Economics

 4 pages essay

2 Readings required to use in the essay, needs citation

Don't use plagiarized sources. Get Your Custom Essay on
Economics
Just from $13/Page
Order Essay

Instructions is attached below.

1 23

1 23

Your article is protected by copyright and all
rights are held exclusively by Royal Swedish
Academy of Sciences. This e-offprint is for
personal use only and shall not be self-
archived in electronic repositories. If you
wish to self-archive your work, please use the
accepted author’s version for posting to your
own website or your institution’s repository.
You may further deposit the accepted author’s
version on a funder’s repository at a funder’s
request, provided it is not made publicly
available until 12 months after publication.

REVIEW PAPER

  • Paying for International Environmental Public Goods
  • Rodrigo Arriagada, Charles Perrings

    Received: 21 December 2010 / Revised: 20 April 2011 / Accepted: 29 April 2011 / Published online: 2 June 2011

    Abstract Supply of international environmental public
    goods must meet certain conditions to be socially efficient,
    and several reasons explain why they are currently under-

    supplied. Diagnosis of the public goods failure associated

    with

    particular ecosystem services is critical to the devel-

    opment of the appropriate international response. There are

    two categories of international environmental public goods

    that are most likely to be undersupplied. One has an
    additive supply technology and the other has a weakest link

    supply technology. The degree to which the collective
    response should be targeted depends on the importance of

    supply from any one country. In principle, the solution for

    the undersupply lies in payments designed to compensate
    local providers for the additional costs they incur in

    meeting global demand. Targeted support may take the

    form of direct investment in supply (the Global Environ-
    ment Facility model) or of payments for the benefits of

    supply (the Payments for Ecosystem Services model).

    Keywords International environmental public goods !
    Ecosystem services ! Payments for ecosystem services !
    Global environmental public

    INTRODUCTION

    How can we best secure the provision of international
    environmental public goods (IEPGs)—public goods offer-

    ing benefits that span multiple national jurisdictions? It is

    well understood that markets undersupply public goods,
    and there is a wealth of evidence that many environmental

    public goods have been systematically undersupplied over

    a long period of time (Millennium Ecosystem Assessment
    2005). If environmental public goods occur at the scale of

    the nation state or below, the failure of markets to supply

    public goods may be offset by the actions of local or

    national governments. There exist many national agencies
    with responsibilities for the provision of environmental

    public goods such as habitat for rare and endangered spe-

    cies, clean water, environmental health protection, and so
    on. There also exist many offset or mitigation systems for

    securing private provision of public goods at a national

    level (Madsen et al. 2010). At the international level, where
    there is no supranational authority to take responsibility,

    the failure of markets to deliver environmental public
    goods is more difficult to offset. Depending upon the

    magnitude and distribution of the payoffs to public good

    provision, individual countries will have a stronger or
    weaker incentive to commit resources to their provision.

    Doing more than that depends upon agreement between

    nation states (Kaul et al. 2003a; Barrett 2007).
    Many IEPGs are strictly global. Examples include the

    conservation of the genetic diversity on which all future

    evolution depends, the mitigation of climate change, the
    control of emerging infectious diseases, and the manage-

    ment of sea areas beyond national jurisdiction. Many more

    are regional, such as the control of acid rain, the manage-
    ment of multi-country river basins, and the protection of

    international watersheds (Touza and Perrings 2011). Like

    all public goods, IEPGs exhibit both consumption indi-
    visibilities and non-excludability. Non-excludability means

    that once the good is provided, none can be excluded from

    enjoying the benefits it confers. Indivisible consumption
    occurs when one country’s enjoyment of the benefits does

    not diminish the amount available for others. Public goods

    are said to be ‘pure’ when they are both non-exclusive and
    non-rival (indivisible) in consumption. They are said to be

    impure if they are either partially excludable or partially

    rival—the most common form of which are local public
    goods, particularly the local common pool resources

    123
    ! Royal Swedish Academy of Sciences 2011

    www.kva.se/en

    AMBIO (2011) 40:798–806

    DOI 10.1007/s13280-011-0156-2

    Author’s personal copy

    analyzed by Ostrom (1990). In most cases, it is not possible

    for any single state to provide such goods on its own.
    International public good supply depends on either inter-

    national coordination or international cooperation (Anand

    2004).
    This article focuses on IEPGs whose benefits extend to

    people in multiple countries. Such IEPGs frequently also

    deliver benefits across multiple generations (Kaul et al.
    1999), but we do not address this aspect of the problem. In

    practice, the beneficiaries of international public goods
    include national populations and their representatives,

    nation states, transnational corporations and non-govern-

    mental organizations, as well as a newly emerging set of
    institutions. Globalization has altered the way that mem-

    bers of civil society organize themselves across national

    boundaries. The information revolution has also stimulated
    new forms of social participation. New networks, fre-

    quently built around environmental websites, enable the

    exchange of ideas and implementation techniques. These
    new relationships and interactions have created a ‘global

    environmental public’, interested in asserting new rights

    and responsibilities to the resources of the planet. Its
    concerns span both the ethical responsibilities of individ-

    uals, organizations, countries and corporations, and the

    alternative forms of governance of the biosphere.
    Following the Millennium Ecosystem Assessment, we

    suppose that the benefits people obtain from biosphere

    depend on a set of ecosystem services comprising:

    • Provisioning services: products people obtain from
    ecosystems, such as food, fuel, fiber, fresh water, and
    genetic resources.

    • Cultural services: nonmaterial benefits people obtain
    from ecosystems through spiritual enrichment, cogni-
    tive development, reflection, recreation, and aesthetic

    experiences.

    • Regulating services: benefits people obtain from the
    regulation of ecosystem processes, including air quality

    maintenance, climate regulation, erosion control, reg-

    ulation of floods and droughts, regulation of human
    diseases, and water purification.

    • Supporting services: those that are necessary for the
    production of all other ecosystem services, such as
    primary production, production of oxygen, and soil

    formation.

    These services affect human wellbeing in many ways:

    through their role in the production of consumption goods,

    their support of human health and security, or the satis-
    faction of peoples’ cultural and spiritual needs. A number

    of these services have the characteristics of IEPGs, the

    most important of which involve the regulating and sup-
    porting services. Figure 1 indicates the relation between

    categories of ecosystem services and components of

    wellbeing identified by the Millennium Ecosystem

    Assessment. Of these, only the provisioning services con-
    sistently generate benefits that are both divisible (rival) and

    exclusive. The other services yield benefits that are gen-

    erally indivisible and non-exclusive. We focus on the group
    of ecosystem services that are both public and interna-

    tional. These are services that: (i) cover more than one

    group of countries; (ii) benefit not only a broad spectrum of
    countries but also a broad spectrum of the global popula-

    tion; (iii) meet the needs of both present and future gen-
    erations (Kaul et al. 1999; Anand 2004). International

    public goods generated in any one county must therefore

    generate spillover effects beyond a nation’s boundary
    (Morrissey et al. 2002).

    IEPGs can further be classified according to their

    ‘technology of supply’ (Sandler 2004). The standard
    treatment of public goods focuses on demand (Hirshleifer

    1983). However, understanding the technology of supply of

    IEPGs is critical to the development of appropriate incen-
    tives. Three common examples of public good supply

    technologies are ‘additive’, ‘best shot’, and ‘weakest link’

    technologies. As the name implies, in the additive case, the
    socially available amount Y of a public good is nothing but
    the ‘simple sum’ of the separate amounts, yi, produced by
    each of m participating countries, the i = 1,…, m. In the
    case of simple sum public goods, such as carbon seques-

    tration, each unit of carbon sequestered has the same value

    no matter where it occurs. In the case of weighted sum
    public goods, such as habitat protection, the contribution of

    each hectare protected depends on its characteristics

    (Sandler 2004). For ‘best shot’ public goods, the benefit to
    all countries is determined by the most effective provider.

    For example, the Centers for Disease Control and Pre-

    vention are funded by the U.S.A., but provide information
    on infectious diseases to all countries. For ‘weakest link’

    public goods, the benefits to all countries are limited to the

    benefits offered by the least effective provider. The best
    example of this is the control of infectious diseases. So for

    HIV and tuberculosis, the level of protection available to

    all countries is only as good as the control of the disease
    exercised in the poorest, most densely populated, and least

    well-coordinated country (Perrings et al. 2002).

    Social composition functions

    Y ”

    X

    i
    yi Summation

    Y ” min
    i

    yiY ” min
    i

    yi Weakest-link

    Y ” max
    i

    yi Best-shot

    Of all the Millennium Ecosystem Assessment ecosystem
    services, the regulating services are most often supplied as

    IEPGs. Examples include disease control, which is

    frequently supplied as a weakest or weaker link public

    AMBIO (2011) 40:798–806 799

    ! Royal Swedish Academy of Sciences 2011
    www.kva.se/en 123

    Author’s personal copy

    good, climate regulation through, e.g., carbon sequestration,

    which is supplied as an additive pure public good, or

    watershed protection which is generally an additive but
    impure public good (Holzinger 2001; Dombrowsky 2007;

    Touza and Perrings 2011). Many international public goods

    are also jointly produced with local public goods.
    Biodiversity in tropical forests, for example, yields a set of

    private benefits in the form of timber and other products
    including medicinal plants, hunting, fishing, recreation, and

    tourism. At the same time, tropical forests are a source of

    carbon sequestration, genetic information, hydrological and
    microclimatic regulation—commonly described as co-

    benefits (Perrings and Gadgil 2003).

    An important feature of IEPG is that their spatial extent
    depends partly on the natural hydrological and atmospheric

    flows, and partly on the social linkages between coun-

    tries—the flow of goods, people, and information. The
    global reach of carbon sequestration is a property of the

    general circulation system, but the global reach of disease

    regulation is a property of the global trade and air trans-
    portation systems. In fact, the closer integration of the

    world economic system has rapidly increased the number

    of environmental public goods that are global in reach
    (Kaul et al. 2003b):

    • New technologies increasingly enhance human mobil-
    ity as well as the movement of goods, services, and

    information around the world (e.g., case of transmission

    of human diseases and air pollution as international
    environmental public bads).

    • Economic and political openness have provided further
    impetuses to cross borders and transnational activities

    (e.g., case of transmission of human diseases and air
    pollution as international environmental public bads).

    • Systematic risks have increased (e.g., case of climate
    change as an international environmental public bad).

    • International regimes are becoming more influential,
    often formulated by small groups of powerful nations

    yet often claiming universal applicability (e.g., case of
    bio-prospecting contracts to find cure for cancer and

    other human diseases).

