Cubitt, R. P., Drouvelis, M., & Gächter, S. (2011). Framing and free riding: Emotional responses and
    punishment in social dilemma games. Experimental Economics, 14, 254–272.

    DellaPosta, D., Nee, V., & Opper, S. (2017). Endogenous dynamics of institutional change. Rationality
    and Society, 29, 5–48.

    Dohmen, T., Falk, A., Huffman, D., Sunde, U., Schupp, J., & Wagner, G. (2011). Individual risk attitudes:
    Measurement, determinants, and behavioral consequences. Journal of the European Economic
    Association, 9, 522–550.

    Ellickson, R. (1991). Order without law. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
    Elston, J. A., Harrison, G. W., & Rutström, E. E. (2006). Experimental economics, entrepreneurs and the

    entry decision. UCF Economics Department Working Paper No. 6, 2006.
    Engelmann, D., & Strobel, M. (2004). Inequality aversion, efficiency, and maximin preferences in simple

    distribution experiments. American Economic Review, 94, 857–869.
    Falk, A., & Szech, N. (2013). Morals and markets. Science, 340, 707–711.
    Fehr, E., & List, J. (2004). The hidden costs and returns of incentives: Trust and trustworthiness among

    CEOs. Journal of the European Economic Association, 2, 743–771.
    Fehr, E., & Schmidt, K. M. (1999). A theory of fairness, competition, and cooperation. Quarterly Journal

    of Economics, 114, 817–868.
    Foss, N. J. (2001). Leadership, beliefs and coordination: An explorative discussion. Industrial and Cor-

    porate Change, 10, 357–388.
    Fréchette, G. R. (2015). Laboratory experiments: Professionals versus students. In G. R. Fréchette & A.

    Schotter (Eds.), Handbook of experimental economic methodology (360–390). Oxford: Oxford Uni-
    versity Press.

    Gächter, S., & Renner, E. (2010). The effect of (incentivized) belief elicitation in public good experi-
    ments. Experimental Economics, 13, 364–377.

    Gallani, S., Krishnan, R., & Wooldridge, J. M. (2016). Applications of fractional response model to the
    study of bounded dependent variables in accounting research. Harvard Business School working
    paper, 016.

    Glaeser, E. L., Laibson, D. I., Scheinkman, J. A., & Soutter, C. L. (2000). Measuring trust. The Quarterly
    Journal of Economics, 115, 811–846.

    Güth, W., Schmidt, C., & Sutter, M. (2007). Bargaining outside the lab: A newspaper experiment of a
    three-player ultimatum game. Economics Journal, 117, 449–469.

    Harrison, G. W., & List, J. (2004). Field experiments. Journal of Economic Literature, 42, 1009–1055.
    Hayward, M. L., Shepherd, D. A., & Griffin, D. (2006). A hubris theory of entrepreneurship. Manage-

    ment Science, 52, 160–172.
    Henrich, J., Boyd, R., Bowles, S., Camerer, C., Gintis, H., McElreath, R., et al. (2001). In search of homo

    economicus: Experiments in 15 small-scale societies. American Economic Review, 91, 73–79.
    Hermalin, B. (1998). Toward a theory of leading by example. American Economic Review, 88,

    1188–1206.
    Holm, H. J., Opper, S., & Nee, V. (2013). Entrepreneurs under uncertainty: An economic experiment in

    China. Management Science, 59, 1671–1687.
    Hvide, H. K., & Panos, G. A. (2015). Risk tolerance and entrepreneurship. Journal of Financial Econom-

    ics, 111, 200–223.
    Kagel, J., & Roth, A. (1995). The handbook of experimental economics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton Univer-

    sity Press.
    Kihlstrom, R. E., & Laffont, J.-L. (1979). A general equilibrium entrepreneurial theory of firm formation

    based on risk aversion. Journal of Political Economy, 87, 710–748.
    Koudstaal, M., Sloof, R., & Van Praag, M. (2016). Risk, uncertainty, and entrepreneurship: evidence

    from a lab-in-the-field experiment. Management Science, 62, 2897–2915.
    Kurzban, R., & Houser, D. (2005). Experiments investigating cooperative types in humans: A comple-

    ment to evolutionary theory and simulations. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of
    the United States of America, 102, 1803–1807.

    179

    1 3
    Strategic decisions: behavioral differences between CEOs…

    Levin, I. P., Schneider, S. L., & Gaeth, G. J. (1998). All frames are not created equal: A typology and
    critical analysis of framing effects. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 76,
    149–188.

    Marshall, A. (1890/1920). Principles of economics, 8th ed. London: Macmillan & Co.
    Masclet, D., Colombier, N., Denant-Boemont, L., & Lohéac, Y. (2009). Group and individual risk prefer-

    ences: A lottery-choice experiment with self-employed and salaried workers. Journal of Economic
    Behavior & Organization, 70, 470–484.

    Montmarquette, C., Rullière, J.-L., Villeval, M. C., & Zeiliger, R. (2004). Redesigning teams and incen-
    tives in a merger. An experiment with managers and students. Management Science, 50, 1379–1389.

    Nee, V., Holm, H. J., & Opper, S. (2018). Learning to trust: From relational exchange to generalized trust
    in China. Organization Science, 29, 969–986.

    Nee, V., & Opper, S. (2012). Capitalism from below: Markets and institutional change in China. Cam-
    bridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    North, D. (1990/2007). Institutions, institutional change, and economic performance. Cambridge, UK:
    Cambridge University Press.

    Ockenfels, A., & Weimann, J. (1999). Types and patterns: An experimental East-West-German compari-
    son of cooperation and solidarity. Journal of Public Economics, 71, 275–287.

    Opper, S., Nee, V., & Holm, H. J. (2017). Risk aversion and guanxi activities: A behavioral analysis of
    CEOs in China. Academy of Management Journal, 60, 1504–1530.

    Palacios-Huerta, I., & Volij, O. (2008). Experentia docet: Professionals play minimax in laboratory
    experiments. Econometrica, 76, 71–115.

    Papke, L. E., & Wooldridge, J. M. (1996). Econometric methods for fractional response variables with
    an application to 401 (K) plan participation rates. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 11, 619–663.

    Parravano, M., & Poulsen, O. (2015). Stake size and the power of focal points in coordination games:
    Experimental evidence. Games and Economic Behavior, 94, 191–199.

    Potters, J., Sefton, M., & Vesterlund, L. (2007). Leading by example and signaling in voluntary contribu-
    tion games: An experimental study. Economic Theory, 33, 169–182.

    Schelling, T. C. (1960). The strategy of conflict. Cambridge, USA: Harvard University Press.
    Shleifer, A. (2004). Does competition destroy ethical behavior? American Economic Review Papers and

    Proceedings, 94, 414–418.
    Smith, J. M. (1982). Evolution and the theory of games. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.
    Thöni, C., Tyran, J.-R., & Wengström, E. (2012). Microfoundations of social capital. Journal of Public

    Economics, 96, 636–643.
    Tirole, J. (1988). The theory of industrial organization. Cambridge, MT: MIT Press.
    Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. (1981). The framing of decisions and the psychology of choice. Science,

    211, 453–458.
    Van de Ven, A. H., Sapienza, H. J., & Villanueva, J. (2007). Entrepreneurial pursuits of self- and collec-

    tive interests. Strategic Entrepreneurship Journal, 1, 353–370.
    Van Praag, M., & Cramer, J. S. (2001). The roots of entrepreneurship and labour demand: Individual abil-

    ity and low risk aversion. Economica, 68, 45–69.
    Von Neumann, J., & Morgenstern, O. (1944). The theory of games and economic behavior. Princeton,

    NJ: Princeton University Press.
    Wu, B., & Knott, A.-M. (2006). Entrepreneurial risk and market entry. Management Science, 52,

    1315–1330.

    Publisher’s Note Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published
    maps and institutional affiliations.

    180 H. J. Holm et al.

    1 3

    Affiliations

    Håkan J. Holm1  · Victor Nee2 · Sonja Opper1

    * Håkan J. Holm
    Hakan.Holm@nek.lu.se

    Victor Nee
    Victor.Nee@cornell.edu

    Sonja Opper
    Sonja.Opper@nek.lu.se

    1 Department of Economics, School of Economics and Management, Lund University, P.O.
    Box 7082, 22007 Lund, Sweden

    2 Department of Sociology, Cornell University, Ithaca, USA

    http://orcid.org/0000-0001-5783-2463

    Reproduced with permission of copyright owner.
    Further reproduction prohibited without permission.

    • Strategic decisions: behavioral differences between CEOs and others
    • Abstract
      1 Introduction
      2 Related literature
      3 Theory and hypotheses
      3.1 Prisoner’s Dilemma
      3.2 Battle-of-the-sexes
      3.3 Chicken
      3.4 Hypotheses
      4 Research strategy and design
      4.1 Tasks and treatments
      4.2 Sampling and descriptive statistics
      4.3 Execution
      5 Results
      5.1 Behavior in the games
      5.1.1 Probabilities for outcomes and expected payoffs
      5.1.2 Regression analysis
      5.2 Beliefs
      5.2.1 Difference in beliefs: a regression analysis
      5.2.2 Beliefs and behavior
      5.2.3 Best responses to beliefs
      5.2.4 Accuracy of beliefs
      5.3 Concerns and robustness tests
      6 Explanations and implications
      7 Conclusion
      References

    O R I G I N A L P A P E R

    How Does Ethical Leadership Trickle Down? Test
    of an Integrative Dual-Process Model

    Zhen Wang1 • Haoying Xu1 • Yukun Liu2

    Received: 29 April 2016 / Accepted: 13 October 2016 / Published online: 20 October 2016

    � Springer Science+Business Media Dordrecht 2016

    Abstract Although the trickle-down effect of

    ethical

    leadership has been documented in the literature, its

    underlying mechanism still remains largely unclear. To

    address this gap, we develop a cross-level dual-process

    model to explain how the effect occurs. Drawing on social

    learning theory, we hypothesize that the ethical

    leadership

    of high-level managers could cascade to middle-level

    supervisors via its impact on middle-level supervisors’ two

    ethical expectations. Using a sample of 69 middle-level

    supervisors and 381 subordinates across 69 sub-branches

    from a large banking firm in China, we found that middle-

    level supervisors’ ethical efficacy expectation and unethi-

    cal behavior–punishment expectation (as one form of eth-

    ical outcome expectations) accounted for the trickle-down

    effect. The explanatory role of middle-level supervisors’

    ethical behavior–reward expectation (as the other form of

    ethical outcome expectations), however, was not sup-

    ported. The theoretical and practical implications are

    discussed.

    Keywords Ethical leadership � Ethical efficacy
    expectation � Ethical outcome expectation �
    Social learning theory

    Introduction

    Recent years have seen an onslaught of cases relating to

    corporate fraud and scandals, inflicting great pain on

    organizations and society. Against this background, an

    increasing amount of attention has been paid to the topic of

    ethical leadership in organizational research (Brown and

    Treviño 2006; Treviño et al. 2014). Being defined as ‘‘the

    demonstration of normatively appropriate conduct through

    personal actions and interpersonal relationships, and the

    promotion of such conduct to followers through two-way

    communication, reinforcement, and decision making’’

    (Brown et al. 2005, p. 120), ethical leadership has been

    found to be positively related to a wide range of beneficial

    outcomes, including task performance, citizenship behav-

    iors, ethical conducts, and so forth (for systematic reviews,

    see Bedi et al. 2015; Ng and Feldman 2015). Given these

    positive outcomes, both researchers and practitioners have

    engaged in identifying the antecedents of ethical leadership

    and thus have accumulated a considerable body of evi-

    dence (den Hartog 2015; Treviño and Brown 2014).

