1. Read the first 13 pages of the attached paper which discusses the effect of government intervention on recessions.
2. Locate two JOURNAL articles which discuss this topic further. You need to focus on the Abstract, Introduction, Results, and Conclusion. For our purposes, you are not expected to fully understand the Data and Methodology.
3. Summarize these journal articles. Please use your own words. No copy-and-paste. Cite your sources.
Need 500 words
Let me know if you have any question
MunichPersonal RePEc Archive
Should a Government Fiscally Intervene
in a Recession and, If So, How?
Harashima, Taiji
Kanazawa Seiryo University
2 April 2017
Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/78053/
MPRA Paper No. 78053, posted 31 Mar 2017 09:03 UTC
Should a Government Fiscally Intervene in a Recession and, If So, How?
Taiji HARASHIMA*
April, 2017
Abstra
ct
The validity of discretionary fiscal policy in a recession will differ according to the cause
and
mechanism of recession. In this paper, discretionary fiscal policy in a recession caused by a
fundamental shock that changes the steady state downwards is examined. In such a recession,
households need to discontinuously increase consumption to a point on the saddle path to
maintain Pareto efficiency. However, they will not “jump” consumption in this manner and
instead will choose a “Nash equilibrium of a Pareto inefficient path” because they dislike
unsmooth and discontinuous consumption and behave strategically. The paper concludes that
increasing government consumption until demand meets the present level of production and
maintaining this fiscal policy for a long period is the best option. Consequent government debts
can be sustainable even if they become extremely large.
JEL Classification code: E20, E32, E62, H20, H30, H63
Keywords: Discretionary Fiscal policy; Recession; Government consumption; Government
debts; Pareto inefficiency; Time preference
*Correspondence: Taiji HARASHIMA, Kanazawa Seiryo University, 10-1 Goshomachi-Ushi,
Kanazawa-shi, Ishikawa, 920-8620, Japan.
Email: harashim@seiryo-u.ac.jp or t-harashima@mve.biglobe.ne.jp.
mailto:harashim@seiryo-u.ac.j
p
mailto:t-harashima@mve.biglobe.ne.jp
1
1 INTRODUCTION
Discretionary fiscal policy has been studied from many perspectives since the era of Keynes
(e.g., Keynes, 1936; Kopcke et al., 2006; Chari et al., 2009; Farmer, 2009; Alesina, 2012;
Benhabib et al., 2014). An important issue is whether a government should intervene fiscally in
a recession, and if so, how. The answer will differ according to the cause and mechanism of
recession. Particularly, it will be different depending on whether “disequilibrium” is generated
.
The concept of disequilibrium is, however, controversial and therefore arguments continue even
now about the use of discretionary fiscal policy in a recession. In this paper, the concept of
disequilibrium is not used, but instead the concept of a “Nash equilibrium of a Pareto inefficient
path” is used.
Recessions are generated by various shocks (e.g., Rebelo, 2005; Blanchard, 2009;
Ireland, 2011; Schmitt-Grohé and Uribe, 2012; McGrattan and Prescott, 2014; Hall, 2016).
Some fundamental shocks will change the steady state, and if the steady state is changed
downwards (i.e., to lower levels of production and consumption), households must change the
consumption path to one that diminishes gradually to the posterior steady state. Therefore,
growth rates become negative; that is, a recession begins. However, the explanation of the
mechanism of this type of recession is not perfect because an important question still needs to
be answered. If households discontinuously increase (“jump up”) their consumption from the
prior steady state to a point on the posterior saddle path and then gradually move to the posterior
steady state, Pareto efficiency is held and thereby unemployment rates do not rise. Therefore,
even in a serious and large-scale recession, unemployment does not increase. This is a very
unnatural outcome of a serious recession.
Harashima (2004, 2009, 2013a) showed a mechanism by which households do not
jump up their consumption even if the steady state is changed downward because they are
intrinsically risk averse and non-cooperative and want to smooth consumption. The
consumption jump does not give them the highest expected utility; that is, unsmooth and
discontinuous consumption is not optimal for households. Hence, instead of choosing the
posterior saddle path, they will choose a “Nash equilibrium of a Pareto inefficient path” as the
optimal consumption path. Because of its Pareto inefficiency, unemployment rates will increase
sharply and stay high during a recession. This paper examines whether discretionary fiscal
policy is necessary, and if it is necessary, how it should be implemented when an economy is in
a recession and proceeding on such a Pareto inefficient path.
Fundamental shocks that change the steady state basically mean shocks on deep
parameters. A representative fundamental shock, an upward shock on the rate of time preference
(RTP), is examined in this paper. Faced with this shock, a government has three options: (1) do
not intervene, (2) increase government consumption, and (3) cut taxes. The consequences of
these options are examined and the outcomes are evaluated to determine which is the best
option. I conclude that increasing government consumption until the demand meets the present
level of production and maintaining this fiscal policy during the recession is the best option.
Nevertheless, this option will be accompanied by large and accumulating government debts, but
these debts can be sustained if the government properly increases taxes in the future. This option
means that huge government debts will play an essential role as a buffer against negative effects
of the fundamental shock.
2 A MECHANISM OF RECESSION
2.1 An upward RTP shock
There are various possible sources of recession, but in this paper, a recession caused by a
fundamental shock, particularly by an upward shift of RTP, is examined because an upward
shift of RTP seems to be most likely the cause of the Great Recession (Harashima, 2016). A
2
technology shock was probably not the cause of the Great Recession because technology does
not suddenly and greatly regress. Frictions on price adjustments are also unlikely to be the cause
because the micro-foundation of friction does not seem to be sufficiently persuasive (e.g.,
Mankiw, 2001), particularly the micro-foundation of its persistence. On the other hand,
Harashima (2016) showed that an upward RTP shock could explain the occurrence of the Great
Recession and showed evidence that the estimated RTP of the United States increased in about
2008.
RTP plays an essential role in economic activities, and its importance has been
emphasized since the era of Irving Fisher (Fisher, 1930). One of the most important equations in
economics is the steady state condition
rθ
where θ is RTP and r is the real rate of interest. This condition is a foundation of both static and
dynamic economic studies. The mechanisms of both θ and r are equally important. Particularly,
RTP is an essential element in expectations of economic activities because RTP is the discount
factor for future utility. In addition, RTP has been regarded as changeable even over short
periods (e.g., Uzawa, 1968; Epstein and Hynes, 1983; Lucas and Stokey, 1984; Parkin, 1988;
Obstfeld, 1990; Becker and Mulligan, 1997). Furthermore, households behave based on the
expected RTP of the representative household (RTP RH) (Harashima, 2014, 2016). That is,
changes in RTP and the expected RTP RH can be an important source of economic fluctuations.
2.2 The model
The model in this paper is based on the models in Harashima (2004, 2009, 2013a) and assumes
non-cooperative, identical, and infinitely long living households, and that the number of
households is sufficiently large. Each of the households equally
maximizes the expected utility
dtcuθtE
t
0
0
exp
subject to
t
t
t cA,kf
dt
d
k
,
where yt, ct, and kt are production, consumption, and capital per capita in period t, respectively;
A is technology and constant; u is the utility function;
tt
kAfy , is the production
function; and E
0
is the expectations operator conditioned on the agents’ period 0 information set.
yt, ct, and kt are monotonically continuous and differentiable in t, and u and f are monotonically
continuous functions of ct and kt, respectively. All households initially have an identical amount
of financial assets equal to kt, and all households gain the identical amount of income
tt
kAfy , in each period. It is assumed
that
0
t
t
d
c
cdu
and
0
2
2
t
t
dc
cud
; thus, households
are risk averse. In addition,
0
,
t
t
k
kAf
and
0
2
2
t
t
k
kf
. Both technology (A) and labor
supply are assumed to be constant; that is, there is no technological progress or population
increase. It is also assumed that there is no depreciation of capital.
2.3 A Nash equilibrium of a Pareto inefficient path
3
t
k
The prior steady state
before the shock on θ: W
The posterior steady
state after the shock
θ
Posterior line of
0
dt
dc
t
after
the shock
on θ
Line of 0
dt
dk
t
Z
Pareto inefficient transition
path
Prior line of 0
dt
dc
t
before
the shock on θ
Pareto efficient
saddle path after
the shock on θ
Pareto efficient saddle
path before the shock
on θ
The effects of an upward shift in RTP are shown in Figure 1. Suppose first that the economy is
at steady state before the shock. After the upward RTP shock, the vertical line 0
dt
dc
t moves
to the left (from the solid vertical line to the dashed vertical line in Figure 1). To keep Pareto
efficiency, consumption needs to jump immediately from the steady state before the shock (the
prior steady state) to point Z. After the jump, consumption proceeds on the Pareto efficient
saddle path (the posterior saddle path) from point Z to the lower steady state after the shock (the
posterior steady state). As a result, negative economic growth rates continue for a long period,
but unemployment rates will not increase and resources will not be destroyed or left idle. Note
that an increase in household consumption means consuming the part capital indicated by the
gap between the posterior saddle path (the thin dashed curve) and production (the bold solid
curve) for each kt, which initially is the gap between point Z and W.
1
Figure 1: An upward RTP shock. All terms are defined in the text.
t
c
1 If depreciation of capital is assumed to exist, the “consumption” of excess capital will be achieved by a reduction of
investments that correspond to depreciated capital and an increase in consumer goods and services.