    The central problem addressed in this article is how to
    secure environmental public goods that (a) are provided at

    particular locations but offer benefits over a wider area, and

    (b) generate local benefits that are below the local cost of
    supply. These are the IEPGs that are most likely to be

    undersupplied. This article is organized in four sections.

    The following section reviews the fundamental problem
    with IEPGs—the incentive that each country has to free

    ride on the efforts of others. A third section then considers

    the options for addressing the problem. This reviews the
    applicability of currently popular instruments, such as

    payments for ecosystem services, in terms of the charac-

    teristics of the public good concerned. A final section
    draws out the implications for national and international

    environmental policy.

    WHY ARE INTERNATIONAL ENVIRONMENTAL
    PUBLIC GOODS UNDERPROVIDED?

    International environmental public goods generate benefits
    that spill over national borders, so that the benefits (or

    Provisioning
    (food, fuel , fiber, fresh water, and

    genetic resources)

    ECOSYSTEM SERVICES

    Cultural
    (spiritual enrichment, cognitive

    development, reflection,
    recreation, and aesthetic

    experiences)

    Regulating
    (air quality maintenance, climate

    regulation, erosion control,
    regulation of floods and droughts,
    regulation of human diseases, and

    water purification)

    Security
    • Personal safety
    • Secure resource access
    • Security from disasters

    Basic material for good life
    • Adequate livelihoods
    • Sufficient nutritious food
    • Shelter
    • Access to goods

    Health
    • Strength
    • Feeling well
    • Access to clean air and water

    Good social relations
    • Social cohesion
    • Mutual respect
    • Ability to help others

    CONSTITUENTS OF WELL-BEING

    ARROW’S COLOR
    Potential for mediation by socioeconomic factors

    Low Medium High

    Supporting
    (nutrient

    cycling, soil
    formation,

    and primary
    production)

    Fig. 1 Linkages between
    ecosystem services and human
    well-being (arrow’s width
    intensity of linkages between
    ecosystem services and human
    well-being) (adapted from
    Millennium Ecosystem
    Assessment, 2003)

    800 AMBIO (2011) 40:798–806

    123
    ! Royal Swedish Academy of Sciences 2011
    www.kva.se/en
    Author’s personal copy

    costs) of those goods extend beyond the country of origin.

    If the marginal local benefits of public good provision are
    less than the marginal local costs, there will be no incentive

    to provide the public good at all. If the marginal local

    benefits of public good provision exceed the marginal local
    costs of provision, but benefits also accrue to other coun-

    tries, there will be an incentive to produce the public good,

    but unless the country is a ‘best-shot provider’ it will not be
    at a level that would satisfy international demand (Ferroni

    and Mody 2002; Kanbur 2003, 2004). We first of all review
    the problem and then consider the options for addressing it.

    We have elsewhere considered the cases where the national

    incentive to produce IEPGs is sufficient to meet global
    demand (Touza and Perrings 2011). In this article, we

    address the case where independent local action is not

    sufficient to secure efficient global supply.
    Consider the conservation of endangered species. Can

    we rely on the national action to produce the efficient

    amount of an IEPG such as the protection of iconic spe-
    cies? The key to understanding this lies in the difference

    between a pure public good and a private good. For a

    private good, everyone pays the same price, but is free to
    consume as much or as little as they want. Consumers

    adjust the quantity they consume given the market price.

    For a pure public good everyone consumes the same
    amount of the ‘‘good’’ but is willing to pay a different price

    for it. Consumers adjust the amount they are willing to pay

    for the public good given the quantity supplied (Batina and
    Ihori 2005). In general, private provision of public goods

    will be below the socially optimal level. Efficiency requires

    that marginal benefit equals marginal cost. In the case of
    conservation of endangered species (or any other public

    good), the relevant measure of marginal benefits is social

    marginal benefit—the sum of all countries marginal bene-

    fits. We illustrate the problem in Fig. 2, in which local and
    global benefit curves for species conservation in a partic-

    ular country, i, are presented. Global benefits are repre-
    sented by the vertical sum of the benefit curves of country
    i, and all other countries.

    The level of conservation in country i that maximizes
    local net benefits is indicated by yi, while the level of
    conservation that maximizes global benefits is indicated by

    yi#. yi is given by the intersection of local supply and local
    benefit curves, and yi# by the intersection of local supply
    and the vertical sum of local benefits for all countries.

    Since the marginal cost of provision at yi# is greater than
    country i would be willing to accept on its own, socially
    optimal provision of the public good depends on the

    existence of a mechanism to cover the ‘incremental’ cost of
    socially optimal provision to country i.

    Biodiversity conservation, like many other IEPGs, is an

    impure global public good. If there are many potential
    providers, each generates local benefits from its conser-

    vation effort, but also benefits from the conservation

    actions of others. Following, Perrings and Gadgil (2003),
    we characterize the problem for the individual country as

    follows. Vi denotes welfare of the ith country, assumed to
    depend on consumption of a vector of market goods, xi, and
    global biodiversity conservation, denoted C = C(y1,
    y2,…,ym), then the problem it faces is of the general form:

    MaxxiyiV
    i xi; yi; C y1; . . .; ym

    ! “! ”

    In other words, it derives a direct benefit from its own

    conservation efforts, yi, but also benefits from the global
    conservation effort to which it has contributed, C. If the
    cost of conservation effort in terms of the cost of market

    Quantity of local
    conservation effort

    Costs and
    benefits of
    local
    conservation
    effort

    Global benefits
    Costs of local
    conservation effort

    yi yi*

    ‘Incremental
    cost’ =
    benefits to
    global
    interests in
    excess of
    costs
    warranted by
    local interest
    of country i

    Benefits to all other countries

    Benefits to country i

    Fig. 2 Efficient provision of
    conservation effort

    AMBIO (2011) 40:798–806 801

    ! Royal Swedish Academy of Sciences 2011
    www.kva.se/en 123
    Author’s personal copy

    goods is p(yi), and if the income available to country i is Ii,
    this will be subject to the constraint that

    Ii ” xi $ p

    yi

    ! ”

    yi

    In the absence of cooperation, and noting that

    Viyi ” oV
    i=oyi; Vixi ” oV

    i=oxi and Cyi ” oC=oyi, wellbeing
    of the ith country will be maximized where the local level
    of conservation satisfies:

    ViYi
    Vi
    xi
    ” pyi %

    Vic
    Vi
    xi
    Cyi

    If global wellbeing is the sum of the welfare of all
    countries, V ”

    P
    j”1 V

    j, then global wellbeing will be

    maximized where

    ViYi
    Vi
    xi
    ” pyi %
    X

    j”1

    V jc
    Vi
    xi
    Cyi

    The extra terms in the summation term on the right hand
    side capture the conservation benefits that the ith country
    confers on all other countries. These benefits will be

    neglected by the ith country unless there is a mechanism to
    convert them into a direct incentive.

    The failure of markets to signal the global benefit of

    such public goods accordingly results in under-invest-
    ment in their local provision. The benefits of protection,

    management and establishment of forests provide a good

    example. Apart from the loss of the valuable environ-
    mental services (e.g., protection of genetic resources, air

    quality maintenance, climate regulation and regulation of
    human diseases), forest degradation frequently translates

    into a loss of timber and non-timber forest products

    important to local livelihoods (Landell-Mills & Porras
    2002).

    Currently, there are few measures of the underprovi-

    sion of public goods. The United Nations Development
    Programme (UNDP) has opted instead for measures of

    ‘‘adequate’’ provision that differ from one public good to

    another. Such measures can, for example, correspond to
    the complete elimination of global public bads. More

    generally, they are measures of what is considered pos-

    sible, given the current state of technology (e.g., to
    control—rather than eradicate—the problem of HIV/

    AIDS) and what is ‘‘fair’’ (e.g., what would emerge if all

    concerned stakeholders had an effective voice in the
    decision-making process) (ODS-UNC 2002). The crite-

    rion of adequacy is not meant to indicate optimality—the

    balancing of marginal costs with the sum of people’s
    marginal willingness to pay for a particular public good

    (see Samuelson 1954; Cornes and Sandler 1996). Rather,

    it is meant to establish a relatively simple, yet reliable,
    yardstick for measuring the present provision of a certain

    good against a technical notion of adequacy.

    In the case of the global public good ‘communicable

    disease control’, for example, it has been possible, given
    the biological characteristics of the infectious agent and

    available technologies, to completely eradicate certain

    diseases. In these cases, the criterion for adequate provision
    is defined as complete eradication, or zero incidences in the

    ‘‘wild.’’ The determination of ‘‘adequate provision’’ is

    based solely on technical considerations, without reference
    to costs, benefits or existing preferences and willingness to

    pay. Therefore, there may be cases where adequate provi-
    sion may not be economically feasible. It is important to

    assess the net benefits/costs of inaction against the net

    benefits/costs of corrective action to determine, at least
    approximately, whether meeting the technological

    requirements for adequate provision is economically

    desirable (UNDP 2002).

    POLICY OPTION: PAYMENTS FOR ECOSYSTEM
    SERVICES

    In principle, the solution to IEPG problems of this form lies
    in payments designed to compensate local providers for the

    additional costs they incur in meeting global demand.

    Indeed, that is the basis on which the Global Environment
    Facility (GEF) was founded. The GEF unites 182 member

    governments—in partnership with international institu-

    tions, nongovernmental organizations, and the private
    sector—to address global environmental issues. An inde-

    pendent financial organization, the GEF provides grants to

    developing countries and countries with economies in
    transition for projects related to biodiversity, climate

    change, international waters, land degradation, the ozone

    layer, and persistent organic pollutants. These projects
    benefit the global environment, linking local, national, and

    global environmental challenges, and promoting sustain-

    able livelihoods. The concept of incremental cost, which
    notionally determines the payments made by the GEF, is

    related to the difference between the cost a country would

    be prepared to bear in the provision of an environmental
    public good (the cost that would be warranted in terms of

    the national benefits generated by the public good) and the

    cost of meeting global demand for the same public good
    (Pearce 2003, 2005). It is a national payment for an envi-

    ronmental service that is an IEPG.