    Among several streams of research, there is one suggesting

    a ‘‘trickle-down’’ effect of ethical leadership, which argues

    that ethical leadership of high-level leaders could cascade

    downward and influence the ethical leadership of middle-

    level supervisors (Mayer et al. 2009; Ruiz et al. 2011a, b;

    Schaubroeck et al. 2012).

    However, these accumulated studies on the trickle-down

    effect of ethical leadership are limited in a critical way.

    Although almost all studies have relied on social learning

    & Yukun Liu
    liuyukun@u.nus.edu

    Zhen Wang

    wangzhen@cufe.edu.cn

    Haoying Xu

    xuyingzhongshan@163.com

    1
    Department of Organization and Human Resources

    Management, Business School, Central University of Finance

    and Economics, 39 South College Road, Haidian District,

    Beijing 100081, People’s Republic of China

    2
    Department of Management and Organization, NUS Business

    School, National University of Singapore, B2-03, Biz 2

    Building, 1 Business Link, Singapore 117592, Singapore

    123

    J Bus Ethics (2018) 153:691–705

    https://doi.org/10.1007/s10551-016-3361-x

    http://crossmark.crossref.org/dialog/?doi=10.1007/s10551-016-3361-x&domain=pdf

    http://crossmark.crossref.org/dialog/?doi=10.1007/s10551-016-3361-x&domain=pdf

    https://doi.org/10.1007/s10551-016-3361-x

    theory to explain the mechanisms underlying the effect,

    none of them has used social learning-related constructs to

    test this account. As noted in a recent article by Sumanth

    and Hannah (2014, p. 46), ‘‘in investigating the effects of

    ethical leadership of higher level organizational leaders on

    lower level leaders…though frequently theorized, we are
    not aware of any research that has actually tested social

    learning as a mediator in the cascading process.’’ The lack

    of such research results in an unclear understanding of the

    intermediate process through which the trickle-down effect

    occurs. Given this research gap, the current study intends to

    continue the momentum of research on the trickle-down

    effect of ethical leadership and advance further to examine

    its underlying mechanism, aiming to provide a better

    understanding of how ethical leadership cascades from

    high-level managers to middle-level supervisors within an

    organization.

    Specifically, we propose ethical efficacy expectation and

    ethical outcome

    expectation

    1

    as mediators to disentangle

    the cascading process of ethical leadership. Social learning

    theory emphasizes the importance of individual’s cognition

    in the regulation of human behaviors and posits that ‘‘most

    external influences affect behavior through intermediary

    cognitive processes’’ (Bandura 1977, p. 160). In particular,

    the changes in efficacy expectation and outcome expecta-

    tion are the most important intermediate cognitive pro-

    cesses that link external influences to behavioral changes

    (Bandura 1977; Manz and Sims 1981). Given that our

    focus is on the ethical realm, we concentrate on ethical

    efficacy expectation and ethical outcome expectation in the

    current research. Ethical efficacy expectation (i.e., ethical

    efficacy) refers to ‘‘individuals’ belief in their ability to

    mobilize the motivation, cognitive resources, and courses

    of action necessary to execute ethical behavior’’ (Mitchell

    and Palmer 2010, p. 92); ethical outcome expectation

    represents ‘‘individuals’ perception of the likelihood that

    an [ethical/unethical] behavior will lead to a particular

    [reward or punishment] outcome’’ (Ashkanasy et al. 2006,

    p. 450). Social learning theory holds that an individual’s

    efficacy expectation and outcome expectation are suscep-

    tible to the influence of role models (e.g., leaders) through

    a vicarious learning process (Manz and Sims 1981). Thus,

    it is reasonable to suggest that, the ethical leadership of

    high-level managers, who oftentimes are regarded as role

    models, will exert an influence on the ethical efficacy

    expectation and ethical outcome expectation of middle-

    level supervisors, which will in turn elicit their ethical

    leadership

    behaviors.

    We tested our theoretical model using a sample from a

    large banking firm. Results generally provided support to

    our hypotheses. By conducting this research, we contribute

    to the extant literature in three ways. First, this study

    advances the existing research on the trickle-down effect of

    ethical leadership by delineating the underlying mecha-

    nisms. By considering ethical efficacy expectation and

    ethical outcome expectation as mediators, the present study

    provides a direct examination of the trickle-down effect of

    ethical leadership from the social learning perspective.

    Second, this study extends the research on ethical efficacy

    by providing further insights into its nomological network.

    In the early 1990s, Bandura (1991) suggested that moral/

    ethical beliefs could be applied to ethical situations, sug-

    gesting the existence of ethical efficacy. It is only recently,

    however, that a few studies have formally conceptualized

    and operationalized this construct and studied its relevance

    to ethics (Arnaud and Schminke 2012; Hannah and Avolio

    2010). Even so, research on ethical efficacy still remains

    largely in its infancy, and thus warrants further investiga-

    tion (Hannah et al. 2011). This said, the present study

    addresses this call and enriches our understanding of eth-

    ical efficacy. Third, this study also highlights the role of

    ethical outcome expectation and advances the literature by

    contextualizing it in the ethical leadership context (Ash-

    kanasy et al. 2006; Treviño and Youngblood 1990), illu-

    minating another important psychological mechanism that

    could explain the function of ethical leadership. Taken

    together, using social learning theory as a theoretical

    framework, our research aims to answer the question how

    ethical leadership of high-level managers trickles down to

    influence the ethical leadership of middle-level supervisors.

    Our research model is depicted in Fig. 1 as shown below.

    Theory and Hypotheses

    Manager Ethical Leadership and Supervisor Ethical

    leadership

    Social learning theory is based on the idea that an indi-

    vidual learns by paying attention to and emulating the

    attitudes, values, and behaviors of role models (Bandura

    1977). As to the learning of ethical conducts in organiza-

    tions, although individuals can rely on organization’s for-

    mal regulations or norms to gain ethics-related knowledge,

    they can also learn ethical conducts via a modeling process,

    in which they look for role models in the organization and

    emulate their ethical attitudes, values, and behaviors

    (Brown et al. 2005). This modeling process not only

    applies to followers who regard their leaders as role

    models, but also applies to leaders themselves, who also

    learn from their role models. Indeed, as Brown and Treviño

    1
    Consistent with the common practices in the management field

    (e.g., Mitchell and Palmer 2010; Treviño et al. 2006), we used the

    terms ethical and moral interchangeably in this paper.

    692 Z. Wang et al.

    123

    (2006, p. 600) highlighted, ‘‘followers are not the only ones

    who learn from models. Leaders learn from models too. By

    observing an ethical role model’s behavior as well as the

    consequences of their behavior, leaders should come to

    identify with the model, internalize the model’s value and

    attitudes, and emulate the modeled behavior.’’ Then it

    comes to the question who would be leaders’ ethical role

    models. A few studies have answered this question and

    suggested that top managers or top executives in an orga-

    nization could serve as ethical role models for middle-level

    supervisors (see examples in Mayer et al. 2009; Ruiz et al.

    2011a). The reasons supporting supervisors as ethical role

    models for frontline employees, as suggested by existing

    studies (Brown et al. 2005; Brown and Treviño 2006),

    could also be extended to the dyadic relationships between

    high-level managers and middle-level supervisors, in

    which supervisors become followers of high-level man-

    agers. Just like supervisors, having power, status, and the

    control over the reward/punishment system, as well as

    having personal characteristics such as being honest and

    trustworthy, high-level managers are legitimate, attractive,

    and credible to be regarded as ethical role models, from

    whom supervisors could emulate the ethical conducts

    (Bandura 1977). Based upon the above reasoning as well as

    the findings in several existing studies (e.g., Mayer et al.

    2009; Ruiz et al. 2011a, b; Schaubroeck et al. 2012), we

    propose the trickle-down effect of ethical leadership of

    high-level managers on their immediate supervisors. By

    using high-level managers, we refer to managers whom

    middle-level supervisors work closely and communicate

    frequently with, but not those distant top executives. Our

    rationale is that ethical role modeling is a ‘‘side by side’’

    phenomenon (Weaver et al. 2005), and middle-level

    supervisors have more chances to observe and imitate

    ethical behaviors of their intimate leaders (i.e., high-level

    managers), rather than those of top or executive managers

    (Brown and Treviño 2014). We propose that:

    Hypothesis 1 High-level managers’ ethical leadership

    relates positively to middle-level supervisors’ ethical

    leadership.

    The Mediating Effect of Ethical Efficacy

    Expectation

    As an ethical cognition (Schaubroeck et al. 2012), ethical

    efficacy expectation (i.e., ethical efficacy) represents indi-

    viduals’ confidence in their ability to execute ethical

    behaviors (Hannah and Avolio 2010; Mitchell and Palmer

    2010). Unlike the trait-like general

    efficacy expectation

    which is more stable, ethical efficacy expectation is more

    state-like, which indicates that it could be influenced to

    change. Existing research has found that ethical efficacy

    expectation is susceptible to external influences (Fischbach

    2015; Hannah and Avolio 2010; May et al. 2013) and could

    play an important role in ethics-relevant situations (Arnaud

    and Schminke 2012; Lee et al. 2015). In the present study, we

    consider ethical efficacy expectation as a crucial factor that

    contributes to the cascading of high-level managers’ ethical

    leadership. We analyze its role from two aspects as follows.

    In one aspect, given that an ethical role model plays a

    critical role in developing and strengthening one’s ethical

    efficacy beliefs (Bandura 1991), we believe that high-level

    managers’ ethical leadership would exert a positive influence

    on middle-level supervisors’

    ethical efficacy expectation.

    According to the social learning theory, expectations of

    efficacy are based on four sources of information: perfor-

    mance accomplishments, vicarious experience, verbal per-

    suasion, and emotional arousal, and these four sources could

    be further influenced by different modes of induction (Ban-

    dura 1977). Bandura presented a framework in which many

    external factors induce sources of efficacy, which in turn

    impacts efficacy. For instance, he argued that participant

    modeling, performance desensitization, performance expo-

    sure, and self-instructed performance could lead to

    Research Model

    Manager’s
    Ethical

    Leadership

    Ethical Efficacy Expectation

    Supervisor’s Ethical Efficacy Expectation

    Ethical Outcome Expectation

    Supervisor’s Ethical Behavior-Reward Expectation
    Supervisor’s Unethical Behavior-Punishment Expectation

    Supervisor’s

    Ethical Leadership

    Level 2

    Level 1

    Fig. 1 Research model

    How Does Ethical Leadership Trickle Down?… 693

    123

    individuals’ performance accomplishments, which in turn

    increase their efficacy, while suggestions, exhortation, self-

    instruction, and interpretive treatments are inducements of

    verbal persuasion, which in turn impacts efficacy. That said,

    these four sources are not sub-dimensions of efficacy, rather,

    they are more like the determinants of efficacy and the

    mechanisms through which external factors influence effi-

    cacy. In our research, based on this ‘‘mode of induc-

    tion ? sources of efficacy ? efficacy’’ framework and the
    function of ethical leadership as the mode of induction (e.g.,

    participant modeling, suggestions), we theorized that ethical

    leadership would induce individuals’ performance accom-

    plishments, vicarious experience, verbal persuasion, and

    emotional arousal, which would ultimately increase their

    ethical

    efficacy.