0
4
However, this discontinuous jump to Z will be uncomfortable for risk-averse
households that wish to smooth consumption. Households may instead chose a shortcut and, for
example, proceed on a path on which consumption is reduced continuously from the prior
steady state to the posterior steady state (the bold dashed line), although this shortcut is not
Pareto efficient. The mechanism for why they are very unlikely to jump consumption is
explained in Harashima (2004, 2009, 2013a) and also in the Appendix. Because households are
risk averse and want to smooth consumption, and are also intrinsically non-cooperative, they
behave strategically in game theoretic situations. Because of these features, when households
strategically consider whether or not the jump is better for them (i.e., they are in a game
theoretic situation), they will generally conclude that they obtain a higher expected utility if they
do not jump. Hence, households will not actually choose this path and instead will choose a
different transition path to the steady state (e.g., the bold dashed curve). Because this transition
path is not on the posterior saddle path, it is not Pareto efficient (I call this transition path a
“Nash equilibrium of a Pareto inefficient path” or more simply a “Pareto inefficient transition
path”). Therefore, the excess resources indicated by the gap between the posterior saddle path
(the thin dashed curve) and the Pareto inefficient transition path (the bold dashed curve) for
each kt (initially, the gap between points Z and X) will be destroyed or left idle. Unemployment
rates will increase sharply and stay high for a long period.
3 SHOULD THE GOVERNMENT FISCALLY
INTERVENE?
3.1 The government’s options
3.1.1 The three options
When households choose a Nash equilibrium of a Pareto inefficient path, the government
basically has three options: (1) do not intervene, (2) increase government consumption, and
(3) cut taxes.
If Option (1) is chosen, the gap between the posterior saddle path and the Pareto
inefficient transition path (initially the gap between points Z and W) is not filled by any demand.
Therefore, unemployment rates increase sharply and huge amounts of resources are destroyed or
left idle. High unemployment rates and destruction of resources will continue until the economy
reaches the posterior
steady state.
If Option (2) is chosen, government consumption is increased to fill the demand gap
between the posterior saddle path and the Pareto inefficient transition path, where government
consumption is indicated on a per capita basis similar to the other variables. Suppose for
simplicity that government consumption is zero before the shock. With increases in government
consumption, the path of the sum of government and household consumption (hereafter
“combined consumption”) can be equal to the posterior saddle path.
Conceptually, government consumption is the collective consumption of households
through government expenditures, for example, spending on various kinds of administrative
services that households receive. Therefore, increases in government consumption can be
substituted for decreases in household consumption. Nevertheless, government consumption
will not directly generate utility in households. In this sense, increases in government
consumption may be interpreted as forced increases in household consumption. Even if
households do not want these increases in government consumption, however, the increases will
work to increase aggregate demand. Option (2) therefore indicates a measure to compulsorily
fill the gap between aggregate demand and supply, even against households’ will, when the
economy proceeds on a Pareto inefficient transition path. Notice that the excess resources
cannot be used for investments because the economy would otherwise deviate from a path to the
steady state.
5
If Option (3) is chosen, households’ disposable incomes will increase, but if the
Ricardian equivalence holds, they will still proceed on a Pareto inefficient transition path.
Because household consumption does not change, high unemployment rates and destruction of a
huge amount of resources continue as in Option (1). Because there is a huge amount of excess
capital, no additional investment will be made. Nevertheless, if the Ricardian equivalence does
not hold, tax cuts may increase household consumption at least temporarily. Therefore, the
validity of Option (3) depends on the validity of the Ricardian equivalence. If households are
sufficiently rational, the Ricardian equivalence will basically hold at least in the long run.
Therefore, even if tax cuts are effective, they will be effective only in the short run, and these
short run effects will be reversed because the Ricardian equivalence will hold in the long run.
3.1.2 Financing
In Option (3), tax cuts are financed by borrowing from households. In Option (2), an increase in
the government consumption is financed by borrowing from or tax increases on households.
Nevertheless, financing by borrowing will be preferred in Option (2) because the Ricardian
equivalence may not necessarily hold in the short run. If the Ricardian equivalence does not
hold, increases in taxes may increase unemployment rates and thereby the main aim of
Option (2) cannot be fully achieved. Therefore, it is highly likely that an increase in government
consumption will be financed by government borrowing, and therefore borrowing is assumed in
this paper. However, financing by borrowing requires tax increases in the future to pay off the
debt with interest. Options (2) and (3) assume that necessary future tax increases are fully
implemented by the government.
In addition, it is assumed that a government borrows money only from its own people,
that is, not from foreigners because foreign borrowing means that foreigners also intervene in
addition to the government, and such intervention is beyond the scope of this paper.
3.2 Comparison among options
(1) Economic growth rate
Because production and consumption at the posterior steady state are lower than those at the
prior steady state, the rate of economic growth is equally negative during the transition in the
three options except for a subordinate option of Option (2), in which, as will be shown in
Section 4, it is zero. Nevertheless, there actually still will be steady technological progress
(remember that no technological progress is assumed in the model), and thereby the actual rates
of growth will not necessarily be negative or zero and may even be low but positive.
(2) Household utility
Households choose a Nash equilibrium of a Pareto inefficient path equally in the three options.
Therefore, the utilities of households are basically same in the three options.
(3) Unemployment
In Options (1) and (3), unemployment rates will rise sharply and stay high for a long period. In
contrast, in Option (2), high unemployment rates can be avoided because the gap of demand is
filled by increases in government consumption and thereby no resources are destroyed or left
idle.
(4) Government debt
In Option (1), government debt does not increase because the government does not borrow
additional money, but in Options (2) and (3), government debt will increase because of
continuous financing by borrowing. However, if taxes are raised properly to pay off the debt in
the future, government debt will stabilize in some future
period.
3.3 Government debt
6
3.3.1 Is the government debt sustainable?
The usual arguments on sustainable government debts (e.g., Hamilton and Flavin, 1986; Bohn,
1995) are not applicable to the government debts in Options (2) and (3) because households
proceed on an “unusual” Pareto inefficient transition path, so an alternative approach is
necessary. Let dt be per capita “extra” government debts in period t that are accumulated in
Option (2) or (3). Because all dt are owned by households as assumed above, dt also indicates
the financial assets of households, and the other household assets (other than dt) are ignored for
simplicity. In the future, dt is redeemed with interest, but the redemption takes a long time.
Because the Ricardian equivalence will hold in the long run, it is assumed that household
consumption is not influenced by dt. Let zt be per capita taxes to redeem a part of dt in period t
and also let gt be additional government borrowing in Option (2) or (3) in period t. In Option
(2),
ttt gcy , (1)
and in Option (3),
ttt gcy (2)
for any t because no new investment is made in Options (2) and (3) and the household assets
other than the government bonds are ignored; yt and ct are per capita income and consumption
of households in period t. If the condition
t
ttt
zgdr (3)
is satisfied indefinitely in a certain future period, government debt never explodes; that is, it is
sustainable where 10 tt rr is the real interest rate. By equality (1) and inequality (3), the
condition for sustainability in Option (2) is
tttttt
zdrcy . (4)
By inequalities (2) and (3), if inequality (4) is satisfied indefinitely in a certain future period,
government debt is also sustainable in Option (3).
Because the household assets other than dt are ignored, the sum of a household’s
income and assets is
ttt cyd
.
If the sum of a household’s income and assets exceeds zt, that is, if
tttt
cydz , (5)
then zt can be imposed in the sense that households have enough resources to fully pay taxes.
Hence, by inequalities (4) and (5), if
ttt ddr (6)
7
is satisfied, taxes that satisfy the condition for sustainable debts can be imposed. Here, because
10
t
r , then inequality (6) always holds. Therefore, for any dt, there always exists zt that
satisfies inequality (3) indefinitely in a certain future period. That is, the government debt can
be sustainable for any dt, and even if dt becomes extremely large, the debt can be sustainable.
Consider an extreme example. If a government collects taxes that are equivalent to dt from a
household’s financial assets in a period, the government’s debts are eliminated completely all at
once. That is, any dt can be sustainable.
Such an extreme tax will not actually be imposed, but if dt exceeds a certain amount
such that
ttt zrdy ,
(i.e., if taxes exceed income), then they need to be collected from a part of a household’s
holdings of dt. If households well know the possibility of a tax on dt in the future, they will not
regard their accumulated financial assets corresponding to dt as their “real” assets in the sense
they can be freely used for consumption even though dt may be extremely large. In addition,
because any dt can be sustainable, the tax increase can be started even after all the excess capital
is eliminated. Hence, a huge amount of government debt can remain even if there is no excess
capital.
Finally, it is important to note that the increased tax revenues should not be used to
finance increases in government consumption for purposes other than dealing with the excess
capital. The increased taxes should be used only to pay down dt (with interest) because the
economy otherwise deviates from the steady state.
3.3.2 How large can government debt be?
Any dt can be sustainable but only if a government properly raises taxes and ttt zdr is
satisfied indefinitely in a certain future period. The question arises, however, when is “a certain
future period”? The time at which taxes are raised is indeterminate in the discussion in the
previous section. The tax increase can be postponed almost indefinitely if taxes will certainly be
raised eventually. This indeterminacy may generate a political struggle because people
intrinsically dislike tax increases, and opposition parties will utilize people’s anti-tax sentiment
as ammunition to attack the government. Opposition parties will appeal to people that a tax
increase is not necessary at present and that it will only generate a recession because the
Ricardian equivalence will not hold in the short run. The government may not sufficiently refute
this argument and persuade people that the current level of government debt is unsustainable,
because any dt can be sustainable. The incentive for the government to raise taxes to reduce dt
will therefore be weak.