    Systems of Payments for Ecosystem Services (PES)
    have become popular instruments for dealing with IEPGs,

    in part because they appear to satisfy the incremental cost

    principle (Ferraro and Simpson 2002; Goldstein et al. 2006;
    Wunder 2007; Ferraro and Kiss 2007; Pagiola 2008; Engel

    et al. 2008; Wunder et al. 2008). They are not, however,

    appropriate mechanisms in all cases. International PES
    schemes are appropriate where non-marketed ecosystem

    802 AMBIO (2011) 40:798–806

    123
    ! Royal Swedish Academy of Sciences 2011
    www.kva.se/en
    Author’s personal copy

    services are privately supplied in one country, but offer

    benefits that are public and accrue elsewhere.
    To illustrate the potential pluses and minuses of PES, we

    consider a particular problem: the impact of local defor-

    estation on the provision of a range of IEPGs including
    climate regulation (through carbon sequestration), protec-

    tion of genetic diversity, and watershed protection in

    addition to timber and non-timber forest products. The
    Economics of Ecosystems and Biodiversity (TEEB) study

    is a major international initiative to draw attention to the
    global economic benefits of biodiversity, to highlight the

    growing costs of biodiversity loss and ecosystem degra-

    dation, and to draw together expertise from the fields of
    science, economics and policy to enable practical actions

    moving forward. The current assessment of TEEB on PES

    has used existing studies to estimate the mean value of both
    the macroclimatic regulation offered by terrestrial carbon

    sequestration, and the change in provisioning and cultural

    services offered by forest systems. Its findings are pre-
    liminary but telling. TEEB (TEEB 2009; Kumar 2010)

    suggests that the mean values of forest ecosystem services,

    in US$/ha/year, are dominated by regulatory functions:
    specifically regulation of climate ($1965), water flows

    ($1360), and soil erosion ($694). The mean value of all

    provisioning services combined—timber and non-timber
    forest products, food, genetic information, pharmaceuti-

    cals—is $1313. This is less than the value of water flow

    regulation alone. There are substantial off-site benefits to
    forest conservation that are not currently captured by forest

    landowners and are difficult to incorporate on PES

    schemes.
    Governments around the world have frequently imple-

    mented forest protection policies in areas high in biodi-

    versity, landscape beauty or critical for their watershed
    protection. However, as pressure mounts on governments

    to curtail spending and cut budget deficits, their ability to

    invest directly in the provision of public goods and services
    is compromised. Where public authorities have been

    unable to tackle the public good problem, they have sear-

    ched for ways to involve non-governmental actors. Efforts
    to transfer responsibility for forest environmental services

    out of the public sector have relied on a combination of

    regulation and market-based approaches (Landell-Mills
    and Porras 2002). Experience has shown that well-designed

    market-based instruments can achieve environmental goals

    at less cost than conventional ‘‘command and control’’
    approaches, while creating positive incentives for continual

    innovation and improvement (Stavins 2003). Examples of

    such instruments in the forestry sector include stumpage
    value-based forest revenue systems, financial and material

    incentives, long-term forestry concessions, trade liberal-

    ization, forest certification and the promotion of markets
    for non-timber forest products.

    The costs and benefits associated with many human

    activities spill over jurisdictional boundaries, thereby
    generating externalities that are often reciprocal and

    quantitatively significant (Cornes 2008). Therefore, IEPGs

    supply depends on either international coordination or
    international cooperation. Among payment schemes to

    internalize the external benefits of maintaining intact for-

    ests, Reducing Emissions from Deforestation and Forest
    Degradation (REDD) is an effort to create a financial value

    for the carbon stored in forests, offering incentives for
    developing countries to reduce emissions from forested

    lands and invest in low-carbon paths to sustainable devel-

    opment. REDD is an example of international coordination
    in delivery of ecosystem services. Its integration into

    international market-based climate change policies poses a

    number of challenges both to institutional design and to
    implementation. At present, for example, there are few

    effective mechanisms for converting international pay-

    ments to governments into incentives to on-the-ground
    forest communities (Myers 2008; Sikor et al. 2010).

    Indeed, creating an effective multilevel system of pay-

    ments is seen as the core issue in building REDD consid-
    ering that REDD goes beyond deforestation and forest

    degradation, and includes the role of conservation, sus-

    tainable management of forest and enhancement of forest
    carbon stocks (Anngelsen and Wertz-Kanounnikoff 2008).

    It is predicted that financial flows for greenhouse gas

    emission reductions from REDD could reach up to US$30
    billion a year. This significant North–South flow of funds

    could reward a meaningful reduction of carbon emissions

    and could also support new, pro-poor development, help
    conserve biodiversity, and secure vital ecosystem services.

    A second issue is the linkage between distinct ecosystem

    services. The REDD scheme targets one important eco-
    system service: carbon sequestration. However, it has the

    potential to secure other services as well. These services

    potentially include both habitat provision for biodiversity
    conservation and watershed protection. Reaching interna-

    tional agreement on an instrument to reduce emissions

    from deforestation and forest degradation, while recog-
    nizing the co-benefits offered by conservation, and the

    sustainable management of forested watershed would both

    secure global carbon sequestration services, as well as help
    to maintain other valuable services provided by forests

    (TEEB 2009). There is growing recognition that REDD

    planning requires a broadened approach. A future REDD
    mechanism should incentivize emissions reduction from

    reduced deforestation, enhanced carbon sequestration and

    address a number of non-carbon services. Implementation
    of REDD also requires attention to the quality of forest

    governance, conservation priorities, local rights and tenure

    frameworks, and sub-national project potential (Phelps
    et al. 2010).

    AMBIO (2011) 40:798–806 803

    ! Royal Swedish Academy of Sciences 2011
    www.kva.se/en 123
    Author’s personal copy

    IMPLICATIONS FOR INTERNATIONAL
    ENVIRONMENTAL POLICY

    Globalization isoften associated withincreased privateness—

    economic liberalization is associated with the growth of the
    number of goods and services allocated through markets,

    international market integration, and enhanced private cross-

    border economic activity such as trade, investment, transport,
    travel, migration and communication.However,globalization

    is also about increased publicness—about people’s lives

    becoming more interdependent. Events in one place of the
    globe often have worldwide repercussions. Moreover, a

    growing volume of international policy principles, treaties,

    norms, laws, and standards is defining common rules for an
    ever-wider range of activities (Kaul et al. 2003b).

    Public goods are recognized as having benefits that

    cannot easily be confined to a single ‘‘buyer’’ (or set of
    ‘‘buyers’’). Yet once they are provided, many can enjoy

    them for free. A clean environment is an example. Without

    a mechanism for collective action, these goods will gen-
    erally be underprovided. In fact, many crises dominating

    the international policy agenda today reflect the under-

    provision of global public goods. With globalization,
    externalities are increasingly borne by people in other

    countries. Indeed, issues that have traditionally been

    merely national are now global because of the greater
    interconnectedness of the planet.

    Kaul et al. (2003b) suggest a rethinking of three notions
    underpinning the theory of public goods. First, properties

    of non-rivalry in consumption and non-excludability of

    current benefits do not automatically determine whether a
    good is public or private. Some goods may be either public

    or private. Nevertheless, it is important to distinguish

    between a good’s having the potential of being public (that
    is, its having non-rival and non-excludable properties) and

    its being de facto public (non-exclusive and available for

    all to consume). Second, public goods do not necessarily
    have to be provided by the state. Many other actors can,

    and increasingly do, contribute to their provision. And

    third, a growing number of public goods are no longer
    national in scope, having assumed cross-border dimen-

    sions. Many have become global and require international

    cooperation to be adequately provided.
    For the most part, the theoretical and empirical literature

    in economics has focused on two polar models of public

    goods provision: the provision of pure public goods that
    benefit all agents, and the provision of local public goods

    that only benefit agents in one community (Bloch and

    Zenginobuz 2007). We are concerned with cases where the
    members of one community enjoy positive spillovers from

    the public goods provided by other communities. In the

    context of global climate regulation, the REDD scheme
    will compensate tropical nations that succeed in reducing

    carbon emissions from deforestation and forest degrada-

    tion—source of nearly one fifth of global carbon emissions.
    Since forests offer a number of benefits aside from carbon,

    however, the scheme could potentially benefits to com-

    munities that would otherwise be unable to afford them
    (Stickler et al. 2009). If well designed and implemented,

    PES schemes such as REDD have the potential to secure

    provision of IEPGs that offer benefits at multiple scales,
    such as the protection of water supplies, local and regional

    climate regulation, and habitat provision for the protection
    of biodiversity. The effectiveness of PES schemes depends

    heavily on the conditionality of payments (Arriagada and

    Perrings 2009), but the principles for their effective design
    and implementation are well understood.

    To summarize, the implications of this paper for inter-

    national environmental policy are the following:

    1. Diagnosis of the public goods failure associated with

    particular ecosystem services is critical to the devel-

    opment of the appropriate international response.
    There are a number of cases where the incentive

    structure is such that independent actions by nation

    states will be ‘good enough’ to secure the public
    interest (Touza and Perrings 2011). Where the tech-

    nology of supply is ‘best shot’ or where the local

    benefits are high enough to lead to a level of supply
    that is close to the global optimum, then the indepen-

    dent actions of nation states will be adequate. How-

    ever, where local benefits lead to a level of local
    supply that leaves global demand unsatisfied, then

    international coordination or cooperation in the deliv-

    ery of ecosystem services will be required. We note
    that this largely depends on the nature and strength of

    off-site effects. Local actions that generate significant

    off-site benefits or costs are most likely to require
    international coordination or cooperation. Off-site

    effects can reflect both natural (through hydrological

    or atmospheric flows) and social (through trade and
    travel) transmission. Since social transmission of

    effects is rapidly evolving, understanding social trans-

    mission pathways is important to the diagnosis of the
    public goods failure.

    2. There are two categories of IEPGs that are most likely

    to be undersupplied. The first involves an additive
    supply technology, a high opportunity cost of supply

    and transmission to a large number of other countries

    through the general circulation system. Examples
    include mitigation of climate change, and management

    of transboundary nutrient flows, currently addressed

    through the UN Framework Convention on Climate
    Change and the Convention on Long Range Trans-

    boundary Air Pollution. The second involves a weakest

    link supply technology, and transmission to a large

    804 AMBIO (2011) 40:798–806

    123
    ! Royal Swedish Academy of Sciences 2011
    www.kva.se/en
    Author’s personal copy

    number of other countries through global trade,

    transport and travel. Examples include the manage-

    ment of infectious zoonotic diseases and the control of
    invasive pest species, currently addressed through the

    International Health Regulations, the Sanitary and

    Phytosanitary Agreement, and the Convention on
    Biological Diversity.