    First, high-level managers’ ethical leadership can

    enhance middle-level supervisors’ ethical efficacy expecta-

    tion through performance accomplishments. Ethical man-

    agers set high moral standards and hold their followers

    accountable for ethical issues through using proactive and

    effective measures (e.g., using reward systems, conveying

    ethics-related messages) (Brown et al. 2005). These tactics

    can ultimately help supervisors to achieve ethical perfor-

    mance and thus enable them to have more opportunities to

    obtain personal attainment and success in an ethics-related

    domain. Second, supervisors’ ethical efficacy expectation

    can be enhanced through their own vicarious experience

    (Bandura 1991). In other words, supervisors can strengthen

    their ethical efficacy expectation by vicariously observing

    what others do when being faced with an ethics-related issue.

    Ethical managers, given their legitimacy, attractiveness, and

    credibility, of course are the role models whom supervisors

    would learn from when facing an ethical issue (Brown et al.

    2005). Third, verbal persuasion from ethical managers can

    ameliorate supervisors’ ethical efficacy expectation. Ethical

    managers usually would discuss business ethics or values

    openly with their immediate supervisors and encourage them

    to ask ‘‘what is the right thing to do’’ when making decisions

    (Brown et al. 2005). Through this communication process,

    ethical managers verbally convey the message to their

    immediate supervisors that ethical behaviors are appropriate

    and should be encouraged, hence enhancing supervisors’

    ethical efficacy expectation (Bandura 1977). Fourth, ethical

    managers define success not only by outcomes, but also by

    the ways how the outcomes are achieved. This philosophy

    helps alleviate followers’ affective concerns (e.g., anxiety or

    stress) that usually relate to outcomes and thus enables fol-

    lowers to pay more attention to the ethicality of their

    approaches in achieving goals (Lee et al. 2015; Walumbwa

    et al. 2011). Additionally, ethical managers expect, appre-

    ciate, and support their immediate supervisors’ ethical

    behaviors. Such expectations, appreciation, and support may

    make supervisors feel proud and emotionally delighted when

    exhibiting ethical behaviors, thus enhancing their ethical

    efficacy expectation. Apart from the above four sources,

    Hannah and Avolio (2010) recently added another one,

    which involves providing and articulating organizational

    support measures that could equip leaders with the confi-

    dence to take ethical actions. By setting the ethical tone of the

    work unit, stressing the importance of ethical behaviors and

    using a reward system to incentivize ethical behaviors, eth-

    ical managers can establish a social environment that pro-

    vides the necessary support for their immediate supervisors

    to adhere to ethical standards and engage in ethical behav-

    iors. Such an ethical social environment could boost super-

    visors’ confidence to behave ethically, thus enhancing their

    ethical efficacy expectation (Schaubroeck et al. 2012).

    In the other aspect, we propose that enhanced ethical

    efficacy expectation will motivate middle-level supervisors

    to exhibit ethical leadership behaviors. According to Ban-

    dura (1997), how people behave is better predicted by their

    beliefs about their capabilities rather than by their actual

    capabilities. The same logic has also been extended to the

    realm of moral behavior regulation by Bandura (1991),

    who contended that ethical efficacy expectation is a critical

    cognitive process for moral thoughts and behaviors. Ethical

    efficacy expectation instills in supervisors a sense of con-

    fidence in their capabilities to organize and mobilize the

    cognitive resources to attain moral performance and regu-

    late their behaviors to meet inner moral standards, thus

    ensuring that they will engage in ethical behaviors even in

    an ethically adverse situation (Hannah and Avolio 2010;

    Mitchell and Palmer 2010). Extending to the case of

    middle-level ethical supervisors, given that they bear the

    ‘‘moral manager’’ responsibility to hold followers

    accountable for their ethical/unethical behaviors (Brown

    et al. 2005), ethical efficacy expectation will be more

    necessary for supervisors’ exhibition of ethical leadership

    behaviors.

    Summarizing the above two aspects of theorizing, we

    conjecture that ethical efficacy expectation would serve as

    an intermediate factor linking high-level managers’ ethical

    leadership and their immediate supervisors’ ethical lead-

    ership. We propose that:

    Hypothesis 2 The relationship between high-level man-

    agers’ ethical leadership and middle-level supervisors’

    ethical leadership is mediated by middle-level supervisors’

    ethical efficacy expectation.

    The Mediating Effect of Ethical Outcome

    Expectation

    Outcome expectation is the other intermediate cognition in

    social learning theory. Distinguished from efficacy expec-

    tation, which represents one’s perceived ability to execute

    694 Z. Wang et al.

    123

    a behavior, outcome expectation is one’s judgment con-

    cerning the likelihood of outcomes resulting from a specific

    behavior (Manz and Sims 1981). According to Bandura

    (1977), the consequences of a behavior, which inform

    individuals about the benefits of an appropriate conduct

    and the costs of an inappropriate conduct, can facilitate

    individuals’ learning from their role models. Extending this

    notion to the ethical leadership area, we consider ethical

    outcome expectation as a key factor in the trickle-down

    process of ethical leadership and argue that high-level

    managers’ ethical leadership can promote their immediate

    supervisors’ ethical leadership through shaping their

    expectations of ethical outcomes.

    According to the social learning perspective, individuals

    form their ethical outcome expectations through two ways:

    (1) being rewarded for their own ethical behaviors or pun-

    ished for their own unethical behaviors (direct learning) and

    (2) observing or hearing about the consequences of others’

    ethical or unethical behaviors in the workplace (vicarious

    learning). The latter way, which stresses the role of models

    in the process of learning, is the primary learning approach

    (Bandura 1977). Having said that ethical leaders would

    serve as role models for supervisors to learn ethical con-

    ducts and given the above arguments on ethical outcome

    expectations, we reason that ethical managers would play a

    crucial role in affecting immediate supervisors’ ethical

    outcome expectations. First, being ethical role models for

    their immediate supervisors, ethical managers would lead

    them to believe that managers’ ethical leadership has been

    rewarded in the past. Indeed, as Bandura suggested, which

    was also noted in Weiss (1977), a role model’s (i.e., leader)

    attributes such as status, power, or perceived competence

    would lead observers (i.e., followers) to believe that the

    model’s behaviors have been rewarded in the past or are

    appropriate in the situation, and this information would

    affect observers’ expectations that engaging in similar

    behaviors would lead to eventual rewards. Second, ethical

    managers will shape immediate supervisors’ ethical out-

    come expectations through rewarding those who behave

    ethically and punishing those who behave unethically in the

    workplace (Detert et al. 2007). When supervisors observe

    the consequences of ethical behaviors and unethical

    behaviors, they will learn what is considered appropriate

    and inappropriate concerning ethical issues in the organi-

    zation (Davis and Luthans 1980; Manz and Sims 1981). In

    other words, these social cues would convey a message to

    supervisors that behaving ethically is appropriate and will

    be rewarded, whereas behaving unethically is inappropriate

    and will be punished (Brown et al. 2005; Brown and Tre-

    viño 2006). Accordingly, these outcome

    expectations

    would facilitate supervisor’s learning in an anticipatory

    ethical manner and influence them to engage in more ethical

    leadership behaviors.

    To summarize, the reasoning above suggests that the

    relationship between high-level managers’ ethical leader-

    ship and middle-level supervisors’ ethical leadership could

    be mediated by the ethical outcome expectations of middle-

    level supervisors. To examine this mediating mechanism in

    more depth, we further differentiate ethical outcome

    expectation into two types: ethical

    behavior–reward

    expectation, which refers to the perceived likelihood of

    getting rewards for ethical behaviors; and unethical

    behavior–punishment expectation, which refers to the

    perceived likelihood of getting punished for unethical

    behaviors. We propose that:

    Hypothesis 3 The relationship between high-level man-

    agers’ ethical leadership and middle-level supervisors’
    ethical leadership is mediated by middle-level supervisors’

    ethical behavior–reward expectation.

    Hypothesis 4 The relationship between high-level man-

    agers’ ethical leadership and middle-level supervisors’
    ethical leadership is mediated by middle-level supervisors’

    unethical behavior–punishment expectation.

    Method

    Sample and Procedure

    We collected multilevel and multi-source data from a large

    banking company in China. This banking company has 120

    sub-branches and 976 employees (including front desk

    clerks and back office staff) in total. At the most basic level

    of the bank, each sub-branch runs independently as a

    standard operating team that consists of one supervisor

    (i.e., middle-level supervisor in the organizational hierar-

    chy) and several subordinates. Each sub-branch is under

    the control of a high-level manager from the corresponding

    regional branch of the bank. We chose to conduct the

    research in the banking industry for a few reasons. First, it

    provides a suitable context for researchers to do ethics-

    related research. The banking industry is more likely to

    induce employees to conduct unethical behaviors than

    other industries because it is characterized by higher stress

    and less regulation (Ruiz-Palomino et al. 2013). Although

    ethics in this industry has garnered tremendous public

    attention and urged government to adopt strict regulation

    measures, the number of fraud and scandals is still on the

    rise (Boatright 2010). As ethical leadership has been rec-

    ognized as an effective way to restrain unethical conduct

    and elicit ethical behaviors in the banking industry (e.g.,

    Ruiz-Palomino et al. 2011, 2013; Sims and Brinkman

    2002; Walumbwa and Schaubroeck 2009), it would be

    meaningful to examine why and how ethical leadership

    behavior cascades downward to shape a collective ethical

    How Does Ethical Leadership Trickle Down?… 695

    123

    leadership culture in such an industry (Treviño et al. 2003).

    Second, although most banking firms have ethics-related

    policies, norms, or codes that regulate supervisors’

    behaviors (Treviño et al. 2003), the boundaries between

    ethical and unethical behaviors in many banks are still

    quite vague, which makes supervisors more likely to learn

    from their direct leaders (i.e., high-level managers) about

    what is right and what is wrong in the organization. This

    said, the cross-level influences of leadership on employees’

    ethics become very relevant a phenomenon in banking

    firms. Third, most banking firms have a typical hierarchical

    structure in which managers in charge of higher-level

    branches have control over resource allocation, goal set-

    ting, and reward/punishment system, while supervisors in

    charge of lower-level branches report directly to these

    managers. This difference in authority between higher-

    level managers and lower-level supervisors, along with the

    frequent interactions between them, meet the prerequisite

    of social learning process, making the trickle-down effect

    of ethical leadership possible in the context of banking

    firms.

    Through personal social network and alumni contacts,

    we approached 79 sub-branches. Our research assistants

    communicated with the branch directors by phone and

    explained the purpose of the survey in the hope of

    obtaining their support. Three sub-branches refused to

    participate, resulting in 76 sub-branches that participated.