Is there a problem, however, if dt becomes extremely large? As shown in Section 3.2.1,
other things being equal, any dt can be sustainable, but if something changes and affects the
sustainability as dt becomes larger, a large dt will not actually be sustainable. One possible
factor that may change as dt becomes larger is uncertainty. If the tax increase has been
postponed for a long period, questions about the ability of the government to govern the nation
and run the economy will arise. Faced with an extremely large dt, people may begin to suspect
that their government cannot do what it should do. Hence, uncertainty about the ability of the
government will increase, and increased uncertainty about the government’s ability means that
the government’s performance in the future is no longer a certainty.
It has been argued that good institutions, including governments, enhance economic
growth (e.g., Knack and Keefer, 1995; Mauro, 1995; Hall and Jones, 1999; Acemoglu et al.,
2001, 2002; Easterly and Levine, 2003; Dollar and Kraay, 2003; Rodrik et al., 2004). Acemoglu
et al. (2005) conclude that differences in economic institutions are empirically and theoretically
8
the fundamental cause of differences in economic development.2 It is therefore highly likely
that a government’s ability is an important determinant of total factor productivity, that is, levels
of production and consumption. Therefore, if uncertainty about the ability of a government
increases, household’s expected variances of production and consumption will also increase.
Larger variances of production and consumption mean more uncertainty about the entire future
economy. That is, as dt increases, household uncertainty about the entire future economy
increases.
An important consequence of increases in uncertainty about the entire future economy
is an increase in household RTP. The concept of a temporally varying RTP has a long history
(e.g., Böhm-Bawerk, 1889; Fisher, 1930; Uzawa, 1968; Lawrance, 1991; Becker and Mulligan,
1997). In addition, uncertainty has been regarded as a key factor that changes RTP. Fisher
(1930) argued that uncertainty, or risk, must naturally influence RTP, and higher uncertainty
tends to raise RTP. Harashima (2004, 2009) showed a mechanism of how an increase in
uncertainty leads to an increase in RTP by constructing an endogenous RTP model
where
uncertainty is defined by the stochastic dominance of the distribution of steady-state
consumption. Increases in uncertainty will increase RTP RH. An increase in RTP RH indicates
an increase in the real interest rate at steady state and consequently a decrease in production and
consumption at the steady state because RTP RH is equal to the real interest rate at steady state
in Ramsey-type growth models. That is, it is likely that as dt increases, long-run production and
consumption will decrease.
Considering the effect of dt on RTP RH and on long run production and consumption,
therefore, a government will not have to postpone the a tax increase for a long period and to
accumulate an extremely large dt. Nevertheless, the scale of the effect of dt on RTP RH is
unclear. It may be small and take a long period before households clearly recognize the negative
effect of a large dt on RTP RH. Hence, the exact upper limit of dt is unclear, so there will still be
much room for a government with regard to the timing and scale of tax increases.
When the long run negative effect of a huge dt on the expected household utility
becomes larger than the short run effect of deviation from the Ricardian equivalence on the
expected household utility, taxes should be raised. However, it may be difficult to judge which
is currently larger. On the other hand, if the negative effect of the short run deviation from the
Ricardian equivalence can be controlled such that it remains very small, it will be better to raise
taxes even for small dt. In this sense, it may be a good idea to raise the tax rate by a very small
percentage point amount in every period, for example, by 0.5% per year. Because this tax
increase is very small in each period, the negative effect of any short run deviation from the
Ricardian equivalence can be controlled such that it is also very small in each period.
There is another relatively minor problem associated with extremely large dt. As dt
increases, the amount of necessary future tax increases (as shown in Section 3.3.1) will
eventually exceed income (yt). Therefore, taxes need to be imposed not only on income but also
on household’s financial assets corresponding to dt. However, large taxes on financial assets
may be less easy to implement than other types of taxes both practically and politically.
Nevertheless, an inheritance tax may be relatively easy to implement, and therefore it will be
important as taxes on household’s financial assets.
3.3.3 Price stability
It has been argued that a large amount of government debt will result in high inflation (Sargent
and Wallace, 1981). Fiscal theory of price level particularly emphasizes this mechanism (Leeper,
1991; Sims, 1994, 1998; Cochrane, 2005; Woodford, 2001). However, Harashima (2006)
showed that the relation between the government debts and inflation is not simple and presented
a model that explains the law of motion for inflation considering government debt. The model
in Harashima (2006) indicates that a large amount of government debts does not result in high
2 Some economists argue the reverse causation from growth to institutional improvement (e.g., Barro, 1999) or that
institutional improvement has a smaller impact on growth than human capital (Glaeser et al., 2004).
9
inflation as long as the central bank is sufficiently independent. Inflation will not be affected by
temporary increases in government expenditure and consequent future taxes. As a result, if the
central bank is sufficiently independent, the government can implement Option (2) without
worrying about an outbreak of high inflation.
3.4 Evaluation
As shown in Section 3.2, the rate of economic growth in the three options is equally negative
until arriving at the steady state, and household utilities are basically same in the three options.
On the other hand, unemployment rates will rise sharply and stay high for a long period in
Options (1) and (3), but not in Option (2). As argued in Section 3.3, the extra government debts
are sustainable if the government properly increases taxes in the future. If the future tax increase
is properly implemented, therefore, Option (2) is favorable to Options (1) and (3) because
unemployment rates do not rise.
4 HOW SHOULD THE GOVERNMENT
INCREASE ITS CONSUMPTION?
4.1 Subordinate options in Option (2)
Option (2) is the best choice, but how should the government increase its consumption? There
are two basic subordinate options in Option (2).
Option (2-1): Increase government consumption in order for the combined consumption to
jump up to point Z and then proceed on the posterior saddle path to the posterior steady state.
Option (2-2): Increase government consumption for the combined consumption to jump up to
point W, and then stay at point W.
Remember that combined consumption indicates the sum of government and household
consumptions. Option (2-1) indicates that the government intervenes so as to make the
combined consumption proceed on the posterior saddle path and eventually reach the posterior
steady state, and Option (2-2) indicates that it intervenes so as to make the production and
combined consumption stay at the prior steady state (i.e., at point W) forever. Note that, as noted
in Section 3.1.1, excess resources cannot be used for investments because the economy would
otherwise deviate from the posterior saddle path in Option (2-1) and from point W in
Option (2-2).
4.2 Option (2-1)
4.2.1 Basic features
When a government chooses Option (2-1), each household may change its consumption path in
response to the government’s action, but it is highly likely that households will still proceed on a
Pareto inefficient transition path because the households’ expected utilities are not affected by
the increase in government consumption. Here, a gap between the posterior saddle path (the thin
dashed curve in Figure 1) and production (the bold solid curve) for each kt indicates excess
capital. Excess capital needs to be “consumed” for the economy to be on the posterior saddle
path.3 Option (2-1) means that excess capital is consumed by the government. In addition, to be
on the posterior saddle path, government consumption needs to be increased not only to
consume excess capital but also to substitute for a reduction in household consumption that is
the source of the excess capital. That is, the government needs to consume not only the gap
between the posterior saddle path and production (i.e., excess capital), but also the gap between
3 If capital depreciation is assumed to exist, consumption of excess capital will be achieved by a reduction of
investments that corresponds to depreciated capital inputs and an increase in consumer goods and services.
10
production and the Pareto inefficient transition path while the economy proceeds from the prior
steady state to the posterior steady state. Because of the increase in government consumption,
the economy proceeds on the posterior saddle path and thereby high and persistent
unemployment rates are avoided.
4.2.2 Subordinate options
However, how does a government “consume” such a large quantity of excess resources, most of
which were originally produced as capital? There are three basic subordinate options: Options
(2-1-a), (2-1-b), and (2-1-c).
The easiest way for a government to consume the excess resources is simply to buy
them from firms and dispose of them (Option (2-1-a)). “Dispose of” in this case includes not
only eliminating them but also leaving them unused forever or constructing useless
infrastructure. It will also mean giving laborers busy work, including the classic example of
“having workers dig holes and then fill them back up.” These activities do not generate any
utility for households, but they can be interpreted as a kind of “consumption” in the broad sense
that the products purchased are intentionally made unusable. High unemployment rates can be
avoided, but huge amounts of resources are systematically and continuously disposed of and
negative growth rates continue for a long period.
Disposing of the excess resources in Option (2-2-a) is different from destroying them
in Option (1) because the owners of the excess resources lose them without compensation in
Option (1), but sell them to the government in Option (2-1-a). The excess resources are equally
eliminated in both options, but nothing remains in the hands of the former owners or the
government in Option (1), whereas financial assets and debts remain in the hands of the former
owners and government, respectively, in Option (2-1-a).