    3. If there is a public goodfailure that demands international

    coordination or cooperation, it is then important to
    determine the degree to which the collective response

    should be targeted. In principle, action should be targeted

    to reflect the weight attaching to the supply from any one
    country.So,at one extreme, international contributions to

    an IEPG with an additive supply technology that is

    unweighted (a simple sum), such as carbon sequestration
    by forest plantations, should not be targeted at all.

    Whereas international contributions to a weakest link

    international environmental public good, such as infec-
    tious disease control, should be targeted at the weakest

    link. In practice, most ecosystem services are jointly

    produced(come asa bundle),and involveanintermediate
    position. Particular countries are more important for the

    provision of some services than others (e.g., high

    biodiversity countries contribute more to the global gene
    pool than others) so most international contributions to

    IEPGs should be targeted in some measure.

    4. For IEPGs that are supplied in specific countries,
    support may take the form of direct investment in

    supply (the Global Environment Facility model) or of

    payments for the benefits of supply (the Payments for
    Ecosystem Services model). The fact that GEF is

    under-resourced, and is only weakly targeted, suggests

    that the second option may become the dominant
    mechanism for assuring local provision of IEPGs. We

    have elsewhere discussed the conditions that need to

    be satisfied for PES schemes to be effective (Arriagada
    and Perrings 2009). The most important of these is that

    payments for ecosystem services should be conditional

    on the supply of those services. Where PES schemes
    have both income transfer/poverty alleviation and

    public good supply objectives, conditionality may be

    lost altogether. It is important that the design of PES
    schemes fit the diagnosis of the public good problem,

    and the technology of public good supply.

    Acknowledgment The authors acknowledge support from the
    United Nations Environment Programme.

    REFERENCES

    Anand, P. 2004. Financing the provision of public goods. The World
    Economy 27: 215–237.

    Anngelsen, A., and S. Wertz-Kanounnikoff. 2008. What are the key
    design issues for REDD and the criteria for assessing options? In
    Moving ahead with REDD,, ed. A. Angelse. Bogor: SUBUR
    Printing.

    Arriagada, R., and C. Perrings. 2009. Making payments for ecosystem
    services work. Ecosystem services economics working papers.
    United Nations Environment Programme, Nairobi.

    Barrett, S. 2007. Why cooperate? The incentive to supply global
    public goods. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Batina, R., and T. Ihori. 2005. Public goods: Theories and evidence.
    Berlin: Springer-Verlag.

    Bloch, F., and U. Zenginobuz. 2007. The effect of spillovers on the
    provision of local public goods. Review of Economic Design 11:
    199–216.

    Cornes, R. 2008. Global public goods and commons: theoretical
    challenges for a changing world. International Tax and Public
    Finance 15: 353–359.

    Cornes, R., and T. Sandler. 1996. The theory of externalities, public
    goods, and club goods. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Dombrowsky, I. 2007. Conflict, cooperation and institutions in
    international water management: An economic analysis. Chel-
    tenham: Edward Elgar.

    Engel, S., S. Pagiola, and S. Wunder. 2008. Designing payments for
    environmental services in theory and practice: An overview of
    the issues. Ecological Economics 65: 663–674.

    Ferraro, P., and A. Kiss. 2007. Direct payments to conserve
    biodiversity. Science 298: 1718–1719.

    Ferraro, P., and R. Simpson. 2002. The cost-effectiveness of
    conservation payments. Land Economics 78: 339–353.

    Ferroni, M., and A. Mody. 2002. Global incentives for international
    public goods: Introduction and overview. In International goods
    public: Incentives, measurement, and financing,, ed. M. Ferroni,
    and A. Mody. Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic Publishers.

    Goldstein, J., G. Daily, J. Friday, P. Matson, and R. Naylor. 2006.
    Business strategies for conservation on private lands: Koa
    forestry as a case study. Proceedings of the National Academy of
    Sciences of the United States of America 103: 10140–10145.

    Hirshleifer, J. 1983. From weakest-link to best shot: The voluntary
    provision of public goods. Public Choice 41: 371–386.

    Holzinger, K. 2001. Aggregation technology of common goods and
    its strategic consequences: Global warming, biodiversity, and
    sitting conflicts. European Journal of Political Research 40:
    117–138.

    Kanbur, R. 2003. IFI’s and IPG’s: operational implications for the
    World Bank. In Challenges to the World Bank, IMF: Developing
    country perspectives,, ed. A. Buira. London: Anthem Press.

    Kanbur, R. 2004. Cross-border externalities, international public
    goods and their implications for aid agencies. In Global tensions:
    Challenges, opportunities in the World economy,, ed. L. Beneria,
    and S. Bisnath. New York: Routledge.

    Kaul, I., I. Grunberg, and M. Stern, ed. 1999. Defining global public
    goods. In Global public goods: International cooperation in the
    21st century. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Kaul, I., P. Conceição, K. Le Goulven, and R. Mendoza, ed. 2003a.
    How to improve the provision of global public goods. In
    Providing global public goods: Managing globalization. Oxford:
    Oxford University Press.

    Kaul, I., P. Conceição, K. Le Goulven, and R. Mendoza, ed. 2003b.
    Why do global public goods matter today? In Providing global
    public goods: Managing globalization. Oxford: Oxford Univer-
    sity Press.

    Kumar, P. 2010. The economics of ecosystems and biodiversity.
    London: Earthscan.

    Landell-Mills, N., and I. Porras. 2002. Silver bullet or fool’s gold? A
    global review of markets for forest environmental services and

    AMBIO (2011) 40:798–806 805

    ! Royal Swedish Academy of Sciences 2011
    www.kva.se/en 123
    Author’s personal copy

    their impact on the poor. London: International Institute for
    Environment and Development.

    Madsen, B., N. Carroll, and K. Moore. 2010. Offset and compensation
    programs worldwide. Washington: Ecosystem Marketplace.

    Millennium Ecosystem Assessment. 2005. Ecosystems and human
    well-being: General synthesis. Washington: Island Press.

    Morrissey, O., D. Te Velde, and A. Hewitt. 2002. Defining
    international public goods: conceptual issues. In International
    public goods: Incentives, measurement, financing, ed. M. Ferroni,
    and A. Mody. Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic Publishers.

    Myers, M. 2008. Policies to reduce emissions from deforestation and
    degradation (REDD) in developing countries. An examination of
    the issues facing the incorporation of REDD into market-based
    climate policies. Resources for the future. Discussion paper RFF
    DP 07-50, Washington, DC, USA.

    Ostrom, E. 1990. Governing the commons: The evolution of
    institutions for collective action. Cambridge: Cambridge Uni-
    versity Press.

    Pagiola, S. 2008. Payments for environmental services in Costa Rica.
    Ecological Economics 65: 712–724.

    Pearce, D. 2003. The social cost of carbon and its policy implications.
    Oxford Review of Economic Policy 19: 362–384.

    Pearce, D. 2005. Paradoxes in biodiversity conservation. World
    Economics 6: 57–69.

    Perrings, C., and M. Gadgil. 2003. Conserving biodiversity: Recon-
    ciling local and global public benefits. In Providing global public
    goods: Managing globalization, ed. I. Kaul, P. Conceição, K. Le
    Goulven, and R. Mendoza. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Perrings, C., M. Williamson, E. Barbier, D. Delfino, S. Dalmazzone,
    J. Shogren, P. Simmons, and A. Watkinson. 2002. Biological
    invasion risks and the public good: an economic perspective.
    Conservation Ecology 6: 1.

    Phelps, J., M. Guerrero, D. Dalabajan, B. Young, and E. Webb. 2010.
    What makes a REDD country? Global Environmental Change
    20: 322–332.

    Samuelson, P. 1954. The pure theory of public expenditure. The
    Review of Economics and Statistics 36: 387–389.

    Sandler, T. 2004. Global collective action. Cambridge: Cambridge
    University Press.

    Sikor, T., J. Stahl, T. Enters, J.C. Ribot, N. Singh, W.D. Sunderlin,
    and L. Wollenberg. 2010. REDD-plus, forest people’s rights and
    nested climate governance. Global Environmental Change 20:
    423–425.

    Stavins, R. 2003. Experience with market-based environmental policy
    instruments. In Handbook of environmental economics, ed.
    M. Karl-Goran, and R.V. Jeffrey. Amsterdam: North Holland.

    Stickler, C., D. Nepstad, M. Coe, D. Mcgrath, H. Rodriguez, W.
    Walker, B. Soares-Filho, and E. Davidson. 2009. The potential
    ecological costs and co-benefits of REDD: A critical review and
    case study from the Amazon region. Global Change Biology 15:
    2803–2824.

    TEEB. 2009. TEEB climate issues update. Nairobi: United Nations
    Environment Program.

    Touza, J., and C. Perrings. 2011. Strategic behavior and the scope for
    unilateral provision of transboundary ecosystem services that are
    international environmental public goods. Strategic Behavior
    and the Environment 1: 89–117.

    United Nations Development Programme. 2002. Profiling the provi-
    sion status of global public goods. New York: UNDP Office of
    Development Studies.

    Wunder, S. 2007. The efficiency of payments for environmental
    services in tropical conservation. Conservation Biology 21:
    48–58.

    Wunder, S., S. Engel, and S. Pagiola. 2008. Taking stock: a
    comparative analysis of payments for environmental services
    programs in developed and developing countries. Ecological
    Economics 65: 834–852.