    To ensure the effectiveness of the survey, with the branch

    supervisor’ help, we distributed and collected the ques-

    tionnaires in person. Date collection was conducted during

    the regular early meeting before business hours. Before

    completing the questionnaires, all respondents were

    informed of the research purpose and assured of confi-

    dentiality. To reduce common method bias, we adminis-

    tered two different sets of questionnaires, one for sub-

    branch supervisors and the other one for their subordi-

    nates. Specifically, sub-branch supervisors reported their

    perceived ethical leadership of high-level managers, their

    own ethical efficacy expectation and ethical outcome

    expectation, whereas subordinates reported their perceived

    ethical leadership of sub-branch supervisors. After com-

    pleting the survey, each respondent forwarded his or her

    questionnaire (enclosed in a sealed envelope) to the

    researchers.

    After excluding responses from seven sub-branches with

    only one or two subordinates, we finally collected a sample

    of 69 sub-branch supervisors (57.5 % of all sub-branch

    supervisors) and 381 subordinates (39.0 % of all employ-

    ees). In this matched sample, the average number of par-

    ticipating subordinates per sub-branch supervisors was

    5.52. Of the 69 supervisors, 47.8 % were women, 81.2 %

    had a college degree, the average age was 39.61 years

    (SD = 5.97), and the average tenure as a sub-branch

    supervisor was 2.33 years (SD = 1.22). Among the sub-

    ordinates, 61.9 % were women, 79.0 % had a college

    degree, the average age was 31.49 years (SD = 6.37), and

    the average dyadic tenure with the supervisor was

    2.32 years (SD = 1.14).

    Measures

    Except for ethical outcome expectation, all other measures

    in the study were originally in English. Applying the

    standard translation and back-translation procedure (Brislin

    1986), we translated the English scales into Chinese ver-

    sions. Unless otherwise indicated, the measures were rated

    by the respondents on a five-point Likert-type scale. The

    anchors for the scale were from strongly disagree (1) to

    strongly agree (5).

    Manager Ethical Leadership and Supervisor Ethical
    Leadership

    To capture leadership in the eyes of beholders, we asked

    followers to rate the ethical leadership behaviors of their

    immediate leaders. Specifically, high-level manager’s eth-

    ical leadership was rated by middle-level supervisors (i.e.,

    sub-branch supervisors); middle-level supervisor’s ethical

    leadership was evaluated by their immediate subordinates.

    This approach has been used in a number of leadership

    studies (e.g., Li and Sun 2015; Liu et al. 2012). We used

    the six-item version (Detert et al. 2007) of the ethical

    leadership scale (ELS; Brown et al. 2005) in this study (see

    Appendix). We chose to use this short version instead of

    the original 10-item version as we found that some of the

    items (e.g., has the best interests of employees in mind, can

    be trusted) in the original 10-item scale are redundant and

    have obvious content overlapping with some other con-

    structs such as consideration and trust, and this has been

    pointed out by a few recent studies (Mayer et al. 2012;

    Yukl et al. 2013). We concurred with these studies and

    believed that we should use the most representative items

    for ethical leadership in our current study. Sample items for

    the six-item scale include ‘‘My leader defines success not

    just by results but also by the way that they are obtained’’

    and ‘‘My leader disciplines employees who violate ethical

    standards.’’ As supervisor ethical leadership scores were

    essentially aggregated based on subordinates’ ratings in the

    multilevel analyses, we calculated the ICC(2) and mean of

    Rwg for supervisors’ ethical leadership, which were .84 and

    .91, respectively, and were above the suggested cutoff

    point (Bliese 2000; James et al. 1993), supporting the

    aggregation for supervisor ethical leadership in the multi-

    level analyses. The Cronbach’s as were .89 for manager
    ethical leadership and .93 for supervisor ethical leadership.

    696 Z. Wang et al.

    123

    Ethical Efficacy Expectation

    Ethical efficacy expectation was measured with a five-item

    moral efficacy sub-scale from the Moral Potency Ques-

    tionnaire (MPQ) developed by Hannah and Avolio (2010).
    2

    Sample items include ‘‘I am confident that I can confront

    others who behave unethically to resolve the issue’’ and ‘‘I

    am confident that I can determine what needs to be done

    when I face moral/ethical decisions.’’ In the present study,

    the Cronbach’s a of the scale was .89.

    Ethical Outcome Expectation

    Since there was no existing scale of ethical outcome

    expectation in the organizational context, we developed the

    items based on the theory. Specifically, ethical behavior–

    reward expectation was measured through three items,

    including ‘‘In our work unit, those who behave ethically

    will be rewarded,’’ ‘‘In our work unit, those who follow

    ethical standards will be given priority in promotion,’’ and

    ‘‘In our work unit, those who follow ethical principles will

    be respected by others,’’ Unethical

    behavior–punishment

    expectation was measured via another three items,

    including ‘‘In our work unit, those who behave unethically

    will be punished,’’ ‘‘In our work unit, it will be difficult for

    those who violate ethical standards to get promoted,’’ and

    ‘‘In our work unit, those who violate ethical principles will

    be despised by others.’’ The anchors for both measures

    ranged from 1 (very unlikely) to 5 (very likely). The

    Cronbach’s as were .90 and .73, respectively. To check the
    construct validity, we performed exploratory factor analy-

    sis using the principal component method with the number

    of factors not specified. The results based on oblimin

    rotation revealed the emergence of two distinct dimensions

    of ethical outcome expectation, with items loaded nicely on

    the two proposed factors, without any cross-loadings. The

    two factors explained 77.22 % of the total variance in

    ethical outcome expectation.

    Control Variables

    We controlled for middle-level supervisor’s age, gender,

    education, and position tenure. Age and position tenure

    were measured by the number of years. Gender was coded

    as 1 = male and 2 = female. Education was coded into

    four categories (1 = high school or lower, 2 = associate’s

    degree, 3 = bachelor’s degree, 4 = master’s degree or

    higher).

    Analysis Strategy

    Given the nested nature of the data, to account for potential

    non-independence effects, we conducted multilevel mod-

    eling to test the hypotheses. Specifically, we tested

    Hypothesis 1 through hierarchical linear modeling using

    HLM 6.08 (Raudenbush and Bryk 2002). Following the

    recommendations of Hofmann and Gavin (1998), we cen-

    tered the predictor according to its grand mean in per-

    forming these analyses to control for multicollinearity.

    To test the cross-level mediation effects (Hypotheses

    2–4), we conducted multilevel path analyses using Mplus

    7.0 (Muthén and Muthén 1998–2012). Specifically, we

    followed the method suggested in Zhang et al. (2009) and

    estimated the indirect effects based on a 2–2–1 path-ana-

    lytical model (2 refers to variables at level 2, while 1 refers

    to variables at level 1). To examine the significance of each

    indirect effect we estimated, we followed Selig and

    Preacher’s (2008) method and conducted a Monte Carlo

    simulation (i.e., a form of parameter bootstrapping) with

    20,000 replications, which provided an estimate of the

    confidence interval (CI) for each effect.

    Results

    Discriminant Validity Tests

    Before hypotheses testing, we conducted a series of con-

    firmatory factor analyses to examine the distinctiveness of

    the four supervisor-reported variables (manager’s ethical

    leadership, ethical efficacy expectation, ethical behavior–

    reward expectation, and unethical behavior–punishment

    expectation). As shown in Table 1, the theorized four-

    factor model provided an acceptable fit to the data

    (v2 = 186.32, df = 113, CFI = .93, TLI = .91,
    SRMR = .08) and showed a significantly better fit than the

    three-factor model (Dv2ð3Þ = 73.46, p \ .01), the two-factor

    model (Dv2ð5Þ = 179.51, p \ .01), and the single-factor

    model (Dv2ð6Þ = 432.75, p \ .01). Given these results, the
    theorized four-factor model was superior in fit to all

    alternative models, and therefore, we can continue to

    examine these variables as distinct constructs.

    To provide further support for the discriminant validity

    of the constructs, we also computed the square root of

    average variance extracted, another widely used index for

    establishing the discriminant validity of constructs (Fornell

    and Larcker 1981). As was shown in Table 2, the square

    root of AVEs for all major constructs in our study was

    above .81, which was higher than any of the inter-construct

    correlations, suggesting that all constructs have good dis-

    criminant validity.

    2
    The MPQ (copyright 2010 by Sean T. Hannah and Bruce J. Avolio)

    was used with the permission of Mind Garden, Inc. All rights

    reserved.

    How Does Ethical Leadership Trickle Down?… 697

    123

    Descriptive Statistics

    The means, standard deviations, and correlations among

    variables are presented in Table 2. As shown in the table,

    high-level managers’ ethical leadership was positively

    related to middle-level supervisors’ ethical efficacy

    (r = .56, p \ .01) and unethical behavior–punishment
    expectation (r = .38, p \ .01). Additionally, middle-level
    supervisors’ ethical efficacy (r = .62, p \ .01) and uneth-
    ical behavior–punishment expectation (r = .51, p \ .01)
    were positively related to their ethical leadership (aggre-

    gated from subordinates’ ratings). In what follows, we

    develop a multilevel model to test the hypotheses.

    Hypotheses Testing

    Hypothesis 1 predicted that high-level managers’ ethical

    leadership would be positively related to the middle-level

    supervisors’ ethical leadership. Before testing this

    hypothesis, we examined whether there was significant

    between-group variance in subordinates’ perceived ethical

    leadership of middle-level supervisors. The results revealed

    a significant between-group variance [r2 = 0.21,
    s00 = 0.19, v2 = 404.69, p \ .01; ICC(1) = .48, indicat-
    ing that 48 % of the variance can be attributed to level 2],

    justifying the appropriateness of the use of hierarchical

    linear modeling to test the hypotheses.

    To test Hypothesis 1, we estimated an intercepts-as-

    outcomes model in HLM 6.08, in which we used high-level

    managers’ ethical leadership (level 2 predictor) to predict

    the intercept of middle-level supervisors’ ethical leadership

    (level 1 outcome). As shown in Table 3, after controlling

    for middle-level supervisors’ age, gender, education, and

    position tenure, high-level managers’ ethical leadership

    related positively to middle-level supervisors’ ethical

    leadership (B = 0.40, p \ .01). Thus, Hypothesis 1 was
    supported.

    Hypotheses 2–4 proposed that middle-level supervisors’

    three ethical expectations (level 2) would mediate the

    relationship between high-level managers’ ethical leader-

    ship (level 2) and middle-level supervisors’ ethical

    leadership (level 1). We tested these three mediation

    effects simultaneously in the same multilevel path-analyt-

    ical model, in which there were three level 2 paths linking

    high-level managers’ ethical leadership and middle-level

    supervisors’ three ethical expectations (paths a1, a2, and a3,

    respectively), and another three level 1 paths linking

    middle-level supervisors’ ethical expectations and ethical

    leadership (paths b1, b2, and b3, respectively). The pro-

    posed mediation effects were examined by estimating the

    three indirect effects linking high-level managers’ ethical

    leadership and middle-level supervisors’ ethical leadership:

    a1b1, a2b2, and a3b3, respectively. As shown in Table 4, the

    indirect effect of high-level managers’ ethical leadership

    on middle-level supervisors’ ethical leadership through

    middle-level supervisor’s ethical efficacy expectation was

    0.13, with a 95 % Monte Carlo CI being [0.01, 0.26],

    which did not include zero, suggesting that the indirect

    effect was significant, supporting Hypothesis 2. The indi-

    rect effect through unethical behavior–punishment expec-

    tation was also significant (estimate = 0.09, 95 % Monte

    Carlo CI [0.01, 0.18]). Thus, Hypothesis 4 was supported.