Another way to consume the excess resources is to export them to other countries at
lower prices than the prevailing international prices (Option (2-1-b). This is not “consumption”
in the literal sense, but it can be interpreted as a sort of consumption in that exports are an
element of demand. The government does not necessarily need to directly export the excess
resources. Instead, it can indirectly support exports by directly subsidizing firms or through
various kinds of regulations. An important problem with this option is that other countries may
not accept the excessive exports. This option clearly means setting prices that are far lower than
the costs of production (i.e., dumping) on a large scale. Other countries would not be likely to
stay silent on this issue and would likely take countermeasures, for example, by imposing high
anti-dumping customs. Therefore, Option (2-1-b) will generally not be adopted in a democratic
country.
There is one more important subordinate option. With minor modifications, capital
inputs can be used to produce arms and munitions. Hence, the necessary increase in government
consumption can easily be achieved by a large military buildup (Option (2-1-c)). An important
problem with this option is that a unilateral excessive military buildup will greatly worsen
international relations and increase political and military tensions among countries. Therefore,
in a democratic country, Option (2-1-c) will generally not be adopted.
4.3 Option (2-2)
4.3.1 Basic features
For the same reason as given for Option (2-1), it is highly likely that households also proceed on
a Pareto inefficient transition path in Option (2-2). When households proceed on this path, if the
government does nothing, a part of the capital that is used to produce products corresponding to
households’ reduction in consumption becomes excess capital and will be destroyed, but if the
government purchases and consumes these unconsumed products, the capital need not be
destroyed and the level of capital will remain the same in the next period. If the government
purchases and consumes the unconsumed products in every period, capital will continue to stay
at the same level indicated by point W. The phenomenon where capital is prevented from being
11
reduced by government intervention may be interpreted as keeping so-called “zombie” firms
alive. As in Option (2-1), high unemployment rates can be avoided, but unlike in Option (2-1),
the growth rate is not negative. Rather, it is zero because the economy stays at point W forever.
An important difference between Options (2-1) and (2-2) is that, unlike Option (2-1),
capital is not consumed by the government in Option (2-2), but households’ reduction in
consumption is equally substituted by an increase in government consumption in both options.
That is, in Option (2-2), the government consumes only the gap between production at point W
and the Pareto inefficient transition path (bold dashed curve) and does not consume the gap
between the posterior saddle path (thin dashed curve) and production at point W (i.e., capital).
As a result, production and capital remain at point W forever in Option (2-2).
4.3.2 Subordinate options
Option (2-2) also consists of three basic subordinate options depending on what path is chosen
at point W: Options (2-2-a), (2-2-b), and (2-2-c). As was the case with Option (2-1-a), the
easiest way for a government to consume excess resources is simply to buy them from firms and
dispose of them (Option (2-2-a)). As with Options (2-1-b) and (2-1-c), the necessary jump of the
government consumption can be achieved by exporting the excess resources (Option (2-2-b)) or
by a military buildup (Option (2-2-c)). However, for the same reasons as given for Options
(2-1-b) and (2-1-c), Options (2-2-b) and (2-2-c) will generally not be adopted in a democratic
country.
4.4 Comparison and evaluation
Section 4.3 indicates that the only feasible options are (2-1-a) and (2-2-a). On major issues,
commonalities and differences between the two options are as follows.
(1) Period of government intervention
In Option (2-1-a), excess capital decreases gradually and eventually becomes zero when the
economy arrives at the posterior steady state.4 Hence, the period of transition and government
intervention is definite. In Option (2-2-a), however, the economy never approaches the posterior
steady state. Hence, the government intervention never ends.
(2) Scale of government intervention
Because government consumption needs to be initially increased to point Z in Option (2-1-a),
the scale of intervention is initially much larger in Option (2-1-a) than in Option (2-2-a).
However, in Option (2-1-a), excess capital gradually decreases and eventually reaches the level
of the posterior steady state, and thereby the necessary increase in government consumption
decreases to zero as the economy approaches the posterior steady state. On the other hand, in
Option (2-2-a), the necessary increase in government consumption increases as household
consumption gradually decreases to the level at the posterior steady state. In sum, the scale of
intervention is initially larger in Option (2-1-a) than it is Option (2-2-a), but this relation will be
reversed in some future period.
(3) Growth rates during the transition
In Option (2-1-a), the growth rates are negative, whereas in Option (2-2-a), they are zero.
(4) Household utility
In both options, household consumption proceeds on the same Pareto inefficient transition path.
In addition, the Ricardian equivalence holds in the long run. Therefore, the utilities that
4 More correctly, the economy never arrives exactly at the posterior steady state, but it arrives close to it in a definite
period.
12
households will obtain from the stream of consumption after the shock are almost the same in
both cases.
(5) Unemployment
In both options, unemployment rates do not increase.
(6) Government debt
In both options, a large amount of government debt accumulates. However, if the government
properly increases taxes in the future, the debt will stabilize at some level in both options.
Although the period and scale of government interventions differ between the two options, these
differences basically do not matter to household optimality. Therefore, because the only
difference in the evaluated criteria is that growth rates are higher in Option (2-2-a), Option
(2-2-a) is considered to be more favorable than Option (2-1-a).
4.5 Technological progress
Although Option (2-2-a) is the best, it has its drawbacks. Huge amounts of resources need to be
disposed of in the name of the government consumption forever. Although this is rational from
an economic point of view, it may not be environmentally or ethically reasonable. If there is a
way to reduce the amount of discarded resources, that is, reduce excess capital, Option (2-2-a)
could be much better. It is impossible to find that way within the framework discussed in the
previous sections, but if the assumption on technological progress is loosened, it may be
possible.
Thus far, I have assumed no technological progress, but in reality, technologies
steadily progress. In addition, technological progress basically requires additional increases in
capital. Instead of adding capital, however, the new capital that is embedded in new
technologies can be introduced by using part of the excess capital. As a result, the amount of
excess capital is gradually reduced as part of the process of technological progress. Of course,
not all of the excess capital can be easily replaced in each period, but most of it should be able
to be replaced in the long run.
With the gradual replacement of the excess capital through technological progress, the
excess capital will eventually be fully eliminated and the government intervention will end.
Note nevertheless that this elimination process will take a long time. In addition, the economic
growth caused by technological progress will be slower because part of the increase in capital
required by technological progress is being replaced with a reduction in excess capital. The
economy will therefore grow more slowly because of the relatively slower growth of capital.
5 DISCUSSION
5.1 Japan since the 1990s
Japan has experienced low, occasionally negative, growth rates since the 1990s, even though the
Japanese government has spent huge amounts of money to stabilize its economy by issuing
similarly huge amounts of government bonds. At the same time, the debts of the Japanese
government have greatly increased. Japan’s experience seems to be very similar to the
consequences predicted when Option (2-2-a) is chosen. This similarity implies that the
stagnation of the Japanese economy since the 1990s was caused by an upward RTP shock, and
the Japanese government chose Option (2-2-a) as the countermeasure to the shock. Harashima
(2016) examines this possibility theoretically and empirically and concludes that RTP RH of
Japan rose 2–3 percentage points in the early 1990s, and this upward shift of RTP RH was the
cause of the stagnation of Japanese economy since the 1990s.
13
If the Japanese government had not chosen Option (2-2-a) and had instead chosen
Option (1), Japan would have experienced a significantly more severe recession, possibly
similar to the Great Depression of the 1930s. Production would have decreased and
unemployment rates would have increased far more than they did actually. Therefore, the
Japanese government may be praised for choosing the best option when facing a large upward
shift of RTP RH. However, the Japanese government should keep in mind that Option (2-2-a) is
only the best option if the government properly increases taxes to redeem the debts at some
point in the future.
5.2 The Great Depression and World War II
Many hypotheses on the causes of the Great Depression in the 1930s have been presented, but
no consensus has been reached. The phenomena observed during the Great Depression are very
similar to those predicted when Option (1) is chosen; that is, the growth rates were negative and
unemployment rates rose sharply. In addition, this agonizing situation was prolonged. Here, I
have indicated that the best option to tackle such a situation is to adopt Option (2-2-a), but large
discretionary fiscal interventions by governments were generally seen as taboo in that period.
Government expenditures were increased only to a limited extent in the United States with the
introduction of the New Deal, and the Great Depression persisted.
However, the U.S. economy recovered in 1940s after government consumption was
greatly increased to build up the military in the face of the outbreak of World War II. It is likely
that the U.S. government unintentionally or compulsorily chose Option (2-1-c) or (2-2-c).
Unemployment rates declined and destroying or disposing of resources stopped as predicted by
both options. In this case, it appears that the taboo against discretionary fiscal intervention was
broken because of the threat and outbreak of a large-scale war.
Similar phenomena were observed in Germany. Germany was one of the hardest-hit
economies by the Great Depression, but after the Nazis took power in 1933, the German
economy recovered quickly and sharply. The government of Nazi Germany significantly
intervened in various aspects of the German economy. This intervention eliminated the
large-scale Pareto inefficiency that was generated by the Great Depression. In particular, the
German government greatly built up its military so it is likely that Option (2-1-c) or (2-2-c) was
adopted to restore the German economy.
6 CONCLUDING REMARKS
If the steady state is shifted downwards by a fundamental shock, each household must change
its consumption path to one that diminishes gradually to the posterior steady state. Because
consumption decreases, a recession begins. In this case, if households increase their
consumption discontinuously to a point on the posterior saddle path and then follow that to the
posterior steady state, Pareto efficiency is held and unemployment rates do not rise. However,
households will not behave like this because it does not give them the highest expected utility.