    AUTHOR BIOGRAPHIES

    Rodrigo Arriagada (&) is a Assistant Professor in the Department
    of Agricultural Economics at the Pontificia Universidad Catolica de
    Chile. Dr. Arriagada is also an associated research fellow for Envi-
    ronment for Development (EfD) initiative in Central America and
    ecoSERVICES Group at Arizona State University. His fields of
    specialization are environmental economics, program evaluation
    econometrics, applied microeconomics and development economics.
    Dr. Arriagada’s current research interests focus on environmental
    economics and policy, the use of experimental and quasi-experi-
    mental program evaluation methods on conservation interventions,
    deforestation and land use, issues at the intersection of economic
    development and environmental protection.
    Address: Department of Agricultural Economics, Pontificia Univers-
    idad Católica de Chile, Avenida Vicuña Mackenna 4860 Macul,
    Santiago, Chile.
    e-mail: rarriagadac@uc.cl

    Charles Perrings is a Professor of Environmental Economics at
    Arizona State University (ASU). Previous appointments include
    Professor of Environmental Economics and Environmental Manage-
    ment at the University of York; Professor of Economics at the Uni-
    versity of California, Riverside; and Director of the Biodiversity
    Program of the Beijer Institute, Royal Swedish Academy of Sciences,
    Stockholm, where he is a Fellow. At ASU, he directs (with Ann
    Kinzig) the ecoSERVICES Group within the College of Liberal Arts
    and Sciences. The Group studies the causes and consequences of
    change in ecosystem services—the benefits that people derive from
    the biophysical environment. It analyses biodiversity change in terms
    of its impacts on the things that people care about.
    Address: ecoSERVICES Group, School of Life Sciences, Arizona
    State University, Box 874501, Tempe, AZ 85287-4501, USA.
    e-mail: Charles.perrings@asu.edu

    806 AMBIO (2011) 40:798–806

    123
    ! Royal Swedish Academy of Sciences 2011
    www.kva.se/en
    Author’s personal copy

      Paying for International Environmental Public Goods
      Abstract
      Introduction
      Why are International Environmental Public Goods Underprovided?
      Policy Option: Payments for Ecosystem Services
      Implications for International Environmental Policy
      Acknowledgment
      References

    1

    Economic Incentives and Wildlife Conservation

    Erwin H. Bult

    e

    Department of Economics
    Tilburg University, The Netherlands

    G. Cornelis van Kooten
    Department of Economics
    University of Victoria, Canada

    Timothy Swanson
    Department of Economics
    University of London, United Kingdom

    Draft: October 27, 200

    3

    ________________________________________________________________________

    Wildlife exploitation and conservation involves various costs and benefits, which
    should all be taken into account to achieve an optimal outcome. For this to occur, it will
    be necessary to develop appropriate economic instruments and incentives. Examining the
    scope for his is the topic of the current study. The time and funds available to complete
    this paper were extremely limited, which effectively made it impossible to complete a
    thorough and detailed analysis. As a result, in the paper we focus on what can be learne

    d

    from standard economics. The paper lacks the level of detail and data to provide
    guidance in many operational issues.

    Wildlife management poses a particular challenge to the global community
    because wildlife has an impact not only on people living in areas where wildlife is found,
    but also on people located considerable distances away. The problem is that the costs and
    benefits of wildlife exploitation facing “source” states differ substantially from those
    faced by other countries. From an economist’s perspective, the main wildlife problem is
    that all too often many of the costs of harvesting wildlife are not appropriately taken into
    account. In particular, the values that wildlife such as elephants, tigers and rhinoceros
    have for people who may someday view them in the wild and the values that such fauna
    have for people who are simply delighted to know that such wildlife exist (having no
    intention of ever viewing them) are ignored in most harvesting decisions. Further, when
    property rights are insecure, those who harvest wildlife do not take into account the cost
    of their actions on the future availability of the resource because they do not have a stake
    in wildlife beyond those accessible to them today. This cost is referred to as the “user
    cost” and it is typically ignored in harvest decisions unless property rights are clearly
    stated, and protected. As a result, in situ wildlife is undervalued leading to their possible
    overexploitation (see below).

    2

    In essence, there is a divergence between what is optimal from a regional,
    community or individual perspective, and what is optimal from the perspective of a
    country or even global society. To address this divergence, a variety of economi

    c

    instruments can be employed. The term “economic instrument” is used to describe any
    device/method used by government to achieve an outcome contrary to (other than) the
    one that occurs in the absence of any government intervention. The government
    essentially has three categories of economic instruments available to it: (1) common
    values and norms (threats or moral suasion in economic terms), (2) command and
    control, and (3) market incentives, which are also referred to as economic incentives
    (EIs). Moral suasion refers to the ability of the state to convince economic agents
    (individuals or firms) to act in a fashion that is socially desirable. Voluntary instruments
    (e.g., product certification/labeling by an industry association), perhaps accompanied by
    threats, are one aspect, but there also exist opportunities to “convince” citizens to report
    poachers, protect wildlife habitat and so on. Economic or market incentives and
    command and control (i.e., regulation) are generally used in combination, often out o

    f

    necessity.

    The objective of this study is to examine the scope of economic incentives in the
    conservation of wildlife. The focus of the study is on developing countries as these host
    most of the biodiversity and wildlife. The main results are as follows: While economists
    often believe that, in general, the best way to conserve wildlife and their habitat is to
    encourage efficient and sustainable use of these resources, the scope of EIs in such
    conservation efforts as an ‘extra measure’ to regulate harvesting pressure may in some
    cases be limited. Specifically, we argue that there are cases where the usual gains of EIs
    may be of secondary importance. Whether or not such gains materialize depends on the
    specific characteristics of a species and the parties involved in its harvesting. This should
    be assessed on a case-by-case basis. If both the habitat and the harvesters are
    “homogenous” (in the sense that there is little variation in the area in which the species is
    harvested and the skills/technologies of those harvesting the species), then the gains from
    EIs are small. These conditions may hold for (low-tech) open-access harvesting of certain
    species in Africa, but not for fisheries where “firms” of various sizes from individuals to
    large corporately-sponsored vessels are engaged in harvesting.

    Two important qualifications are in order. First, while the role of EIs in regulation
    of harvesting may (but need not) be modest, we argue that international EIs may be of
    great importance when it comes to habitat conservation (indirectly contributing to
    wildlife conservation). In this respect we mainly think of means to capture and channel
    non-use values associated with conservation to affected parties living with (or owning)
    wildlife in developing countries – an example of international transfers or subsidies.
    Second, establishing property rights (or secure use rights for extended periods – that is
    establishing property rights in legal or physical space) is consistently encouraged by
    economists as a first step towards efficient management of resources – both of land and
    the wildlife it supports. Whether this first step must be complemented by additional EIs
    (tax, tradable quota) to arrive at a truly global optimum, however, is not certain.
    Sometimes additional command and control measures are to be preferred, and sometimes
    no additional measures are necessary (for example when external effects are small – see
    the next section).

    3

    We begin by examining why society might wish to intervene in the protection and
    provision of wildlife – the economic theory underpinning public wildlife management. In
    section 2, we provide a general discussion of the types of EIs that are available for
    addressing environmental spillovers, focusing on those instruments that may be useful in
    wildlife management. In section 3 we compare the performance of EIs with that of
    command and control instruments when addressing the two most important threats to
    wildlife; overexploitation and habitat conversion. In section 4 we emphasize the
    importance of the institutional context, and discuss implications for developing countries.
    Section 5 summarizes and concludes, and we propose a few priorities for targeted follow-
    up research that can be useful for making progress towards implementation of key issues
    raised in the paper.

    1. ECONOMIC EFFICIENCY AND VARIOUS FAILURES

    Environmental economics has become an important subject within economics as
    people have become increasingly concerned with pollution and other forms of
    environmental damage. The fact that some wild fauna and flora is threatened and
    endangered can be considered a special form of environmental damage. Therefore, ideas
    from environmental economics are relevant to wildlife management. What then does
    economic efficiency mean in a wildlife context? We consider ‘wildlife’ as broadly as
    possible, encompassing all biotic resources, including timber and fish.

    First off, economic efficiency refers to the maximization of the well-being or
    welfare of citizens within a society. Economists measure welfare using a monetary metric
    and define it in terms of the economic surpluses (or rents) that accrue to economic agents
    in their capacities as consumers and producers. The surplus accruing to consumers is
    given by the difference between the benefit that they get from consuming a bundle of
    goods and services and what they have to pay for those goods and services. In technical
    terms, the “consumer surplus” is the difference between what people are willing to pay
    for goods and services and what they actually do pay. Likewise, the “producer surplus” is
    defined as the difference between the revenues from the sale of goods and services and
    the cost of providing them. Since fixed costs are sunk (i.e., made in the past and
    unaffected by current decisions), the net benefit accruing to economic agents as owners
    of factors of production is given as the difference between total revenue and total variable
    costs. In essence, therefore, the total surplus or economic welfare at any time is given by
    the difference between the benefit that citizens receive as “consumers” and the costs of
    providing the goods and services consumed – the area between the demand and supply
    curves (Figure 1).

    To maximize society’s overall well being when producing a good, an additional
    unit of the good should be provided as long as the benefit from this additional unit (the
    marginal benefit), to whomsoever they accrue, exceed the cost of this additional unit (the
    marginal cost), no matter who incurs them. Provision should stop when the benefit
    received from the last unit equals the cost of supplying that unit – marginal costs equal
    marginal benefits. Marginal benefits (or marginal willingness to pay) define the demand
    function, and marginal costs determine the supply function (Figure 1). Then society’s

    4

    welfare is maximized at the price and quantity where demand intersects supply – where
    marginal benefit (demand price) equals marginal cost (supply price). The area between a
    falling demand function and a rising supply function, up to the point where they intersect,
    represents the maximum sum of the consumer and producer surpluses, or maximum
    societal welfare, as shown in Figure 1. However, environmental problems arise because
    of three sorts of failure: institutional failure, market failure and policy failure. These
    forms of failure are clearly interdependent. For example, property rights to resources may
    be insecure (institutional failure) because governments fail to provide the legal
    environment that supports them (policy failure) or because of public good characteristics
    associated with the resource (market failure). One result of imperfect property rights can
    be external effects (another form of market failure). We will explain these concepts
    below.

    Quantity per unit time

    Price ($ per unit)

    Supply = marginal cost

    Demand = marginal benefit

    Consumer
    Surplus

    Producer
    Surplus

    0

    price =
    marginal
    cost

    Q*

    P*

    Quantity per unit time
    Price ($ per unit)
    Supply = marginal cost
    Demand = marginal benefit
    Consumer
    Surplus
    Producer
    Surplus
    0
    price =
    marginal
    cost
    Q*
    P*

    Figure 1: Maximizing Social Welfare when there is No Market Failure

    1.1 Institutional failure: Ill-defined and enforced property rights

    First, consider the pervasive problem of institutional failure. The most relevant
    manifestation of institutional failure for the case of wildlife and trade in species is
    probably insecure property rights, or ‘open access’ to resources – both the species
    themselves and the land upon which they live. Property rights can be understood as
    characteristics that define the rights and duties associated with the use of a particular
    asset or resource. Four property regimes are usually identified.

    5

    1. Private property In this case, the private owner has the right to utilize and benefit
    from the exploitation, conservation or sale of wildlife, as long as no (socially
    unacceptable) externalities are imposed on others (e.g., when shooting wildlife endangers
    the lives of others). Private ownership does not imply absence of state regulation
    (control), as private property cannot exist without state sanction and protection.

    2. State property The state owns the wildlife and individuals may be allowed to
    harvest them, but only according to rules imposed by the state or the CITES Management
    Authority.