    However, the indirect effect through ethical behavior–re-

    ward expectation was not significant (estimate = -0.02,

    95 % Monte Carlo CI [-0.07, 0.01]), which did not sup-

    port Hypothesis 3.

    Discussion

    Although past research has recognized the trickle-down

    effect of ethical leadership, the underlying mechanism

    delineating the cascading process still remains largely

    unclear. Building upon social learning theory, which sug-

    gests that a role model influences an observer’s behaviors

    through shaping his or her cognitive expectations (Bandura

    1977; Manz and Sims 1981), we proposed and tested an

    integrative dual-process model in which the trickle-down

    effect of high-level managers’ ethical leadership on mid-

    dle-level supervisors’ ethical leadership was mediated by

    middle-level supervisors’ cognitive expectations about

    their ethical efficacy and the potential outcomes of their

    Table 1 Results of confirmatory factor analyses

    Models Factors v2 df Dv2 SRMR CFI TLI

    Model 0 Theorized four factors 186.32 113 .08 .93 .91

    Model 1 Three factors ethical behavior–reward expectation and unethical behavior–

    punishment expectation were merged as one factor (ethical outcome

    expectation)

    259.78 116 73.46** .14 .88 .86

    Model 2 Two factors ethical efficacy expectation, ethical behavior–reward expectation, and

    unethical behavior–punishment expectation were merged as one factor (ethical

    expectation)

    365.83 118 179.51** .13 .80 .77

    Model 3 One factor: all variables were merged as a single factor 619.07 119 432.75** .16 .71 .66

    ** p \ .01

    698 Z. Wang et al.

    123

    ethical or unethical behaviors. Results from a survey study

    of 69 middle-level supervisors and 381 subordinates from a

    large banking company largely supported the model we

    proposed. We discuss the implications, limitations, and

    future directions of our findings as follows.

    Theoretical Implications

    First, through exploring the mediating roles of ethical

    expectations, we disentangled the intermediate psycho-

    logical processes underlying the trickle-down effect of

    Table 2 Means, standard deviations, and correlations among variables

    M SD HAVE 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8

    (1) Supervisor age 39.61 5.97 –

    (2) Supervisor gender 1.48 0.50 – -.04

    (3) Supervisor education 2.99 0.44 – -.35** -.04

    (4) Supervisor position tenure 2.33 1.22 – .40** -.19 -.02

    (5) Manager’s ethical leadership 3.99 0.67 .84 -.03 .14 -.05 -.14

    (6) Supervisor’s ethical efficacy expectation 3.88 0.62 .82 -.21 .31** -.02 -.23 .56**

    (7) Supervisor’s ethical behavior–reward

    expectation

    4.41 0.59 .89 -.22 .05 -.15 -.01 .19 .32**

    (8) Supervisor’s unethical behavior–punishment

    expectation

    4.20 0.66 .81 -.01 -.05 .13 .12 .38** .41** .41**

    (9) Supervisor’s ethical leadership (aggregated) 4.12 0.49 .92 -.08 .09 .01 -.14 .61** .62** .15 .51**

    HAVE square root of the average variance extracted (AVE)

    ** p \ .01, * p \ .05

    Table 3 Results of cross-level regressions

    Variables Mediators and dependent variables

    Supervisor’s
    ethical
    leadership

    Supervisor’s ethical

    efficacy expectation
    Supervisor’s ethical
    behavior–reward
    expectation

    Supervisor’s unethical

    behavior–punishment
    expectation
    Supervisor’s
    ethical
    leadership

    Control variable

    Supervisor age -0.002 -0.02

    -0.04* -0.002 -0.001

    Supervisor gender -0.01 0.27* 0.03 -0.09 -0.06

    Supervisor education 0.04 -0.07 -0.36* 0.22* -0.04

    Supervisor position tenure -0.02 -0.03 0.08 0.09 -0.02

    Independent variable

    Manager’s ethical

    leadership

    0.40** 0.47** 0.17

    0.41**

    0.21*

    Mediators

    Supervisor’s ethical
    efficacy expectation

    0.27*

    Supervisor’s ethical
    behavior–reward
    expectation

    -0.12

    Supervisor’s unethical
    behavior–punishment
    expectation
    0.21*

    Level 2 residual variance 0.12** 0.23** 0.29** 0.35** 0.09**

    Nlevel 2 = 69, Nlevel 1 = 381

    B unstandardized regression coefficients, level 2 residual variance unexplained variance at level 2. The smaller the level 2 residual variance, the

    greater amount of variance explained by the model

    ** p \ .01, * p \ .05, � p \ .10

    How Does Ethical Leadership Trickle Down?… 699

    123

    ethical leadership. Resonating with several recent studies

    on ethical leadership (Mayer et al. 2009; Ruiz et al.

    2011a, b; Schaubroeck et al. 2012), our study also revealed

    a positive relationship between high-level managers’ ethi-

    cal leadership and middle-level supervisors’ ethical lead-

    ership, providing further support for this trickle-down

    effect of ethical leadership. Going beyond that, the sig-

    nificant mediating effects of ethical expectations as we

    found in the current study clearly delineated the underlying

    mechanism of how ethical leadership cascades downward

    in an organization. Specifically, we found that high-level

    managers’ ethical leadership could facilitate middle-level

    supervisors’ exhibition of ethical leadership behaviors

    through influencing their ethical efficacy expectation and

    unethical behavior–punishment expectation. According to

    social learning theory, efficacy expectation and outcome

    expectation are the two major cognitive processes influ-

    encing human functioning (Bandura 2012; Manz and Sims

    1981). Our research extended the expectation-related per-

    spectives of social learning theory into the ethical leader-

    ship context and thus provided a novel and meaningful

    understanding of the social learning process of ethical

    leadership. As theorized in the current study, ethical effi-

    cacy expectations instill followers with a ‘‘can-do’’ moti-

    vation for their ethical behavior regulations, while ethical

    outcome expectations instill them with a ‘‘reason-to-do’’

    motivation. The findings of our research, to some extent,

    provided direct support for the well-recognized social

    learning account of the trickle-down effect of ethical

    leadership.

    Second, we contributed to the growing, yet still limited,

    body of literature on ethical efficacy. To explain an indi-

    vidual’s ethical behaviors, earlier studies have highlighted

    the importance of moral judgment (Blasi 1980; Kohlberg

    1969). The association between moral judgment and ethical

    behaviors, however, remains weak and inconsistent. This is

    also called as the ‘‘judgment-action gap’’ (Jennings et al.

    2015; Walker 2004). As such, an individual’s judging a

    situation as ethical or unethical and understanding of what

    should be done and what should not be done does not

    necessarily translate into ethical behaviors. In this sense,

    understanding how to motivate ethical behaviors is criti-

    cally important (Treviño et al. 2006). Defined as individ-

    uals’ beliefs about their abilities to execute ethical

    behaviors, ethical efficacy is a relevant construct that could

    help address the ‘‘judgment-behavior gap’’ (Hannah and

    Avolio 2010; Hannah et al. 2011; Mitchell and Palmer

    2010; Sweeney et al. 2015). However, despite its close

    relevance with ethical behaviors, insofar only a few studies

    have investigated the role of ethical efficacy in the ethics

    domain. For instance, Schaubroeck et al. (2012) found that

    ethical leadership could influence followers’ ethical effi-

    cacy through ethical culture. Lee et al.’s (2015) recent

    research found that followers’ ethical efficacy could

    mediate the effect of ethical leadership on followers’ moral

    voice behaviors. By providing support for the intermediary

    role of ethical efficacy in the trickle-down process of high-

    level managers’ ethical leadership, the current research

    added to the ongoing exploration of ethical efficacy in the

    organizational ethics context, advancing the knowledge of

    ethical efficacy’s antecedents and consequences. However,

    it should also be noted that the research on ethical efficacy

    is still in its infancy, and thus more research is needed to

    further the understanding of this construct.

    Third, we contributed to the research on ethical outcome

    expectation by extending it to the area of ethical leadership.

    Despite its important role in the regulation of moral

    behaviors (Ashkanasy et al. 2006; Treviño and Young-

    blood 1990), expectations of ethical outcomes received

    little attention from researchers. Drawing on earlier work

    by Treviño and Youngblood (1990), we took a pioneering

    step to differentiate two important types of ethical outcome

    expectations: the expectation of getting rewards for ethical

    behaviors and the expectation of getting punished for

    unethical conducts. Furthermore, we found evidence sup-

    porting the intermediary role of middle-level supervisor’s

    unethical behavior–punishment expectation in the cascad-

    ing process of high-level managers’ ethical leadership,

    which suggested that ethical leaders could influence their

    followers to become ethical leaders through shaping their

    expectations that behaving unethically would be punished.

    However, the study lent no support to the mediating effect

    of ethical behavior–reward expectation. We argue that

    there might be three possible reasons for this unsupported

    effect. First, prior research suggested that, in the short term,

    using rewards to elicit ethical behaviors may be frustrating.

    As posited by Treviño and Brown (2004, p. 79), ‘‘Can we

    really reward ethical behavior? In the short term, we

    probably cannot. For the most part, ethical behavior is

    simply expected, and people don’t expect or want to be

    Table 4 Results of the
    mediating effects of ethical

    expectations

    Indirect effects via Estimates t test Monte Carlo 95 % CI

    Low end High end

    Path 1 ethical efficacy expectation 0.13 p = .048 0.01 0.26

    Path 2 ethical behavior–reward expectation -0.02 p = .299 -0.07 0.01

    Path 3 unethical behavior–punishment expectation 0.09 p = .027 0.01 0.18

    700 Z. Wang et al.

    123

    rewarded for doing their jobs the right way.’’ Second, it has

    been posited that a transactional leadership approach,

    characterized by managing by exception and contingent

    reinforcement, is more likely to draw followers’ attention

    to oughts, duties, and losses (Kark and van Dijk 2007), thus

    making them more sensitive to behaviors that they should

    not do. Given that ethical leaders usually use a transac-

    tional approach to hold followers accountable (Brown et al.

    2005; Treviño and Brown 2014), it could be reasoned that

    supervisors working under ethical managers might pay

    more attention to losses, such as punishments for behaving

    unethically, rather than to gains, such as rewards for

    behaving ethically. In indirect support of our finding, Shao

    et al. (2011) suggested that ethical leadership is more likely

    to induce employees’ ethical prevention focus, a construct

    that to some extent is similar to unethical behavior–pun-

    ishment expectation. Finally, the unsupported mediating

    role of ethical behavior–reward expectation might also be

    attributed to the measurement of ethical leadership in the

    current research. Although Brown et al. (2005) contended

    that ethical leaders use rewards and punishments to hold

    followers accountable for their conducts, the ELS (Brown

    et al. 2005; Detert et al. 2007) we used only captured the

    ‘‘punishment’’ component (e.g., disciplining employees

    who violate ethical standards), yet neglected the ‘‘reward’’

    component.