Households are risk averse and dislike unsmooth and discontinuous consumption. Instead,
households will choose a Nash equilibrium of a Pareto inefficient path as the optimal
consumption path. Because of its Pareto inefficiency, the unemployment rate will increase
sharply and stay high for a long period.
In this paper, I examined whether discretionary fiscal policy is necessary if this type of
recession occurs, and if it is necessary, how it should be implemented. Particularly, the fiscal
policy for a Nash equilibrium of a Pareto inefficient path caused by an upward shock on RTP
was examined. In this case, a government has three options: (1) do not intervene, (2) increase
government consumption, and (3) cut taxes. Option (2) has several subordinate options. I
compared and evaluated these options and concluded that increasing government consumption
until the demand meets the present level of production and maintaining this fiscal policy is the
best option. The accompanying huge government debts can be sustainable even though they are
14
extremely large if the government properly increases taxes in the future. In this option, large
government debts play an essential role as a buffer against the negative effects of the shock.
15
APPENDIX
A Nash equilibrium of a Pareto inefficient path
A1 Model with non-cooperative households 5
A1.1 The shock
The model describes the utility maximization of households after an upward time preference
shock. This shock was chosen because it is one of the few shocks that result in a Nash
equilibrium of a Pareto inefficient path. Another important reason for selecting an upward time
preference shock is that it shifts the steady state to lower levels of production and consumption
than before the shock, which is consistent with the phenomena actually observed in a recession.
Although the rate of time preference (RTP) is a deep parameter, it has not been
regarded as a source of shocks for economic fluctuations, possibly because RTP is thought to be
constant and not to shift suddenly. There is also a practical reason, however. Models with a
permanently constant RTP exhibit excellent tractability (see Samuelson, 1937). However, RTP
has been naturally assumed and actually observed to be time-variable. The concept of a
time-varying RTP has a long history (e.g., Böhm-Bawerk, 1889; Fisher, 1930). More recently,
Lawrance (1991) and Becker and Mulligan (1997) showed that people do not inherit
permanently constant RTPs by nature and that economic and social factors affect the formation
of RTPs. Their arguments indicate that many incidents can affect and change RTP throughout a
person’s life. For example, Parkin (1988) examined business cycles in the United States,
explicitly considering the time-variability of RTP, and showed that RTP was as volatile as
technology and leisure preference.
A1.2 Households
Households are not intrinsically cooperative. Except in a strict communist economy, households
do not coordinate themselves to behave as a single entity when consuming goods and services.
The model in this paper assumes non-cooperative, identical, and infinitely long living
households and that the number of households is sufficiently large. Each of them equally
maximizes the expected utility
dtcuθtE
t
0
0
exp ,
subject to
ttt
t cδkkA,f
dt
dk
,
where yt, ct, and kt are production, consumption, and capital per capita in period t, respectively;
A is technology and constant; u is the utility function;
tt
kAfy , is the production function;
>θ 0 is RTP; δ is the rate of depreciation; and E0 is the expectations operator conditioned on
the agents’ period 0 information set. yt, ct, and kt are monotonically continuous and
differentiable in t, and u and f are monotonically continuous functions of ct and kt, respectively.
All households initially have an identical amount of financial assets equal to kt, and all
households gain the identical amount of income
tt
kAfy , in each period. It is assumed
5 The model in Appendix is based on the model by Harashima (2012). See also Harashima (2004, 2013b).
16
that
0
t
t
dc
cdu
and
0
2
2
t
t
dc
cud
; thus, households are risk averse. For simplicity, the utility
function is specified to be the constant relative risk aversion utility function
γ
c
cu
γ
t
t
1
1
if 1γ
tt
ccu ln if 1γ ,
where γ is a constant and γ0 . In addition, 0,
t
t
k
kAf
and
0
2
2
t
t
k
kf
. Both
technology (A) and labor supply are assumed to be constant.
The effects of an upward shift in RTP are shown in Figure A1. Suppose first that the
economy is at steady state before the shock. After the upward RTP shock, the vertical line
0
dt
dc
t moves to the left (from the solid vertical line to the dashed vertical line in Fig. 1). To
keep Pareto efficiency, consumption needs to jump immediately from the steady state before the
shock (the prior steady state) to point Z. After the jump, consumption proceeds on the Pareto
efficient saddle path after the shock (the posterior Pareto efficient saddle path) from point Z to
the lower steady state after the shock (the posterior steady state). Nevertheless, this
discontinuous jump to Z may be uncomfortable for risk-averse households that wish to smooth
consumption and not to experience substantial fluctuations. Households may instead take a
shortcut and, for example, proceed on a path on which consumption is reduced continuously
from the prior steady state to the posterior steady state (the bold dashed line in Fig. 1), but this
shortcut is not Pareto efficient.
Choosing a Pareto inefficient consumption path must be consistent with each
household’s maximization of its expected utility. To examine the possibility of the rational
choice of a Pareto inefficient path, the expected utilities between the two options need be
compared. For this comparison, I assume that there are two options for each non-cooperative
household with regard to consumption just after an upward shift in RTP. The first is a jump
option, J, in which a household’s consumption jumps to Z and then proceeds on the posterior
Pareto efficient saddle path to the posterior steady state. The second is a non-jump option, NJ, in
which a household’s consumption does not jump but instead gradually decreases from the prior
steady state to the posterior steady state, as shown by the bold dashed line in Figure A1. The
household that chooses the NJ option reaches the posterior steady state in period 0s . The
difference in consumption between the two options in each period t is bt (≥ 0). Thus, b0 indicates
the difference between Z and the prior steady state. bt diminishes continuously and becomes
zero in period s. The NJ path of consumption (ct) after the shock is monotonically continuous
and differentiable in t and 0
dt
dc
t if st 0 . In addition,
tt
ccc ˆ if st 0
cc
t
if ts 0 ,
where
t
ĉ is consumption when proceeding on the posterior Pareto efficient saddle path and
c
is consumption in the posterior steady state. Therefore,
0ˆ
ttt
ccb if st 0
0
t
b if ts 0 .
17
It is also assumed that, when a household chooses a different option from the one the
other households choose, the difference in the accumulation of financial assets resulting from
the difference in consumption (bt) before period s between that household and the other
households is reflected in consumption after period s. That is, the difference in the return on
financial assets is added to (or subtracted from) the household’s consumption in each period
after period s. The exact functional form of the addition (or subtraction) is shown in Section
A1.4.
A1.3 Firms
Unutilized products because of bt are eliminated quickly in each period by firms because
holding them for a long period is a cost to firms. Elimination of unutilized products is
accomplished by discarding the goods or preemptively suspending production, thereby leaving
some capital and labor inputs idle. However, in the next period, unutilized products are
generated again because the economy is not proceeding on the Pareto efficient saddle path.
Unutilized products are therefore successively generated and eliminated. Faced with these
unutilized products, firms dispose of the excess capital used to generate the unutilized products.
Disposing of the excess capital is rational for firms because the excess capital is an unnecessary
cost, but this means that parts of the firms are liquidated, which takes time and thus disposing of
the excess capital will also take time. If the economy proceeds on the NJ path (that is, if all
households choose the NJ option), firms dispose of all of the remaining excess capital that
generates bt and adjust their capital to the posterior steady-state level in period s, which also
corresponds to households reaching the posterior steady state. Thus, if the economy proceeds on
the NJ path, capital kt is
tt
kkk ˆ if st 0
kk
t
if ts 0 ,
where tk̂ is capital per capita when proceeding on the posterior Pareto efficient saddle path
and k is capital per capita in the posterior steady state.
The real interest rate it is
t
t
t
k
kAf
i
,
.
Because the real interest rate equals RTP at steady state, if the economy proceeds on the NJ
path,
θiθ
t
~
if st 0
θi
t
if ts 0 ,
where θ
~
is RTP before the shock and θ is RTP after the shock.
t
i is monotonically
continuous and differentiable in t if st 0 .
A1.4 Expected utility after the shock
The expected utility of a household after the shock depends on its choice of the J or NJ path. Let
Jalone indicate that the household chooses option J, but the other households choose option NJ;
NJalone indicate that the household chooses option NJ, but the other households choose option
J; Jtogether indicate that all households choose option J; and NJtogether indicate that all
18
households choose option NJ. Let p (0 ≤ p ≤ 1) be the subjective probability of a household that
the other households choose the J option (e.g., p = 0 indicates that all the other households
choose option NJ). With p, the expected utility of a household when it chooses option J is
JaloneEpJtogetherpEJE
0
00
1 , (A1)
and when it chooses option NJ is
00
pENJE (NJalone)+ NJtogetherEp
0
1 , (A2)
where JaloneE
0
, NJaloneE
0
,
JtogetherE
0
, and NJtogetherE
0
are the expected
utilities of the household when choosing Jalone, NJalone, Jtogether, and NJtogether,
respectively. Given the properties of J and NJ shown in Sections A1.2 and A1.3,
s
t
s
tt
dtcuθtdtbcuθtpEJE ˆexpexp
0
00
s
s
tt
dtacuθtdtbcuθtEp
0
0
expexp1 , (A3)
and
s
s
ttt
dtacuθtdtcuθtpENJE
0
00
ˆ
expexp
s
s
t
dtcuθtdtcuθtEp expexp1
0
0
, (A4)
where
s s
r
qr
drdqibθ
a
0
exp , (A5)
and
s s
r
qrtt
drdqibia
0
exp , (A6)
and the shock occurred in period t = 0. Figure A2 shows the paths of Jalone and NJalone.