    3. Common property In this case, a group owns and manages the wildlife resource,
    and the group excludes those who are not members. Members of the group have specified
    rights and duties, while non-members must accept exclusion. Coordination (regulation) of
    management may or may not be forthcoming, depending on local circumstances.

    4. No property rights (res nullius) When a property right is not assigned, open or
    free access is the result. Under open-access, each potential user of the resource has
    complete autonomy to utilize wildlife since none has the legal right to keep another
    potential user out.

    A summary is provided in Table 1. In practice, resources are often held in
    overlapping combinations of these regimes, and it is possible to shift from one
    (dominant) regime to another when conditions change. Failure to enforce or manage
    properly a state or common property resource (which is frequent) leads to open-access,
    which is the case for some endangered large-game species. The switch from common and
    state regimes to open-access as a result of population growth is well documented (Murty
    1994; Bromley 1999).

    Table 1: Classification and Characteristics of Property Rights
    Type Characteristics Implications for economic incentives

    Private property Exclusive rights assigned toindividuals
    Strong incentives for conservation of
    resources and for investment as well

    State property
    Rights held in collectivity with
    control exercised by CITES
    authority or designated agency

    Creating opportunities for attenuation of
    rights; managers have incentives for personal
    gains

    Common property

    Exclusive rights assigned to all
    members of a community;
    approaching private property
    when coordination arises.

    Creating free-riders problem and low
    incentives for conservation

    Open access Rights unassigned; lack ofexclusivity
    Lack of incentives to conserve; often resultin

    g

    in resource degradation

    6

    Property rights do not really exist under open access, and if there is no
    cooperation under communal ownership (or no enforcement under state and private
    ownership), then property rights are insecure. The absence of secure property rights (or
    even open-access) has resulted in excessive depletion of resources and biological assets
    for the following reason. The true cost of exploiting a resource consists of two distinct
    components: the private extraction costs and the unobserved opportunity cost, or the
    value of the resource in situ – the user cost. The intuition behind user cost in the context
    of a renewable resource is as follows: harvesting a unit of the resource today means that
    this unit and the growth (including any offspring) it causes are not available for future
    consumption. The (future) value of uncaught game depends on many different factors,
    including the discount rate, future markets for the resource, technological developments,
    reproductive features and so on. A sole private owner aiming to maximize profits will
    maximize the discounted value of this rent, and treat the resource as an asset. Hence, the
    value of unharvested animals and plants prevents a rational wildlife manager from over
    harvesting the resource, but only as long as she expects to be the one to benefit from this
    “investment”. Private property may result in a conservative harvesting policy. In the
    absence of externalities and given similar discount rates, the same applies for state
    ownership.

    An open-access resource exists if there is no possibility to exclude firms attracted
    by excess profits, with their entry competing away those profits. If there is unrestricted
    access to the resource, no person can be sure of who will benefit from the value of
    uncaught game. In an open-access situation, no individual harvester has an economic
    incentive to conserve the wildlife, and none can efficiently conserve the wildlife by
    delaying harvest. Doing so will only enhance the harvest opportunities of competitors,
    which is the tragedy of open-access. One might say that the individual does not care about
    escaped game, and discounts future harvests at an infinite rate (Neher 1990). New
    harvesters will be attracted to the activity, or existing ones will expand their efforts so long
    as they earn more than the (opportunity) cost of their effort. In bionomic equilibrium, all
    rent is dissipated, and total cost equals total revenue, rather than marginal cost being equal
    to marginal benefit. The situation where marginal cost exceeds marginal benefit is usually
    referred to as economic overexploitation.

    In terms of Figure 1, failure to account for the user cost implies that agents will not
    base their harvest decisions on the supply (social marginal cost) curve as drawn, but instead
    on another marginal cost curve that is below it. This is illustrated in Figure 2 (discussed
    further below). As a consequence, harvested quantities in the short run will increase and
    prices will fall.

    1.2 Market failure: Spillover effects and public goods

    Two general types of market failure may occur and undermine economic
    efficiency of resource management, even when property rights are secure. First, the
    supply function may not embody all of the costs of producing goods and services, in
    which case market prices are no longer reliable as a measure of value. In the context of
    wildlife conservation we may think of nonuse values associated with in situ conservation

    7

    – the utility (or well being) that people derive from knowing that certain species exist or
    thrive, even though they will never “use” or view such species themselves.

    One can think of wildlife as providing two sorts of products – products that result
    in the “consumption” of the specimen (e.g. fiber, wool, caviar, timber, ivory, bones, gall
    bladders, hides and bush meat, live export to zoos or as pets, ornamental and medicinal
    plants), and non-consumptive uses like eco-tourism, bird-watching and photography
    associated with the protection of in situ amenities and wildlife. A negative external effect
    can occur when consumptive use of wildlife reduces their numbers, and, as a wildlife
    population declines, the total economic (in situ) value to “preservers” falls. However, the
    consumers of wildlife products fail to take this into account in their decisions because
    there do not exist appropriate economic institutions and incentives to get “consumers” of
    wildlife to regard the costs they impose on those deriving utility from conservation. This
    is referred to as an externality, although the term spillover may be more descriptive of
    what happens and will be used here interchangeably with externality. Externalities can be
    good or bad, but their effect is that the supply price no longer reflects the true cost to
    (global) society of the activity. There is a divergence between private and social costs of
    provision, because one of the inputs in production, namely the environment, is not
    appropriately priced; the environmental cost or damage is not taken into account. In terms
    of Figure 2, agents do not base harvesting decisions on the marginal social cost (the ‘true’
    supply curve), but on private marginal costs. When uncorrected, they will supply too
    much and social marginal cost lies above marginal benefit.

    Second, there are many situations where private provision of a good or service
    does not occur because, once it is provided, no one can be excluded, and “use” or
    “consumption” by one person does not diminish the amount available to others. This is
    the definition of a public good. Public goods such as national defense, clean air and
    water, wilderness, biodiversity, and other environmental amenities will not be supplied
    privately because the provider cannot capture the benefits of so doing – once provided,
    no one can be excluded, so free riding is possible. Clearly some aspects of wildlife bear
    the characteristics of a public good. Wildlife contributes to global biodiversity (the “web
    of life”) and enhances the well being of the majority of people (through the provision of
    “non-use values”). However, no one has the appropriate incentive to provide wildlife
    habitat or otherwise protect wildlife as they cannot capture the full benefits from the
    needed investments. Market failure occurs because the amount of a public good is under-
    provided, and thus marginal social benefits exceed marginal social costs. In this case,
    more of the (public) good should be provided, but it is forthcoming only if society
    subsidizes a private supplier, or provides it publicly.

    1.3 Policy failure: Perverse government incentives

    A final reason why wildlife may be overharvested (or why their habitat is
    degraded in many regions) has to do with perverse government policies. One well-known
    form of policy failure is subsidization of harvesting or habitat conversion. As will
    become clear below, one way to address market failure is through implementation of a
    tax or user charge. However, rather than charging users to exploit natural resources, there
    are many real-world examples where exploitation of natural resources is encouraged

    8

    rather that restricted – policies aggravate rather than mitigate pre-existing distortions.
    When use of resources is subsidized, the marginal cost curve is pushed downwards and
    short-term supply expanded. This could be illustrated in Figure 2 (but is not) by adding
    another marginal cost function that would lie below the ‘marginal private harvest cost
    function with insecure property rights’.

    Marginal private benefit
    from wildlife harvest

    Harvests in a given period (h)

    $

    0

    PS

    h*

    P*

    Marginal private harvest
    costs with insecure property rights
    (no user cost) and no spillovers

    hS

    Marginal private harvest
    costs with secure property
    rights (no spillovers)

    Marginal social costs = marginal
    private harvest costs + user costs
    + spillover costs

    h1

    a
    b

    c
    e
    f
    g
    Marginal private benefit
    from wildlife harvest
    Harvests in a given period (h)
    $
    0
    PS
    h*
    P*
    Marginal private harvest
    costs with insecure property rights
    (no user cost) and no spillovers
    hS
    Marginal private harvest
    costs with secure property
    rights (no spillovers)
    Marginal social costs = marginal
    private harvest costs + user costs
    + spillover costs
    h1
    a
    b
    c
    e
    f
    g
    d
    Marginal private benefit
    from wildlife harvest
    Harvests in a given period (h)
    $
    0
    PS
    h*
    P*
    Marginal private harvest
    costs with insecure property rights
    (no user cost) and no spillovers
    hS
    Marginal private harvest
    costs with secure property
    rights (no spillovers)
    Marginal social costs = marginal
    private harvest costs + user costs
    + spillover costs
    h1
    a
    b
    c
    e
    f
    g
    Marginal private benefit
    from wildlife harvest
    Harvests in a given period (h)
    $
    0
    PS
    h*
    P*
    Marginal private harvest
    costs with insecure property rights
    (no user cost) and no spillovers
    hS
    Marginal private harvest
    costs with secure property
    rights (no spillovers)
    Marginal social costs = marginal
    private harvest costs + user costs
    + spillover costs
    h1
    a
    b
    c
    e
    f
    g
    d

    Figure 2: Divergence of Social and Marginal Costs of Harvesting

    1.4 Policy and land-use decisions

    Figures 1 and 2 suggest that some harvesting of wildlife is typically optimal in the
    sense that it maximizes welfare for society at large – this is the case when the marginal
    social cost curve and the demand curve intersect for some positive harvest level h*. But
    there is more. Economists have long known that allowing profitable use of resources
    provides incentives for their conservation, and could lower enforcement costs associated
    with conservation.

    Prins et al. (2002) argue that arbitrary restrictions on use of wildlife in regions in
    Africa have contributed to the demise of these species – a rather paradoxical statement

    9

    perhaps. The reason is that restrictions on use erode the incentive that people have to
    invest in the protection of the species for potential future harvesting. People have no
    incentive to invest in the conservation of the species. The result will be that base
    resources on which wildlife depend for their survival (such as land) will be allocated to
    other, more profitable uses. The key insight is that taking away the short-term incentive
    to harvest may not be in the species’ best interests. In effect, this is another manifestation
    of policy failure.

    Local people make the decisions concerning land use and resource exploitation. It
    is costly to enforce prohibitions against their chosen activities, and so prohibitions often
    increase monitoring cost without conservation benefits. This is because the conversion of
    reserve lands and incursions for wildlife poaching halt when local people want it to do so,
    not when they are told to do so. The least costly policies provide incentives for the local
    people to support the reserve’s designated uses, not bans against non-designated uses.
    This implies that the most successful policies for the conservation of wildlife and
    wildlands have been those that encourage their limited and managed development. For a
    review of experiences in the context of crocodile management, roughly consistent with
    this insight, refer to Hutton et al (2001).