    Fourth, as a reply to a recent study by Wo et al. (2015),

    the present study defended the legitimacy of using social

    learning theory to explain trickle-down effects in organi-

    zation studies. Wo et al. explored the mechanisms under-

    lying the cascading process of interactional justice

    perception through three perspectives: social learning,

    social exchange, and displaced aggression. Through two

    studies, they found no support for the social learning per-

    spective, thereby casting doubt on its validity in explaining

    the trickle-down effect. Responding to their call for a re-

    evaluation of the social learning perspective, we used

    ethical efficacy expectation and ethical outcome expecta-

    tion, two core variables rooted in social learning theory, to

    examine the validity of this theory in explaining the cas-

    cading effect of ethical leadership. Based on our findings,

    the current research defended the legitimacy of using social

    learning theory in explaining the trickle-down effect.

    Indeed, different theories may have different power in

    explaining the trickle-down process of an organizational

    phenomenon. According to our observations, when study-

    ing the trickle-down effect of behaviors (e.g., leadership

    behaviors, citizenship behaviors, creativity), researchers

    primarily used social learning theory (e.g., Jaussi and

    Dionne 2003; Li and Sun 2015; Liu et al. 2012; Yaffe and

    Kark 2011); when explaining the trickle-down effect of

    exchange relationships (e.g., leader–member exchange,

    perceived organizational support) or justice perceptions

    (e.g., Aryee et al. 2007; Tepper and Taylor 2003;

    Venkataramani et al. 2010), social exchange theory was

    mostly used; the displaced aggression perspective is mainly

    adopted to account for the cascading effect of negative

    leaderships (e.g., abusive supervision) and injustice per-

    ception (e.g., Aryee et al. 2007; Hoobler and Brass 2006;

    Tepper et al. 2006). Taken together, it could be reasoned

    that social exchange theory and displaced aggression per-

    spective might have stronger power than social learning

    theory in explaining the trickle-down effect of justice

    perceptions, as examined in Wo et al.’s study; yet when it

    comes to the cascading effect of ethical leadership

    behaviors, social learning theory might be a more

    suitable perspective.

    Finally, from the results of our data analyses, we found

    some effects relating to the control variables of our study

    interesting and we believe these small yet interesting

    findings could indicate potential research questions to be

    examined in the future. As was shown in Table 3, super-

    visor gender was positively (B = .27, p \ .05) associated
    with their ethical efficacy expectation, such that females

    tend to have higher ethical efficacy scores than males.

    Given that existing research suggested that women should

    be more likely to conduct ethical behaviors and avoid

    unethical behaviors than men (see Franke et al. 1997; Kish-

    Gephart et al. 2010; Pan and Sparks 2012 for meta-ana-

    lytical reviews) and men are more than two times as likely

    as women to engage in actions regarded as unethical (Betz

    et al. 1989), the finding that women have higher belief in

    their ability to execute ethical behaviors is not surprising.

    Besides, supervisor’s level of education was negatively

    (B = -.36, p \ .05) related to supervisors’ ethical
    behavior–reward expectation yet positively (B = .22,

    p \ .05) associated with supervisors’ unethical behavior–
    punishment expectation. A possible explanation could be

    that those highly educated people, due to their higher levels

    of morality or their higher levels of conscience, may view

    conducting ethical behaviors as something normal in their

    life. Under this circumstance, they may not expect any

    rewards for their good deeds and sometimes, they might

    even dislike the rewards given for good deeds. However, in

    terms of unethical behaviors, highly educated individuals

    might be more likely to have a strong belief in norms or

    principles, which essentially requires a punishment for

    unethical behaviors.

    Practical Implications

    This research also has practical implications for organiza-

    tion management, especially for the ethics management in

    the banking industry where ethical scandals have happened

    so frequently and have caused severe consequences. First,

    consistent with other explorations of trickle-down effects

    How Does Ethical Leadership Trickle Down?… 701

    123

    of leadership, the present study highlighted the importance

    of the role modeling of leadership and indicated that high-

    level leaders should set examples for middle-level super-

    visors in the practice of ethical leadership. Moreover,

    supervisors can act either as transmitters of ethical

    behaviors or as inhibitors of unethical behaviors due to

    their role as linking-pins in the organization. Therefore, the

    role of middle-level supervisors in promoting the trickle-

    down effect of ethical behaviors should deserve greater

    attention in organizational ethics management. Second, our

    findings of the intermediate mechanisms underlying the

    trickle-down effect offered deeper insights into how the

    trickle-down effect occurs, providing practical recom-

    mendations for facilitating the trickle-down effect. For

    instance, high-level managers should serve as ethical role

    models for middle-level supervisors to bolster their per-

    ceived abilities to execute ethical behaviors and to shape

    their ethical outcome expectations, which would in turn

    transform those supervisors into ethical leaders.

    Limitations and Future Directions

    Our research is not without limitations. First, although we

    have theoretically delineated the causal relationships

    among variables, the cross-sectional data used in the cur-

    rent study still limited us in making causal inferences. The

    use of multi-source ratings in the current study could help

    alleviate the common method variance to some extent, yet

    future research could use more advanced design to provide

    more conservative and robust support for the proposed

    relationships among variables. For example, a multi-wave

    longitudinal design with the ratings for ethical leadership

    and the mediators separate in time would help establish

    more robust findings. Second, in this study, we only col-

    lected our sample from the banking industry, the general-

    izability of our findings to other contexts remains to be

    further investigated. Although ethical leadership research

    does not primarily focus on any specific sector or generate

    conclusions that were only applicable to any given sector,

    future research should still consider the generalizability of

    the trickle-down effect to other research settings. Third, in

    theorizing on the proposed mechanisms linking manager’s

    ethical leadership and followers’ ethical efficacy expecta-

    tion, we relied heavily on social learning theory and sug-

    gested that the four sources of efficacy, as suggested

    originally by Bandura (1977), to be the focal determinants

    of ethical efficacy. However, due to the lack of a valid

    scale, we did not measure the four sources of efficacy

    directly in the current study, which is an obvious limitation

    of our study. This said, future research should develop a

    reliable and valid scale to measure the four sources of

    efficacy.

    The fourth limitation concerned with the use of self-

    developed measure of ethical outcome expectations. As

    suggested by Bandura (1977), outcome expectation is very

    specific to the research context. Bearing this in mind, we

    indeed tried to find an existing measure for ethical outcome

    expectations. Although there have been a few studies that

    operationalized ethical outcome expectations (Ashkanasy

    et al. 2006; Treviño and Youngblood 1990), the measure-

    ment approach used in these studies, either designed for an

    experimental setting or based on a general assessment (i.e.,

    not differentiating two types of expectations), did not fit

    well with the context and the purpose of our research.

    Given the lack of an appropriate scale to measure ethical

    outcome expectations, we considered the alternative of

    using a self-developed measure instead. We realized that,

    however, many researchers have developed measures

    according to their research purposes. For instance, Yuan

    and Woodman (2010) developed three items to assess

    employees’ expected positive performance outcomes from

    innovative behaviors; Lian et al. (2011) developed a five-

    item scale to assess employees’ perceptions of the likeli-

    hood that abusive behaviors would be rewarded; Schau-

    broeck et al. (2016) recently used a self-developed three-

    item scale to evaluate employees’ beliefs about the benefits

    of engaging in desired customer service behaviors. In light

    of these studies, we built upon our theorizing of ethical

    outcome expectations and developed a six-item measure

    for the current study. Although the self-developed measure

    has demonstrated good reliability and validity, we still

    encourage future research to further develop and validate a

    rigorous measure for ethical outcome expectations.

    Finally, we examined the trickle-down effect of ethical

    leadership and its ‘‘black box’’ solely from the social

    learning perspective, leaving other potential perspectives

    uncharted. The theories of ethical leadership and the earlier

    work on the trickle-down effect of leadership in combi-

    nation suggested that there may be more than one reason

    explaining why ethical leadership cascades in organiza-

    tions. For instance, according to social exchange theory

    and the observation that ‘‘imitation is the sincerest form of

    flattery’’ (Liden et al. 2014, p. 1436), middle-level super-

    visors are expected to feel a sense of indebtedness to high-

    level ethical managers because of their trustworthy,

    humane, and fair nature (Mayer et al. 2012), and such a

    sense of indebtedness might drive middle-level supervisors

    to reciprocate ethical managers by emulating their ethical

    leadership behaviors. Besides social exchange theory,

    social identity theory may also be an alternative explana-

    tion. This theory holds that followers who identify with

    their leaders are more sensitive to and active in meeting

    leaders’ expectations (Aron 2003; Li and Sun 2015; Pratt

    1998). In this sense, it could be possible that high-level

    managers’ ethical leadership could elicit middle-level

    702 Z. Wang et al.

    123

    supervisors’ personal identification with managers (e.g.,

    Walumbwa et al. 2011), which would in turn influence

    them to display behaviors that are consistent with high-

    level managers’ ethical expectations. This said, future

    research should continue investigating alternative expla-

    nations for the trickle-down effect of ethical leadership,

    which could help provide a more comprehensive under-

    standing of this phenomenon.

    Acknowledgments This study was funded by the National Natural
    Science Foundation of China (Grant Number 71302129).

    Compliance with Ethical Standards

    Conflict of Interest The authors declare that they have no conflict of
    interest.

    Ethical approval All procedures performed in this study were in
    accordance with the ethical standards of the Institutional Research

    Committee and with the 1964 Helsinki Declaration and its later

    amendments or comparable ethical standards.

    Informed consent Informed consent was obtained from all individ-
    ual participants included in this study.

    Appendix

    Items from the six-item ELS

    (1) Disciplines employees who violate ethical standards;

    (2) Conducts his/her personal life in an ethical manner;

    (3) Discusses business ethics or values with employees;

    (4) Sets an example of how to do things the right way in

    terms of ethics;

    (5) Defines success not just by results but also the way

    that they are obtained;

    (6) When making decisions, asks ‘‘what is the right

    thing to do.’’

    Note The above six-item ELS was from Detert et al. (2007)

    and was adapted based on the original 10-item ELS

    developed by Brown et al. (2005).

    References

    Arnaud, A., & Schminke, M. (2012). The ethical climate and context

    of organizations: A comprehensive model. Organization

    Science, 23(6), 1767–1780.

    Aron, A. (2003). Self and close relationships. In M. R. Leary & J.

    P. Tagney (Eds.), Handbook of self and identity (pp. 442–461).

    New York: The Guilford Press.

    Aryee, S., Chen, Z. X., Sun, L. Y., & Debrah, Y. A. (2007).

    Antecedents and outcomes of abusive supervision: Test of a

    trickle-down model. Journal of Applied Psychology, 92(1),

    191–201.

    Ashkanasy, N. M., Windsor, C. A., & Treviño, L. K. (2006). Bad

    apples in bad barrels revisited: Cognitive moral development,

    just world beliefs, rewards, and ethical decision making.

    Business Ethics Quarterly, 16(4), 449–473.

    Bandura, A. (1977). Social learning theory. Englewood Cliffs, NJ:

    Prentice-Hall.

    Bandura, A. (1991). Social cognitive theory of moral thought and

    action. In W. M. Kurtines & J. L. Gewwirtz (Eds.), Handbook of

    moral behavior and development (pp. 45–103). Hillsdale, NJ:

    Lawrence Erlbaum.