Because there is a sufficiently large number of households and the effect of an individual
household on the whole economy is negligible, in the case of Jalone, the economy almost
proceeds on the NJ path. Similarly, in the case of NJalone, it almost proceeds on the J path. If
the other households choose the NJ option (Jalone or NJtogether), consumption after s is
constant as c and capital is adjusted to k by firms in period s. In addition, at and it are constant
after s such that at equals a and is equals θ, because the economy is at the posterior steady state.
Nevertheless, during the transition period before s, the value of it changes from the value of the
prior RTP to that of the posterior RTP. If the other households choose option J (NJalone or
Jtogether), however, consumption after s i
s
t
ĉ and capital is not adjusted to k by firms in period s
and remains at tk̂ .
As mentioned in Section A1.2, the difference in the returns on financial assets for the
household from the returns for each of the other households is added to (or subtracted from) its
19
consumption in each period after period s. This is described by at and a in equations (A3) and
(A4), and equations (A5) and (A6) indicate that the accumulated difference in financial assets
resulting from bt increases by compound interest between the period r to s. That is, if the
household takes the NJalone path, it accumulates more financial assets than each of the other J
households, and instead of immediately consuming these extra accumulated financial assets
after period s, the household consumes the returns on them in every subsequent period. If the
household takes the Jalone path, however, its consumption after s is ac , as shown in
equation (A3). a is subtracted because the income of each household,
tt
kAfy , , including
the Jalone household, decreases equally by bt. Each of the other NJ households decreases
consumption by bt at the same time, which compensates for the decrease in income; thus, its
financial assets (i.e., capital per capita; kt) are kept equal to tk̂ . The Jalone household, however,
does not decrease its consumption, and its financial assets become smaller than those of each of
the other NJ households, which results in the subtraction of a after period s.
A2 Nash Equilibrium of Pareto Inefficiency Path 6
A2.1 Rational Pareto inefficient path
A2.1.1 Rational choice of a Pareto inefficient path
Before examining the economy with non-cooperative households, I first show that, if
households are cooperative, only option J is chosen as the path after the shock because it gives a
higher expected utility than option NJ. Because there is no possibility of Jalone and NJalone if
households are cooperative, then JtogetherEJE
00
and NJtogetherENJE
00
.
Therefore,
NJEJE
00
s
s
t
s
t
s
tt
dtcuθtdtcuθtEdtcuθtdtbcuθtE expexpˆexpexp
0
0
0
0
s t
s
ttt
dtcucuθtdtcubcuθtE ˆexpexp
0
0
> 0
because
ttt
bcc and
t
cc ˆ .
Next, I examine the economy with non-cooperative households. First, the special case
with a utility function with a sufficiently small γ is examined.
Lemma A1: If γγ 0 is sufficiently small, then
0
00
NJtogetherEJaloneE .
Proof: NJtogetherEJaloneE
γ 00
0
lim
s
s γtttγ
dtcuacuθtEdtcubcuθtE
0 0
0
0
0
limexplimexp
s
s
t
dtaθtEdtbθtE
0
00
expexp
s
s s s
r
qrt
dtθtdrdqibθEdtbθtE expexpexp
0 0
0
0
s s s
r
qrt
drdqibθsEdtbθtE
0 0
00
expexpexp
s st qt dtdqitsθbθsE 00 expexpexp > 0 ,
6 The idea of a rationally chosen Pareto inefficient path was originally presented by Harashima (2004).
20
because, if st 0 , then θi
t
and
s
t
q
dqitsθ expexp . Hence, because tsθ exp
s
t
q
dqiexp , 000 NJtogetherEJaloneE for sufficiently small γ. ■
Second, the opposite special case (i.e., a utility function with a sufficiently large γ) is
examined.
Lemma A2: If γγ 0 is sufficiently large and if
1lim0
c
a
γ
, then JaloneE
0
0
0
NJtogetherE .
Proof: Because
t
b0 , then
0lim1
lim
11
1
γ
t
γ
tt
γtttγγ c
c
c
bc
cubcu
c
γ
for any period st . On the other hand, because a0 , then for any period st , if
1lim0
c
a
γ
,
γ
l i m
γγ
cuacu
c
γ
lim
1
1
1
γ
c
a
1
1 .
Thus,
γ
l i m
γ
c
γ
1
1
[E0 (Jalone) – E0 (NJtogether)]
dtcubcuθt
c
γ
tttγ
s
γγ
limexp
1
lim
01
dtcuacuθt
c
γ
γsγγ
limexp
1
lim
1
00 .
Because 0
1
1
γ
c
γ
for any γγ 1 , then if 1lim0
c
a
γ
, NJtogetherEJaloneE
00
< 0 for sufficiently large γ . ■
The condition 1lim0
c
a
γ
indicates that path NJ from c0 to c deviates sufficiently from the
posterior Pareto efficient saddle path and reaches the posterior steady state c not taking much
time. Because steady states are irrelevant to the degree of risk aversion (γ), both c0 and c are
irrelevant to γ.
By Lemmas A1 and A2, it can be proved that 0
00
NJtogetherEJaloneE is
possible.
Lemma A3: If 1lim0
c
a
γ
, then there is a γγ 0 such that if γγ ,
21
0
00
NJtogetherEJaloneE .
Proof: If 0γ is sufficiently small, then 0
00
NJtogetherEJaloneE by Lemma A1,
and if γ is sufficiently large and if 1lim0
c
a
γ
, then NJtogetherEJaloneE
00
0 by Lemma A2. Hence, if 1lim0
c
a
γ
, there is a certain γγ 0 such that, if
γγ , then 0
00
NJtogetherEJaloneE . ■
However, 0
00
NJaloneEJtogetherE because both Jtogether and NJalone
indicate that all the other households choose option J; thus, the values of it and kt are the same as
those when all households proceed on the posterior Pareto efficient saddle path. Faced with
these it and kt, deviating alone from the Pareto efficient path (NJalone) gives a lower expected
utility than Jtogether to the NJ household. Both Jalone and NJtogether indicate that all the other
households choose option NJ and it and kt are not those of the Pareto efficient path. Hence, the
sign of NJtogetherEJaloneE
00
varies depending on the conditions, as Lemma A3
indicates.
By Lemma A3 and the property 0
00
NJaloneEJtogetherE , the possibility of
the choice of a Pareto inefficient transition path, that is, 0
00
NJEJE , is shown.
Proposition A1: If 1lim0
c
a
γ
and γγ , then there is a 10 pp such that if
*
pp , 0
00
NJEJE , and if *pp , 0
00
NJEJE .
Proof: By Lemma A3, if γγ , then 0
00
NJtogetherEJaloneE and
JtogetherE
0
0
0
NJaloneE . By equations (A1) and (A2),
NJEJE
00
p NJaloneEJtogetherE
00
+ (1 – p) NJtogetherEJaloneE
00
.
Thus, if 1lim0
c
a
γ
and γγ , NJEJE
p
00
0
lim
0
00
NJtogetherEJaloneE and
0lim
0000
1
NJaloneEJtogetherENJEJE
p
. Hence, by the intermediate value
theorem, there is 10 pp such that if *pp , 0
00
NJEJE and if *pp ,
0
00
NJEJE . ■
Proposition A1 indicates that, if 1lim0
c
a
γ
, γγ , and p < p*, then the choice of
option NJ gives the higher expected utility than that of option J to a household; that is, a
household may make the rational choice of taking a Pareto inefficient transition path. The
lemmas and proposition require no friction, so a Pareto inefficient transition path can be chosen
even in a frictionless economy. This result is very important because it offers counter-evidence
against the conjecture that households never rationally choose a
Pareto inefficient transition path
in a frictionless economy.
A2.1.2 Conditions for a rational Pareto inefficient path
The proposition requires several conditions. Among them, γγ may appear rather strict.
If γ* is very large, path NJ will rarely be chosen. However, if path NJ is such that consumption
is reduced sharply after the shock, the NJ option yields a higher expected utility than the J
22
option even though γ is very small. For example, for any γγ 0 ,
0
lim
s s
1
[E0 (Jalone) – E0 (NJtogether)]
dtcuacuθt
s
dtcubcuθt
s ss
ttt
s
s
exp
1
limexp
1
lim
000
cd
cdu
bcubcu
s
bscucu
cubcu
s
0000
0
0
000
lim
1
0
111
0
1
0
1
00
0
1
0
1
00
b
γ
c
γ
bc
cccb
γ
cb
c
γγ
γγγ
γγ
,
because
0
0
0
000
1
0
1
00
1
1lnlnln
11
lim b
c
b
ccbcc
γ
c
γ
bc
c
γγ
γ
γ
and
0
1
11
lim
11
lim
1
0
0
1
0
1
0
1
00
γ
c
b
cc
γ
c
γ
bc
c
γ
γγ
γ
γγ
γ
γ
because
0
cc . That is, for
each combination of path NJ and γ, there is 0s such that, if ss , then JaloneE
0
0
0
NJtogetherE .