    The allowance of restricted use of wildlife encourages the local community to
    view the wildlife as an asset for development. The allowance of restricted uses of reserve
    lands allows the local people to receive some use of the lands while affording other uses
    to the wildlife. In any event it is necessary for the benefits of wildlife conservation to be
    distributed across the local community, by means of benefit sharing policies. This might
    also take the form of sharing tourism revenues from the reserve with locals, or the
    maintenance of a certain share of the jobs in the reserve for locals. The locals must be
    encouraged by such policies to view the designation of the reserve for wildlife uses as a
    specific form of local development policy for their benefit, not as a constraint on their
    development of the reserved lands.

    In the context of lands that are heavily used by local peoples, the designation of
    protected areas and reserves simply acted as a mechanism for generating hostility
    amongst the local populations. This hostility then became translated into management
    costliness, as park managers attempted to enforce the restrictions on the use of the lands.
    When local peoples viewed these restrictions with hostility, they simply made even
    greater efforts to make use of lands that they believed to be theirs. Park managers had a
    near impossible job of enforcement, and always insufficient funding to accomplish it.

    An important caveat is in order here. There are exceptions to the statement that
    use restrictions should not be too stringent. In certain cases zero use is economically
    optimal. This is the case, for example, when full internalization of costs (including
    spillover cost) would lead the market to break down – that is; the relevant supply curve
    would lay above the demand curve such that there is no intersection where h*>0. In that
    case, assuming there is no pressure for habitat conversion, strict preservation (possibly
    supported through a trade ban) is globally optimal. Alternatively, strict preservation may
    also be optimal when values derived from using the resource conflict with non-use
    values. Economists typically assume that non-use values are associated with the size of

    10

    the wild stock, but recent research suggests that there may also be direct disutility
    following from uses that are harmful to individual animals. For example, people may
    care about the fact that individual whales are shot, rather than care about the fact that the
    whale population becomes a bit smaller as a result. When direct disutility is sufficiently
    large, global welfare is maximized by refraining from use altogether. Swanson and
    Kontoleon (2003) have established that this condition holds for the black rhino, where
    intrusive uses include trophy hunting and seducing rhinos to remove their horn. However,
    the earlier statement about benefits sharing still applies in this context: If non-use values
    are large, they should be captured (through transfer payments from the North, say) and
    channeled to those who bear the burden of living with the wildlife. In the absence of such
    transfers, advocating zero use may simply be non-sustainable.

    1.5 Summary

    Economics prescribes that wildlife should be harvested as long as the marginal
    social benefits of so doing exceed the marginal social costs. Included in (marginal)
    benefits are values of wildlife products (e.g., caviar, medicinal plants, ivory, bush meat,
    hides) or the live specimen (if sold to a zoo or herbarium). In addition, (marginal) social
    costs include (i) the loss in situ (existence, viewing) value that wildlife provide citizens
    who may be located in countries other than the source country, (ii) the opportunity cost
    from harvesting the wildlife today rather than waiting for a more opportune time in the
    future when the specimen(s) may fetch a higher price, (iii) the lost future value of
    offspring that might result from leaving the specimen(s) in place, and (iv) the opportunity
    cost of the resources employed in the harvest activity. This is illustrated in Figure 2,
    where failure to include all costs and benefits leads to suboptimal levels of harvest, hS,
    that are likely well above those desired by global society, h*. The loss to global society
    from harvesting hs rather than h* is area deg in Figure 2.

    We can compare outcomes relative to the suboptimal level of harvest hs (and even
    higher harvests if harvest subsidies are in place). If property rights to wildlife (and
    habitat) are clearly spelled out and protected by the courts, then the harvest level would
    fall to h1. In that case, global benefits would increase by area abfg in Figure 2. If in
    addition it is possible to pay wildlife owners for the nonuse benefits of in situ wildlife,
    harvest levels would decline further to h*, the globally optimal level of harvest. In that
    case, global well-being would increase by an additional amount given by area bcef in
    Figure 2. Our contention based on previous research concerning marginal willingness to
    pay for increased numbers of wildlife and minimum viable populations required for
    preservation of the species (e.g., see van Kooten and Bulte 2000) is that area abfg is
    larger than bcef – that the benefits for wildlife protection of specifying and protecting
    property rights is greater than those from attempting to subsidize “owners” of wildlife for
    protecting in situ numbers. Indeed, without appropriate protection of property rights,
    transfer payments to protect in situ wildlife cannot even be attempted. This is discussed
    further below.

    11

    2. WILDLIFE AND ECONOMIC INSTRUMENTS

    In this section, we examine the various economic instruments that are available to
    countries, and discuss their advantages and disadvantages. As noted in the introductory
    section, economists generally identify three economic instruments for addressing market
    failure due to environmental externalities (or spillovers): (1) command and control
    (hereafter C&C), (2) common values and norms (or more cryptically moral suasion), and
    (3) market incentives. Conceptually, common values and norms are intermediary between
    the “extremes” of the market and C&C (Loasby 1990; Stavins 2002). Common values
    and norms develop more easily in a homogeneous society, while markets are more
    appropriate in a heterogeneous society (CPB 1997, pp.42-44). However, there is much
    confusion about the different instruments that are available and which are preferred (see,
    e.g., Richards 2000).

    One way to classify economic instruments for resolving environmental spillovers
    and user cost is illustrated in Table 2, where instruments are classified according to two
    dimensions – whether control of the means used to address the externality resides with
    the private party or with the state, and who bears the costs. Market incentives include
    subsidies, contracts, taxes and rights trading. (Rights are defined as an entitlement,
    whether to a harvest quota of a wildlife species or fish stock, or the ability to develop or
    conduct other activities on land, such as plowing or harvesting before a certain date.)
    These give private parties complete discretion over the actions taken.

    In contrast, C&C regulations generally provide much less discretion. As will
    become clear below, this will lead to inefficiencies in the context of asymmetric
    information between agent and regulator. At one extreme, regulations may specify
    technology-based standards that regulated firms must use or, in the case of wildlife
    perhaps, prescribe management standards – the “party-on-the-ground” (individual, firm,
    wildlife management agency) has no degrees of freedom in decision-making.
    Alternatively, regulations could provide the party-on-the-ground some degree of freedom
    on how to proceed, as would be the case if the regulation only specified the number of
    specimens that can be harvested each period (a quota of h* in Figure 2, say). The
    regulator or CITES authority could then employ a market instrument (e.g., tradable
    quota) to allocate the harvest in an efficient manner. In either case, the cost is borne by
    the private party.

    Table 2: Classification of Instruments for Addressing Wildlife Conservation
    Private Party ControlWho Bears the

    Costs? Price Based Quantity Based
    Government

    Control

    Government/
    Society

    Subsidies,
    transfers

    Grandfathered (tradable) quota
    Contracts

    Public provision

    Private Party Taxes, fees,charges, tariffs
    Auctioned (tradable) quota C&C regulation

    Harvest quota

    12

    The instruments included in Table 2 do not exhaust the full range of instruments for
    environmental protection. For example, the literature contains discussions of liability
    systems, and bond-and-deposit systems. However, neither of these types is likely to be
    important for the case of wildlife conservation, and they will therefore be ignored in what
    follows. We will focus on the most important economic instruments in the context of the
    protection of wildlife – taxes/charges and tradable quota or rights. In addition, we consider
    physical property rights, since tradable quota constitutes a legal right. Before we turn to a
    discussion of these EIs, however, we will briefly evaluate the subsidy instrument.

    Economists are typically critical about the use of subsidies to achieve conservation.
    Consider the case where harvesters are subsidized to lower their harvest rate (this is the
    logical counterpart of the literature on subsidies and pollution, where firms are paid to
    lower their emissions). Assuming such agreements can be enforced, subsidies would
    “work” in the sense that they tend to lower the optimal harvesting level of individual
    harvesters. But there is a large potential problem with such subsidies when property rights
    to the resource are imperfect: they can encourage entry into the harvesting sector that the
    government aims to control. That is, even though harvesting per harvester goes down, the
    number of harvesters will likely go up, compromising conservation objectives. Unless the
    number of harvesters is somehow fixed such that new entry does not occur (e.g., when
    property rights are secure), subsidies are a poor instrument to regulate harvesting. But,
    importantly, there is another issue to consider in this context. In addition to suffering from
    excess harvesting, many wildlife species are threatened by habitat conversion. Subsidies
    can be an efficient, effective and equitable instrument to deal with habitat conversion. By
    basing transfer flows on habitat made available by landowners, habitat conversion (and,
    thus, indirectly also wildlife conservation) will be promoted. The fact that “entry” in the
    habitat sector is promoted by subsidies is, of course, no problem – quite to the contrary; this
    is the main intention. We return to this in section 3.3.

    Following Panayotou (1994), we distinguish between property rights in physical
    space (land ownership, ownership of wild fauna and flora on one’s land) and property
    rights in legal space (e.g., a right to hunt or collect one or more specimens, trade live
    specimens or parts or derivatives of them). The latter right specifies a narrower “bundle of
    rights” to the resource than the former. Many species are migratory, so it is not possible to
    establish full property rights (i.e., rights in physical space) as access will be shared with
    others. But rights can still be established in legal space by defining an allowable harvest
    level for individuals when the migratory species is on their land. Note that, when property
    rights are established in legal space, the regulator can set the quota by taking external
    effects into account. In contrast, if a private agent has the property rights to the resource in
    physical space, the agent will fail to take these effects into account. When such spillovers
    are important, assignment of property rights in physical space should be complemented
    with other instruments in Table 2.

    Establishing and enforcing property rights to resources in physical space can
    provide an important impetus for sustainable use and conservation. In Figure 2, a private
    agent given the right to a resource will change harvests from hS to h1, still below the
    optimal harvest level h*, but movement is in the “right” direction. Other instruments are
    needed to move from h1 to h*. Whether or not the change from h1 to h* can be

    13

    accomplished via EIs is debatable, but it may also be the case that the “effort” required to
    go from from h1 to h* is not worth making: By appropriate specification of property rights
    in physical space, most of the spillover problem may be overcome and the species spared
    from potential extinction. Property rights depend on cultural conditions, so it may be better
    in some sense to allocate them to a well-defined group or community rather than private
    individuals/firms (see Table 1 and the excellent book by Baland and Platteau 1996).