    Bandura, A. (1997). Self-efficacy: The exercise of control. New York:

    Freeman.

    Bandura, A. (2012). On the functional properties of perceived self-

    efficacy revisited. Journal of Management, 38(1), 9–44.

    Bedi, A., Alpaslan, C. M., & Green, S. (2015). A meta-analytic

    review of ethical leadership outcomes and moderators. Journal

    of Business Ethics,. doi:10.1007/s10551-015-2625-1.

    Betz, M., O’Connell, L., & Shepard, J. M. (1989). Gender differences

    in proclivity for unethical behavior. Journal of Business Ethics,

    8(5), 321–324.

    Blasi, A. (1980). Bridging moral cognition and moral action: A

    critical review of the literature. Psychological Bulletin, 88(1),

    1–45.

    Bliese, P. D. (2000). Within-group agreement, non-independence, and

    reliability: Implications for data aggregation and analysis. In K.

    J. Klein & S. W. Kozlowski (Eds.), Multilevel theory, research,

    and methods in organizations (pp. 349–381). San Francisco:

    Jossey-Bass.

    Boatright, J. R. (2010). Finance ethics: Critical issues in theory and

    practice. Hoboken, NJ: Wiley.

    Brislin, R. W. (1986). The wording and translation of research

    instruments. In W. J. Lonner & J. W. Berry (Eds.), Field methods

    in cross-cultural research (pp. 136–164). Newbury Park, CA:

    Sage.

    Brown, M. E., & Treviño, L. K. (2006). Ethical leadership: A review

    and future directions. Leadership Quarterly, 17(6), 595–616.

    Brown, M. E., & Treviño, L. K. (2014). Do role models matter? An

    investigation of role modeling as an antecedent of perceived

    ethical leadership. Journal of Business Ethics, 122(4), 587–598.

    Brown, M. E., Treviño, L. K., & Harrison, D. A. (2005). Ethical

    leadership: A social learning perspective for construct develop-

    ment and testing. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision

    Processes, 97(2), 117–134.

    Davis, T. R. V., & Luthans, F. (1980). A social learning approach to

    organizational behavior. Academy of Management Review, 5(2),

    281–290.

    den Hartog, D. N. (2015). Ethical leadership. Annual Review of

    Organizational Psychology and Organizational Behavior, 2,

    409–434.

    Detert, J. R., Treviño, L. K., Burris, E. R., & Andiappan, M. (2007).

    Managerial modes of influence and counterproductively in

    organizations: A longitudinal business-unit-level investigation.

    Journal of Applied Psychology, 92(4), 993–1005.

    Fischbach, S. (2015). Ethical efficacy as a measure of training

    effectiveness: An application of the graphic novel case method

    versus traditional written case study. Journal of Business Ethics,

    128(3), 603–615.

    Fornell, C., & Larcker, D. E. (1981). Evaluating structural equation

    models with unobserved variables and measurement error.

    Journal of Marketing Research, 18(1), 39–50.

    Franke, G. R., Crown, D. F., & Spake, D. F. (1997). Gender

    differences in ethical perceptions of business practices: A social

    role theory perspective. Journal of Applied Psychology, 82(6),

    920–934.

    How Does Ethical Leadership Trickle Down?… 703

    123

    http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10551-015-2625-1

    Hannah, S. T., & Avolio, B. J. (2010). Moral potency: Building the

    capacity for character-based leadership. Consulting Psycholog-

    ical Journal: Practice and Research, 62(4), 291–310.

    Hannah, S. T., Avolio, B. J., & May, D. R. (2011). Moral maturation and

    moral conation: A capacity approach to explaining moral thought

    and action. Academy of Management Review, 36(4), 663–685.

    Hofmann, D. A., & Gavin, M. B. (1998). Centering decisions in

    Hierarchical Linear Models: Theoretical and methodological

    implications for organizational science. Journal of Management,

    24(5), 623–641.

    Hoobler, J., & Brass, D. (2006). Abusive supervision and family

    undermining as displaced aggression. Journal of Applied Psy-

    chology, 91(5), 1125–1133.

    James, L. R., Demaree, R. J., & Wolf, G. (1993). Rwg: An assessment

    of within-group interrater agreement. Journal of Applied

    Psychology, 78(2), 306–309.

    Jaussi, K. S., & Dionne, S. D. (2003). Leading for creativity: The role

    of unconventional leader behavior. Leadership Quarterly,

    14(4–5), 475–498.

    Jennings, P. L., Mitchell, M. S., & Hannah, S. T. (2015). The moral

    self: A review and integration of the literature. Journal of

    Organizational Behavior, 36(S1), S104–S168.

    Kark, R., & Van Dijk, D. (2007). Motivation to lead, motivation to

    follow: The role of the self-regulatory focus in leadership

    processes. Academy of Management Review, 32(2), 500–528.

    Kish-Gephart, J. J., Harrison, D. A., & Treviño, L. K. (2010). Bad

    apples, bad cases, and bad barrels: Meta-analytic evidence about

    sources of unethical decisions at work. Journal of Applied

    Psychology, 95(1), 1–31.

    Kohlberg, L. (1969). Stage and sequence. The cognitive develop-

    mental approach to socialization. In D. Goslin (Ed.), Handbook

    of socialization theory (pp. 347–480). Chicago: RanMcNally.

    Lee, D., Choi, Y., Youn, S., & Chun, J. K. (2015). Ethical leadership

    and employee moral voice: The mediating role of moral efficacy

    and the moderating role of leader–follower value congruence.

    Journal of Business Ethics,. doi:10.1007/s10551-015-2689-y.

    Li, Y., & Sun, J. M. (2015). Traditional Chinese leadership and

    employee voice behavior: A cross-level examination. Leadership

    Quarterly, 26(2), 172–189.

    Lian, H., Ferris, D. L., & Brown, D. J. (2011). Does power distance

    exacerbate or mitigate the effects of abusive supervision? It depends

    on the outcome. Journal of Applied Psychology, 97(1), 107–123.

    Liden, R. C., Wayne, S. J., Liao, C. W., & Meuser, J. D. (2014).

    Servant leadership and serving culture: Influence on individual

    and unit performance. Academy of Management Journal, 57(5),

    1434–1452.

    Liu, D., Liao, H., & Loi, R. (2012). The dark side of leadership: A

    three-level investigation of the cascading effect of abusive

    supervision on employee creativity. Academy of Management

    Journal, 55(5), 1187–1212.

    Manz, C. C., & Sims, H. P. (1981). Vicarious learning: The influence

    of modeling on organizational behavior. Academy of Manage-

    ment Review, 6(1), 105–113.

    May, D. R., Luth, M. T., & Schwoerer, C. E. (2013). The influence of

    business ethics education on moral efficacy, moral meaningful-

    ness, and moral courage: A quasi-experimental study. Journal of

    Business Ethics, 124(1), 67–80.

    Mayer, D. M., Aquino, K., Greenbaum, R. L., & Kuenzi, M. (2012).

    Who displays ethical leadership and why does it matter? An

    examination of antecedents and consequences of ethical leader-

    ship. Academy of Management Journal, 55(1), 151–171.

    Mayer, D. M., Kuenzi, M., Greenbaum, R., Bardes, M., & Salvador,

    R. (2009). How low does ethical leadership flow? Test of a

    trickle-down model. Organizational Behavior and Human

    Decision Processes, 108(1), 1–13.

    Mitchell, M. S., & Palmer, N. F. (2010). The managerial relevance of
    ethical efficacy. In M. Schminke (Ed.), Managerial ethics:

    Managing the psychology of morality (pp. 89–108). New York:

    Routledge.

    Muthén, L. K. & Muthén, B. O. (1998–2012). Mplus user’s guide (7th

    ed). Los Angeles: Muthén and Muthén.

    Ng, T. W., & Feldman, D. C. (2015). Ethical leadership: Meta-

    analytic evidence of criterion-related and incremental validity.

    Journal of Applied Psychology, 100(3), 948–965.

    Pan, Y., & Sparks, J. R. (2012). Predictors, consequence, and

    measurement of ethical judgments: Review and meta-analysis.

    Journal of Business Research, 65(1), 84–91.

    Pratt, M. G. (1998). To be or not to be: Central questions in

    organizational identification. In D. A. Whetton & P. C. Godfrey

    (Eds.), Identity in organization: Building theory through con-

    versations (pp. 171–208). Thousand Oaks,

    CA: Sage.

    Raudenbush, S. W., & Bryk, A. S. (2002). Hierarchical linear

    models: Applications and data analysis methods. Newbury Park,

    CA: Sage.

    Ruiz, P., Ruiz, C., & Martı́nez, R. (2011a). Improving the ‘‘leader-

    follower’’ relationship: Top manager or supervisor? The ethical

    leadership trickle-down effect on follower job response. Journal

    of Business Ethics, 99(4), 587–608.

    Ruiz, P., Ruiz, C., & Martı́nez, R. (2011b). The cascading effect of

    top management’s ethical leadership: Supervisors or other lower-

    hierarchical level individuals? African Journal of Business

    Management, 5(12), 4755–4764.

    Ruiz-Palomino, P., Martı́nez-Ruiz, M. P., & Martı́nez-Cañas, R.

    (2013). Assessing ethical behaviours in the Spanish banking and

    insurance industries: Evidence and challenges. International

    Journal of Human Resource Management, 24(11), 2173–2196.

    Ruiz-Palomino, P., Ruiz-Amaya, C., & Knörr, H. (2011). Employee

    organizational citizenship behaviour: The direct and indirect

    impact of ethical leadership. Canadian Journal of Administrative

    Sciences, 28(3), 244–258.

    Schaubroeck, J. M., Hannah, S. T., Avolio, B. J., Kozlowski, S. W. J.,

    Lord, R. G., Treviño, L. K., et al. (2012). Embedding ethical

    leadership within and across organization levels. Academy of

    Management Journal, 55(5), 1053–1078.

    Schaubroeck, J. M., Lam, S. S. K., & Peng, A. C. (2016). Can peers’

    ethical and transformational leadership improve coworkers’

    service quality? A latent growth analysis. Organizational

    Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 133(1), 45–58.

    Selig, J. P., & Preacher, K. J. (2008). Monte Carlo method for

    assessing mediation: An interactive tool for creating confidence

    intervals for indirect effects [Computer software]. http://

    quantpsy.org/.

    Shao, P., Resick, C. J., & Schaubroeck, J. (2011). Ethical leadership

    and motivation: Examining promotion and prevention regulatory

    foci. In Paper presented at the annual conference of the

    Academy of Management, San Antonio, TX.

    Sims, R. R., & Brinkman, J. (2002). Leaders as moral role models:

    The case of John Gutfreund at Salomon Brothers. Journal of

    Business Ethics, 35(4), 327–339.

    Sumanth, J., & Hannah, S. (2014). Developing leadership capacity:

    An integration and exploration of ethical and authentic leader-

    ship antecedents. In L. Neider & C. Schriesheim (Eds.),

    Advances in authentic and ethical leadership (pp. 25–74).

    Charlotte, NC: Information Age Publishing.