Consider an example in which path NJ is such that bt is constant and bbt before s
(Figure A3); thus,
s
t
bsbE
0
0
. In this NJ path, consumption is reduced more sharply than it
is in the case shown in Figure A2. In this case, because
s
t
bθsbθEa
0
0
, γ0 , and
ts
cc for st , then
ss
ss
ttt
cubcudtθtEdtcubcuθtE
0
0
0
0
expexp
ss
cubcu
θ
θs
E
exp1
0
, and in addition,
s
dtcuacuθtE exp
0
cubθscu
θ
θs
Ecuacu
θ
θs
EcuacudtθtE
s
expexp
exp
000
.
Hence,
E0 (Jalone) – E0 (NJtogether)
s
s
ttt
dtcuacuθtEdtcubcuθtE expexp
0
0
0
cubθscu
θ
θs
Ecubcu
θ
θs
E
ss
expexp1
00
bθscucu
θs
θs
cubcu
θ
θs
E
ss
exp1
expexp1
0
.
As γ increases, the ratio
bθscucu
cubcu
ss
decreases; thus, larger values of s can satisfy
0
00
NJtogetherEJaloneE . For example, suppose that c = 10, cs = 10.2, b = 0.3, and θ
23
= 0.05. If 1γ , then s* = 1.5 at the minimum, and if 5γ , then s* = 6.8 at the minimum. This
result implies that, if option NJ is such that consumption is reduced relatively sharply after the
shock (e.g., bb
t
) and *pp , option NJ will usually be chosen. Choosing option NJ is not a
special case observed only if γ is very large, but option NJ can normally be chosen when the
value of γ is within usually observed values. Conditions for generating a rational Pareto
inefficient transition path therefore are not strict. In a recession, consumption usually declines
sharply after the shock, which suggests that households have chosen the NJ option.
A3 Nash equilibrium
A3.1 A Nash equilibrium consisting of NJ strategies
A household strategically determines whether to choose the J or NJ option, considering other
households’ choices. All households know that each of them forms expectations about the
future values of its utility and makes a decision in the same manner. Since all households are
identical, the best response of each household is identical. Suppose that there are NΗ
identical households in the economy where H is sufficiently large (as assumed in Section A1).
Let 10 ηη qq be the probability that a household Ηη chooses option J. The average
utility of the other households almost equals that of all households because H is sufficiently
large. Hence, the average expected utilities of the other households that choose the J and NJ
options are E0(Jtogether) and E0(NJtogether), respectively. Hence, the payoff matrix of the
Η-dimensional symmetric mixed strategy game can be described as shown in Table A1. Each
identical household determines its behavior on the basis of this payoff matrix.
In this mixed strategy game, the strategy profiles
(q1,q2,…,qH) = {(1,1,…,1), ( *** ,…,, ppp ), (0,0,…,0)}
are Nash equilibria for the following reason. By Proposition A1, the best response of household
η is J (i.e., qη = 1) if *pp , indifferent between J and NJ (i.e., any 10,qη ) if *pp , and NJ
(i.e., qη = 0) if
*
pp . Because all households are identical, the best-response correspondence
of each household is identical such that qη = 1 if
*
pp , [0,1] if *pp , and 0 if *pp for
any household Ηη . Hence, the mixed strategy profiles (1, 1,…,1), ( *** ,…,, ppp ), and
(0,0,…,0) are the intersections of the graph of the best-response correspondences of all
households. The Pareto efficient saddle path solution (1,1,…,1) (i.e., Jtogether) is a pure
strategy Nash equilibrium, but a Pareto inefficient transition path (0,0,…,0) ( i.e., NJtogether) is
also a pure strategy Nash equilibrium. In addition, there is a mixed strategy Nash equilibrium
( *** ,…,, ppp ).
A3.2 Selection of equilibrium
Determining which Nash equilibrium, either NJtogether (0,0,…,0) or Jtogether (1,1,…,1), is
dominant requires refinements of the Nash equilibrium, which necessitate additional criteria.
Here, if households have a risk-averse preference in the sense that they avert the worst scenario
when its probability is not known, households suppose a very low p and select the NJtogether
(0,0,…,0) equilibrium. Because
E0 (Jalone) – E0 (NJalone)
dtacuacuθtdtcubcuθtE s
s
ttttt
0
0
ˆexpexp
s sttt dtcuacuθtdtcubcuθtE 00 expexp
24
= E0 (Jalone) – E0 (NJtogether) < 0 , (A7)
by Lemma A3, Jalone is the worst choice in terms of the amount of payoff, followed by
NJtogether, and NJalone, and Jtogether is the best. The outcomes of choosing option J are more
dispersed than those of option NJ. If households have a risk-averse preference in the
above-mentioned sense and avert the worst scenario when they have no information on its
probability, a household will prefer the less dispersed option (NJ), fearing the worst situation
that the household alone substantially increases consumption while the other households
substantially decrease consumption after the shock. This behavior is rational because it is
consistent with preferences. Because all households are identical and know inequality (A7), all
households will equally suppose that they all prefer the less dispersed NJ option; therefore, all
of them will suppose a very low p, particularly 0p , and select the NJtogether (0,0,…,0)
equilibrium, which is the Nash equilibrium of a Pareto inefficient path. Thereby, unlike most
multiple equilibria models, the problem of indeterminacy does not arise, and “animal spirits”
(e.g., pessimism or optimism) are unnecessary to explain the selection.
A4 Amplified generation of unutilized resources
A Nash equilibrium of a Pareto inefficient path successively generates unutilized products
because of bt. They are left unused, discarded, or preemptively not produced during the path.
Unused or discarded goods and services indicate a decline in sales and an increase in inventory
for firms. Preemptively suspended production results in an increase in unemployment and idle
capital. As a result, profits decline and some parts of firms need to be liquidated, which is
unnecessary if the economy proceeds on the J path (i.e., the posterior Pareto efficient path). If
the liquidation is implemented immediately after the shock, unutilized products because of bt
will no longer be generated, but such a liquidation would generate a tremendous shock. The
process of the liquidation, however, will take time because of various frictions, and excess
capital that generates unutilized products because of bt will remain for a long period. During the
period when capital is not reduced to the posterior steady-state level, unutilized products are
successively generated. In a period, unutilized products are generated and eliminated, but in the
next period, another, new, unutilized products are generated and eliminated. This cycle is
repeated in every period throughout the transition path, and it implies that demand is lower than
supply in every period. This phenomenon may be interpreted as a general glut or a persisting
disequilibrium by some definitions of equilibrium.
25
References
Acemoglu, Daron, Simon Johnson and James A. Robinson. (2001) “The Colonial Origins of
Comparative Development: An Empirical Investigation,” American Economic Review, Vol.
91, No. 5, pp. 1369-1401.
Acemoglu, Daron, Simon Johnson and James Alan Robinson. (2002). “Reversal of Fortune:
Geography and Institutions in the Making of the Modern World Income Distribution,”
Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 117, No. 4, pp. 1231-1294.
Acemoglu, Daron, Simon Johnson and James A. Robinson. (2005) “Institutions as a
Fundamental Cause of Long-Run Growth,” in Handbook of Economic Growth, Vol. 1, Part
A, Chapter 6, pp 385-472, Aghion, Philippe and Steven Durlauf (ed.), Elsevier, Amsterdam.
Alesina, Alberto (2012) “Fiscal Policy after the Great Recession,” Atlantic Economic Journal,
Vol. 40, No. 4, pp. 429-435.
Barro, Robert J. (1999) “Determinants of Democracy,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 107,
No. S6, pp. S158-29.
Becker, Gary S. and Casey Mulligan (1997) “The Endogenous Determination of Time
Preference,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 112, No. 3, pp. 729–758.
Benhabib, Jess, George W. Evansb, Seppo Honkapohjad (2014) “Liquidity Traps and
Expectation Dynamics: Fiscal Stimulus or Fiscal Austerity?” Journal of Economic
Dynamics and Control, Vol. 45, pp. 220–238.
Blanchard, Olivier (2009) “The State of Macro,” Annual Review of Economics, Annual Reviews,
Vol. 1, pp. 209-228,
Bohn, Henning (1995) “The Sustainability of Budget Deficits in a Stochastic Economy,”
Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Vol. 27, pp. 257-71.
Böhm-Bawerk, Eugen von (1889) Capital and Interest, Reprinted by Libertarian Press, South
Holland, IL, 1970.
Chari, V., Kehoe, P. J. and McGrattan, E. R. (2009) “New Keynesian Models: Not Yet Useful
for Policy Analysis,” American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, Vol. 1, No. 1, pp.
242–66.
Cochrane, John H. (2005) “Money as stock,” Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol 52, No. 3,
pp. 501-528.
Dollar, David and Aart Kraay. (2003) “Institutions, Trade and Growth,” Journal of Monetary
Economics, Vol. 50, No. 1, pp. 133-162.
Easterly, William and Ross Levine. (2003) “Tropics, Germs, and Crops: How Endowments
Influence Economic Development.” Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 50, No. 1, pp.
3-39.
Epstein, Larry G. and J. Allan Hynes (1983) “The Rate of Time Preference and Dynamic
Economic Analysis,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 91, No. 4, pp. 611-635.
Farmer, Roger E. A.(2009) “Fiscal Policy Can Reduce Unemployment: But There is a Less
Costly and More Effective Alternative,” NBER Working Papers, No. 15021.