    Sweeney, P. J., Imboden, M. W., & Hannah, S. (2015). Building

    moral strength: Bridging the moral judgment-action gap. New

    Directions for Student Leadership, 146, 17–33.

    Tepper, B. J., Duffy, M. K., Henle, C. A., & Lambert, L. S. (2006).

    Procedural injustice, victim precipitation, and abusive supervi-

    sion. Personnel Psychology, 59(1), 101–123.

    704 Z. Wang et al.

    123

    http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10551-015-2689-y

    http://quantpsy.org/

    http://quantpsy.org/

    Tepper, B. I., & Taylor, E. C. (2003). Relationships among

    supervisors’ and subordinates’ procedural justice perceptions

    and organizational citizenship behaviors. Academy of Manage-

    ment Journal, 46(1), 97–105.

    Treviño, L. K., & Brown, M. (2004). Managing to be ethical:

    Debunking five business ethics myths. Academy of Management

    Executive, 18(2), 69–83.

    Treviño, L. K., & Brown, M. E. (2014). Ethical leadership. In D.

    V. Day (Ed.), The Oxford handbook of leadership and organi-

    zations (pp. 524–538). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Treviño, L. K., Brown, M., & Hartman, L. P. (2003). A qualitative

    investigation of perceived executive ethical leadership: Percep-

    tions from inside and outside the executive suite. Human

    Relations, 56(1), 5–37.

    Treviño, L. K., den Nieuwenboer, N. A., & Kish-Gephart, J. J. (2014).

    (Un)ethical behavior in organization. Annual Review of Psy-

    chology, 65, 635–660.

    Treviño, L. K., Weaver, G. R., & Reynolds, S. J. (2006). Behavioral

    ethics in organizations: A review. Journal of Management,

    32(6), 951–990.

    Treviño, L. K., & Youngblood, S. A. (1990). Bad apples in bad

    barrels: A causal analysis of ethical decision-making behavior.

    Journal of Applied Psychology, 75(4), 378–385.

    Venkataramani, V., Green, S. G., & Schleicher, D. J. (2010). Well-

    connected leaders: The impact of leaders’ social network ties on

    LMX and members’ work attitudes. Journal of Applied Psy-

    chology, 95(6), 1071–1084.

    Walker, L. J. (2004). Gus in the gap: Bridging the judgment-action

    gap in moral functioning. In D. Lapsley & D. N. Narvaez (Eds.),

    Moral development, self and identity (pp. 1–20). Mahwah, NJ:

    Lawrence Erlbaum.

    Walumbwa, F. O., Mayer, D. M., Wang, P., Wang, H., Workman, K.,

    & Christensen, A. L. (2011). Linking ethical leadership to

    employee performance: The roles of leader–member exchange,

    self-efficacy, and organizational identification. Organizational

    Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 115(2), 204–213.

    Walumbwa, F. O., & Schaubroeck, J. (2009). Leader personality traits

    and employee voice behavior: Mediating roles of ethical

    leadership and work group psychological safety. Journal of

    Applied Psychology, 94(5), 1275–1286.

    Weaver, G. R., Treviño, L. K., & Agle, B. (2005). ‘‘Somebody I look

    up to’’: Ethical role models in organzations. Organizational

    Dynamics, 34(4), 313–330.

    Weiss, H. M. (1977). Subordinate imitation of supervisor behavior:

    The role of modeling in organizational socialization. Organiza-

    tional Behavior and Human Performance, 19(1), 89–105.

    Wo, D. X. H., Ambrose, M. L., & Schminke, M. (2015). What drives

    trickle-down effects? A test of multiple mediation processes.

    Academy of Management Journal, 58(6), 1848–1868.

    Yaffe, T., & Kark, R. (2011). Leading by example: The case of leader

    OCB. Journal of Applied Psychology, 96(4), 806–826.

    Yuan, F., & Woodman, R. W. (2010). Innovative behavior in the

    workplace: The role of performance and image outcome

    expectations. Academy of Management Journal, 53(2), 323–342.

    Yukl, G., Mahsud, R., Hassan, S., & Prussia, G. E. (2013). An

    improved measure of ethical leadership. Journal of Leadership

    and Organizational Studies, 20(1), 38–48.

    Zhang, Z., Zyphur, M. J., & Preacher, K. J. (2009). Testing multilevel

    mediation using hierarchical linear models: Problems and

    solutions. Organizational Research Methods, 12(4), 695–719.

    How Does Ethical Leadership Trickle Down?… 705

    123

    Journal of Business Ethics is a copyright of Springer, 2018. All Rights Reserved.

    • How Does Ethical Leadership Trickle Down? Test of an Integrative Dual-Process Model
    • Abstract
      Introduction
      Theory and Hypotheses
      Manager Ethical Leadership and Supervisor Ethical leadership
      The Mediating Effect of Ethical Efficacy Expectation
      The Mediating Effect of Ethical Outcome Expectation
      Method
      Sample and Procedure
      Measures
      Manager Ethical Leadership and Supervisor Ethical Leadership
      Ethical Efficacy Expectation
      Ethical Outcome Expectation
      Control Variables
      Analysis Strategy
      Results
      Discriminant Validity Tests
      Descriptive Statistics
      Hypotheses Testing
      Discussion
      Theoretical Implications
      Practical Implications
      Limitations and Future Directions
      Acknowledgments
      Appendix
      References

    Feng, J., Zhou, W., Li, S., & Li, M. (2020). Obstacles open the door — negative shocks can motivate individuals to focus on opportunities. Frontiers of Business Research in China, 14(1), 1-17. doi:http://dx.doi.org.libraryresources.columbiasouthern.edu/10.1186/s11782-019-0067-9

    Sifa, H. B., & Tshiunza, C. L. (2020). THEORETICAL ANALYSIS OF MANAGING CORPORATE SOCIAL RESPONSIBILITY IN DEVELOPING COUNTRIES. International Journal of Information, Business and Management, 12(2), 185-208. Retrieved from

    https://search-proquest-com.libraryresources.columbiasouthern.edu/docview/2348381966?accountid=33337

    Holm, H., Nee, V., & Opper, S. (2020). Strategic decisions: Behavioral differences between CEOs and others. Experimental Economics, 23(1), 154-180. doi:http://dx.doi.org.libraryresources.columbiasouthern.edu/10.1007/s10683-019-09604-3

    Wang, Z., Xu, H., & Liu, Y. (2018). How Does Ethical Leadership Trickle Down? Test of an Integrative Dual-Process Model. Journal of Business Ethics, 153(3), 691–705. https://doi-org.libraryresources.columbiasouthern.edu/10.1007/s10551-016-3361-x

    What Will You Get?

    We provide professional writing services to help you score straight A’s by submitting custom written assignments that mirror your guidelines.

    Premium Quality

    Get result-oriented writing and never worry about grades anymore. We follow the highest quality standards to make sure that you get perfect assignments.

    Experienced Writers

    Our writers have experience in dealing with papers of every educational level. You can surely rely on the expertise of our qualified professionals.

    On-Time Delivery

    Your deadline is our threshold for success and we take it very seriously. We make sure you receive your papers before your predefined time.

    24/7 Customer Support

    Someone from our customer support team is always here to respond to your questions. So, hit us up if you have got any ambiguity or concern.

    Complete Confidentiality

    Sit back and relax while we help you out with writing your papers. We have an ultimate policy for keeping your personal and order-related details a secret.

    Authentic Sources

    We assure you that your document will be thoroughly checked for plagiarism and grammatical errors as we use highly authentic and licit sources.

    Moneyback Guarantee

    Still reluctant about placing an order? Our 100% Moneyback Guarantee backs you up on rare occasions where you aren’t satisfied with the writing.

    Order Tracking

    You don’t have to wait for an update for hours; you can track the progress of your order any time you want. We share the status after each step.

    image

    Areas of Expertise

    Although you can leverage our expertise for any writing task, we have a knack for creating flawless papers for the following document types.

    Areas of Expertise

    Although you can leverage our expertise for any writing task, we have a knack for creating flawless papers for the following document types.

    image

    Trusted Partner of 9650+ Students for Writing

    From brainstorming your paper's outline to perfecting its grammar, we perform every step carefully to make your paper worthy of A grade.

    Preferred Writer

    Hire your preferred writer anytime. Simply specify if you want your preferred expert to write your paper and we’ll make that happen.

    Grammar Check Report

    Get an elaborate and authentic grammar check report with your work to have the grammar goodness sealed in your document.

    One Page Summary

    You can purchase this feature if you want our writers to sum up your paper in the form of a concise and well-articulated summary.

    Plagiarism Report

    You don’t have to worry about plagiarism anymore. Get a plagiarism report to certify the uniqueness of your work.

    Free Features $66FREE

    • Most Qualified Writer $10FREE
    • Plagiarism Scan Report $10FREE
    • Unlimited Revisions $08FREE
    • Paper Formatting $05FREE
    • Cover Page $05FREE
    • Referencing & Bibliography $10FREE
    • Dedicated User Area $08FREE
    • 24/7 Order Tracking $05FREE
    • Periodic Email Alerts $05FREE
    image

    Our Services

    Join us for the best experience while seeking writing assistance in your college life. A good grade is all you need to boost up your academic excellence and we are all about it.

    • On-time Delivery
    • 24/7 Order Tracking
    • Access to Authentic Sources
    Academic Writing

    We create perfect papers according to the guidelines.

    Professional Editing

    We seamlessly edit out errors from your papers.

    Thorough Proofreading

    We thoroughly read your final draft to identify errors.

    image

    Delegate Your Challenging Writing Tasks to Experienced Professionals

    Work with ultimate peace of mind because we ensure that your academic work is our responsibility and your grades are a top concern for us!

    Check Out Our Sample Work

    Dedication. Quality. Commitment. Punctuality

    Categories
    All samples
    Essay (any type)
    Essay (any type)
    The Value of a Nursing Degree
    Undergrad. (yrs 3-4)
    Nursing
    2
    View this sample

    It May Not Be Much, but It’s Honest Work!

    Here is what we have achieved so far. These numbers are evidence that we go the extra mile to make your college journey successful.

    0+

    Happy Clients

    0+

    Words Written This Week

    0+

    Ongoing Orders

    0%

    Customer Satisfaction Rate
    image

    Process as Fine as Brewed Coffee

    We have the most intuitive and minimalistic process so that you can easily place an order. Just follow a few steps to unlock success.

    See How We Helped 9000+ Students Achieve Success

    image

    We Analyze Your Problem and Offer Customized Writing

    We understand your guidelines first before delivering any writing service. You can discuss your writing needs and we will have them evaluated by our dedicated team.

    • Clear elicitation of your requirements.
    • Customized writing as per your needs.

    We Mirror Your Guidelines to Deliver Quality Services

    We write your papers in a standardized way. We complete your work in such a way that it turns out to be a perfect description of your guidelines.

    • Proactive analysis of your writing.
    • Active communication to understand requirements.
    image
    image

    We Handle Your Writing Tasks to Ensure Excellent Grades

    We promise you excellent grades and academic excellence that you always longed for. Our writers stay in touch with you via email.

    • Thorough research and analysis for every order.
    • Deliverance of reliable writing service to improve your grades.
    Place an Order Start Chat Now
    image

    Order your essay today and save 30% with the discount code Happy