Fisher, Irving (1930) The Theory of Interest, Macmillan, New York
Glaeser, Edward L., Rafael La Porta, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes and Andrei Shleifer. (2004)
“Do Institutions Cause Growth?” Journal of Economic Growth, Vol. 9, No. 3, pp. 271-303.
Hall, Robert E. (2016) “Macroeconomics of Persistent Slumps,” NBER Working Paper, No.
22230.
Hall, Robert E. and Charles I. Jones. (1999) “Why Do Some Countries Produce So Much More
Output Per Worker Than Others?” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 114, No. 1, pp.
83-116.
Hamilton, J. D. and M. A. Flavin (1986) “On the Limitations of Government Borrowing: A
Framework for Empirical Testing,” American Economic Review, Vol. 76, pp. 808-19.
Harashima, Taiji (2004) “A More Realistic Endogenous Time Preference Model and the Slump
in Japan,” EconWPA Working Papers, ewp-mac0402015.
26
Harashima, Taiji (2006) “The Sustainability of Budget Deficits in an Inflationary Economy,”
MPRA (The Munich Personal RePEc Archive) Paper, No. 1088.
Harashima, Taiji (2009) “Depression as a Nash Equilibrium Consisting of Strategies of
Choosing a Pareto Inefficient Transition Path,” MPRA (The Munich Personal RePEc
Archive) Paper, No. 18987.
Harashima, Taiji (2013a) “Escaping a Liquidity Trap: Keynes’ Prescription Is Right But His
Reasoning Is Wrong,” MPRA (The Munich Personal RePEc Archive) Paper, No. 69217.
Harashima, Taiji (2013b) The Economics of Fiscal Deficits (Zaisei Akaji No Keizaigaku),
Buitsu-Soryushon, Nagoya, Japan (in Japanese).
Harashima, Taiji (2014) “Time Preference Shocks,” MPRA (The Munich Personal RePEc
Archive) Paper, No. 60205.
Harashima, Taiji (2016) “The Cause of the Great Recession: What Caused the Downward Shift
of the GDP Trend in the United States?” MPRA (The Munich Personal RePEc Archive)
Paper, No. 69215.
Ireland, Peter N. (2011) “ A New Keynesian Perspective on the Great Recession,” Journal of
Money, Credit and Banking, Vol. 43, No. 1, pp. 31-54.
Keynes, John Maynard (1936) The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money,
Macmillan Cambridge University Press, London.
Knack, Stephen and Philip Keefer. (1995) “Institutions and Economic Performance:
Cross-country Tests Using Alternative Institutional Measures.” Economics & Politics, Vol.
7, No. 3, pp. 207–227.
Kopcke, Richard W., Geoffrey M. B. Tootell, and Robert K. Triest, eds., (2006) The
Macroeconomics of Fiscal Policy, MIT Press, Cambridge.
Lawrance, Emily C. (1991) “Poverty and the Rate of Time Preference: Evidence from Panel
Data,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 99, No. 1, pp. 54–77.
Leeper, Eric (1991) “Equilibria under Active and Passive Monetary and Fiscal Policies,”
Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 27, pp. 129-147.
Lucas, Robert E., Jr. and Nancy L. Stokey (1984) “Optimal Growth with Many Consumers,”
Journal of Economic Theory, Vol. 32, pp. 139-171.
McGrattan, Ellen R. and Edward C. Prescott (2014) “A Reassessment of Real Business Cycle
Theory,” American Economic Review, Vol. 104, No. 5, pp. 177-182.
Mankiw, N. Gregory (2001) “The Inexorable and Mysterious Tradeoff between Inflation and
Unemployment,” Economic Journal, Vol. 111, Issue 471, pp. C45–61
Mauro, Paolo. (1995) “Corruption and Growth,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 110, No.
3, pp. 681-712.
Obstfeld, Maurice (1990) “Intertemporal Dependence, Impatience, and Dynamics,” Journal of
Monetary Economics, Vol. 26, No. 1, pp. 45-75.
Parkin, Michael (1988) “A Method for Determining Whether Parameters in Aggregative Models
Are Structural,” Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, Vol. 29, No. 1, pp.
215–252.
Rebelo, Sergio T. (2005) “Real Business Cycle Models: Past, Present, and Future,”
Scandinavian Journal of Economics, Vol. 107, No. 2, pp. 217-238.
Rodrik, Dani, Arvind Subramanian and Francesco Trebbi. (2004). “Institutions Rule: The
Primacy of Institutions Over Geography and Integration in Economic Development,”
Journal of Economic Growth, Vol. 9, No. 2, pp. 131-165.
Samuelson, Paul (1937) “A Note on Measurement of Utility,” Review of Economic Studies, Vol.
4, No. 2, pp. 155–161.
Sargent, Thomas J. and Neil Wallace (1981) “Some Unpleasant Monetarist Arithmetic.”
Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, Quarterly Review, No. 5, pp. 1-18.
Schmitt-Grohé, Stephanie and Martín Uribe (2012) “What’s News in Business Cycles,”
Econometrica, Vol. 80, pp. 2733-2764.
27
Sims, Christopher A. (1994) “A Simple Model for Study of the Determination of the Price
Level and the Interaction of Monetary and Fiscal Policy,” Economic Theory, No. 4, pp.
381-399.
Sims, Christopher A. (1998) “Econometric Implications of the Government Budget Constraint,”
Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 83, No. 1–2, pp. 9–19.
Woodford, Michael (2001) “Fiscal Requirements for Price Stability,” Journal of Money, Credit
and Banking, Vol. 33, pp. 669-728.
Uzawa, Hirofumi. (1968) “Time Preference, the Consumption Function, and Optimal Asset
Holdings,” in Value, Capital, and Growth: Papers in Honour of Sir John Hicks (J. N. Wolfe
ed.), University of Edinburgh Press, Edinburgh, Scotland.
28
kt
ct
Steady state before the
shock on θ
Steady state after
the shock on θ
Line of 0
dt
dc
t
after the shock on θ
Line of 0
dt
dk
t
Z
Pareto inefficient transition path
Line of 0
dt
dc
t
before the shock on θ
Pareto efficient
saddle path after
the shock on θ
Pareto efficient saddle path
before the shock on θ
Figure A1: A time preference shock
0
29
Figure A2: The paths of Jalone and NJalone
ac
Path of NJalone
ac
Path of Jalone
c
0
c
0
s t
00
bc
ct
30
Figure A3: A Pareto inefficient transition path
Posterior Pareto efficient saddle path
Path of NJtogether
c
0
c
0 s t
00
bc
ct
31
Table A1 The payoff matrix
Any other household
J NJ
H
o
u
se
h
o
ld
A
J E0(Jtogether), E0(Jtogether) E0(Jalone), E0(NJtogether)
NJ E0(NJalone), E0(Jtogether) E0(NJtogether), E0(NJtogether)
We provide professional writing services to help you score straight A’s by submitting custom written assignments that mirror your guidelines.
Get result-oriented writing and never worry about grades anymore. We follow the highest quality standards to make sure that you get perfect assignments.
Our writers have experience in dealing with papers of every educational level. You can surely rely on the expertise of our qualified professionals.
Your deadline is our threshold for success and we take it very seriously. We make sure you receive your papers before your predefined time.
Someone from our customer support team is always here to respond to your questions. So, hit us up if you have got any ambiguity or concern.
Sit back and relax while we help you out with writing your papers. We have an ultimate policy for keeping your personal and order-related details a secret.
We assure you that your document will be thoroughly checked for plagiarism and grammatical errors as we use highly authentic and licit sources.
Still reluctant about placing an order? Our 100% Moneyback Guarantee backs you up on rare occasions where you aren’t satisfied with the writing.
You don’t have to wait for an update for hours; you can track the progress of your order any time you want. We share the status after each step.
Although you can leverage our expertise for any writing task, we have a knack for creating flawless papers for the following document types.
Although you can leverage our expertise for any writing task, we have a knack for creating flawless papers for the following document types.
From brainstorming your paper's outline to perfecting its grammar, we perform every step carefully to make your paper worthy of A grade.
Hire your preferred writer anytime. Simply specify if you want your preferred expert to write your paper and we’ll make that happen.
Get an elaborate and authentic grammar check report with your work to have the grammar goodness sealed in your document.
You can purchase this feature if you want our writers to sum up your paper in the form of a concise and well-articulated summary.
You don’t have to worry about plagiarism anymore. Get a plagiarism report to certify the uniqueness of your work.
Join us for the best experience while seeking writing assistance in your college life. A good grade is all you need to boost up your academic excellence and we are all about it.
We create perfect papers according to the guidelines.
We seamlessly edit out errors from your papers.
We thoroughly read your final draft to identify errors.
Work with ultimate peace of mind because we ensure that your academic work is our responsibility and your grades are a top concern for us!
Dedication. Quality. Commitment. Punctuality
Here is what we have achieved so far. These numbers are evidence that we go the extra mile to make your college journey successful.
We have the most intuitive and minimalistic process so that you can easily place an order. Just follow a few steps to unlock success.
We understand your guidelines first before delivering any writing service. You can discuss your writing needs and we will have them evaluated by our dedicated team.
We write your papers in a standardized way. We complete your work in such a way that it turns out to be a perfect description of your guidelines.
We promise you excellent grades and academic excellence that you always longed for. Our writers stay in touch with you via email.