    The existence of property rights and the associated ‘right’ to exclude others from
    using the resource implies that the user cost will no longer be ignored by those with access
    to the resource. When property rights are secure, owners know that the fruits of their
    ‘investments’ (such as refraining from current harvesting, or postponing the decision to
    convert habitat) will accrue to them. This means that they are more inclined to make such
    investments. Addressing this institutional failure therefore enhances efficiency, and
    comprises an important first step in enhancing efficiency and sustainability of resource
    management. This is illustrated in the following case study, which illustrates the benefits of
    defining property rights in legal space, and of benefits sharing.

    2.1 Establishing secure property or use rights – The CAMPFIRE case study

    In Southern Africa there was a widespread problem of poaching in designated
    parks and reserves until government officials began to institute benefit-sharing programs.
    These programs have taken many different forms. Sometimes they simply allow the local
    community to set up tourist related facilities within the park (Natal’s Good Neighbour
    Policy), other times they give the local community a share in the value of wildlife that
    wanders onto their neighbouring lands (Zimbabwe’s CAMPFIRE program), and
    sometimes the community is allotted a share of the receipts from wildlife management on
    reserve lands (Wildlife Management Trusts). It is important to note how these community
    funds were channeled back to the community in a manner that is widely visible
    throughout the community. Sometimes this can be accomplished by means of purchasing
    community goods such as schools etc. Other times it is best to send the benefits back to
    the individuals in the form of jobs or money.

    Zimbabwe’s approach of sustainable wildlife utilization has now been extended to all
    of the communal areas by the CAMPFIRE program. Communities have been granted the
    rights to manage as well as the means to capture the benefits from wildlife use. Since its
    introduction, CAMPFIRE has managed to promote cooperation among village members and
    has enhanced the institutional capacity of other community programs.

    During the colonial times and up to 1978, legislation in Zimbabwe prohibited all
    utilisation of wildlife for commercial as well as traditional hunting. Locals were even
    relocated to make way for National Parks. As a result, many communities have been
    disenfranchised from their natural resources and wildlife became not only valueless, but a
    symbol of oppression and its destruction was encouraged. This alienation of people from
    wildlife was clearly unsustainable. In 1955, the Department of National Parks and Wildlife
    Management allowed commercial, (mainly white) farmers to utilize their wildlife
    commercially. Consequently, farmers began to benefit from wildlife and started to look after
    it. The value of wildlife products combined with the marginal economic viability of

    14

    conventional agriculture induced a shift from livestock to natural ecosystems
    accommodating a wide range of species. While cattle could only be sold for meat, wildlife
    could be photographed, sold as hunting trophies, as well as being sold as meat. At present,
    some 75 percent of Zimbabwe’s commercial ranches now participate in the wildlife industry.

    The first attempt to extend this system to communal areas was a program called
    WINDFALL. The program involved allocating revenues from wildlife culling in National
    Park and from safari hunting to district councils, but overall wildlife management remained
    with the State. The results of this program were disappointing since the councils kept all the
    money and local people saw few benefits. In 1975, a further step was taken which granted
    councils the same rights as private landholders to appropriate the value from wildlife. In
    order to increase the accountability of the councils the CAMPFIRE program was
    established. The program ensured that producer communities rather than councils, managed
    and benefited from wildlife.

    Consider the impact of CAMPFIRE at the local level. Chikwarakwara is a small
    village. Its population is exceedingly poor, largely uneducated and aging, since many of the
    young people have migrated out of the area in search of work. As with many other villages,
    disenfranchisement from its resource resulted in open access and over exploitation of their
    wild resources. Chikwarakwara was characterised by an erosion of traditional controls on
    resource use, growing population pressure, open access resources and unsustainable
    resource use.

    In 1989, there was a major step towards the implementation of CAMPFIRE
    principles including the appropriation of wildlife revenues by the villagers. In the process,
    special care was taken to ensure that villagers related the revenues they received to the
    actual value of wildlife in their area. Moreover, the revenues were allocated to individuals
    rather than to the community as a whole. This not only helped to increase the perception of
    important individual revenues to be gained from wildlife management, but also boosted
    accountability of the project.

    As a result of this approach, more positive attitudes were fostered towards wildlife
    and towards the management of the wildlife revenues. Villagers were able to carry out better
    resource trade-offs and gained self-esteem. New institutions were created including wildlife
    committees to ensure accountability and transparency. With stronger community unity, a
    number of new opportunities began to open. Snaring was reduced as informal social controls
    were established and strengthened. Entrepreneurial skills learned in wildlife management
    were transferable to other projects such as the expansion of the irrigation system and the
    management of the grinding mill.

    To control levels of wildlife use, each council develops a sustainable hunting quota
    in collaboration with the state departments. Middle agents who have the capital and skills
    are employed to attract international clients. In order to avoid excessive monopoly power
    and appropriation of the wildlife rents by the middle agents, a system of tenders was
    established. Through time, the communities have improved their marketing skills, managing
    to double their incomes between 1989-93. In fact, they have managed to capture better
    prices than the government in key safari areas in Zimbabwe. The program has shown that

    15

    communities have rapidly learnt the necessary skills for natural resource management
    despite the limited capacity of the state to provide technical assistance. In fact, districts with
    donor support tended to be slower to develop and have suffered from excessive overhead
    costs.

    The philosophy of CAMPFIRE has been to set initially the conditions right for
    sustainable wildlife management by local communities. The communities have started to
    cooperate and build institutions for management of resources. A key insight is that allowing
    use by well-defined groups (akin to establishing property rights) may go a long way towards
    achieving efficiency. However, to arrive at the optimal outcome property or use rights will
    generally have to be complemented with additional policies. As will become clear below,
    economists usually prefer economic incentives in this case.

    2.2 Preference for economic incentives

    Economists generally express a preference for private party control, or market
    incentives. A common feature of such incentives is that the market allocates resources,
    with the role of the government or regulator restricted to providing the legal and
    institutional framework, rather than interfering with the conduct of business itself, as is
    often the case in C&C approaches. Economic or market incentives consist primarily of
    taxes (or charges) and tradable rights.1 Before taxes can be levied or (tradable) rights
    issued, the authority must have in mind some target. In the context of Figure 2, the target
    is h*, which is much lower than the unregulated harvest hS. (Clearly, government
    intervention is only required if h*≠hS.)

    In this subsection, we present the main arguments in favor of economic
    instruments found in the literature. These four arguments are often advanced to manage
    polluting industries, rather than wildlife, and we will explore to what extent these insights
    spill over to the realm of CITES in section 2.3.

    A. Least cost approach: It is realistic to assume that agents in the economy are
    heterogeneous in their ability to produce commodities – some people will be more
    efficient than others in producing output, harvesting wildlife or abating emissions. It is
    also realistic to assume that knowledge about the capacities of different agents is not
    public; economic agents themselves have more information about their ‘true type’ than
    the government, and it may not be in the interest of private parties to reveal their true type
    to the regulator. If these two assumptions are met, then market incentives are more

    1 The choice between a harvest tax and quota depends on uncertainty. If there is no uncertainty about the
    marginal cost and marginal benefit functions (about species growth, their future value, etc.), it does not
    matter whether the authority chooses a tax or quota to achieve its goal (h* in Figure 2, say). If there is
    uncertainty, picking a harvest tax can lead to the ‘wrong’ level of harvests, while choosing a quantity can
    result in a mistake about the forecasted ‘price’ that agents will have to pay for harvesting rights (Weitzman
    1974). Such errors have social costs. However, unless high values for rights encourage ‘excessive’
    poaching, it would seem that a quota is preferred from an uncertainty standpoint because, subject to the
    effectiveness of policing efforts (which is also required with a tax), it guarantees that harvests do not
    exceed socially desired levels.

    16

    efficient than across the board regulatory C&C measures. If these conditions are not met,
    the regulator can ‘mimic’ the market outcome by tailoring regulations for each and every
    firm/agent. However, even in such an unlikely full-information context, the
    administrative requirements and costs of such regulations exceed those of market
    incentives. To circumvent such costs, the regulator typically ignores heterogeneity at the
    agent level and treats each agent the same (e.g., requiring each one to harvest the same
    quantity). As will become clear, this comes at a cost.

    The main market incentives are harvest taxes and quota trading. Harvest taxes are a
    way to internalize the spillovers associated with harvesting. The optimal level of the tax is
    determined by the institutional setting. When property rights are not secure, the tax should
    be set at a relatively high level to account for both external effects and user costs. When
    property rights are secure, resource owners already account for the user cost, such that the
    optimal tax only reflects the external cost (nonuse values foregone or possibly ecological
    costs) associated with harvesting at the optimal level.

    Quota trading first requires the establishment of an aggregate cap (or quota) on
    harvesting, followed by the ‘issuance’ of ‘rights to harvest’ (quota or permits) that can then
    be traded. Tradable emission permits can be allocated to existing harvesters at no cost to
    them (referred to as “grandfathering”) or sold via an auction to the highest bidders, thereby
    generating revenue for the government.

    The common feature of taxes and tradable rights is that, in equilibrium, harvesting
    occurs by the most efficient firms/agents. With taxes, only agents with low harvesting
    costs will be able to pay the tax and stay in business. The important thing to note here is
    that agents themselves reveal their costs by their actions (exiting or entering the
    ‘industry’ by harvesting wildlife) – the regulator does not need to know anything about
    individual agents. With tradable quota, harvesting rights will gravitate to firms with the
    lowest marginal harvest costs. They are the ones that stand to benefit most from acquiring
    these permits (as their profits per unit of harvesting are greatest), and therefore they are
    able to either outbid other agents at an auction, or simply purchase quota from less
    efficient firms/agents directly. Again trade among firms themselves, with superior
    knowledge about their costs than the regulator, ensures that an efficient outcome
    emerges. This is an important result: with taxes and quota the total harvesting costs are
    minimized for a given (pre-determined) total harvest level.

    B. Easy to enforce: Market incentives are no panacea. Regardless of whether the
    authority chooses regulations or market incentives, or a mix of both, there is no escaping
    the need to monitor agents’ behavior and enforce the regulations. Regardless of the type
    of regulation chosen, agents have an incentive to ignore it and free ride on the
    conservation efforts of others – over-harvest their quota, understate their catch to save on
    taxes, and so on. However, it can be argued that enforcement requirements can be
    lowered when property rights are created (regardless of whether they exist at the level of
    the individual or the community). This will have two important effects. First, as stated
    above, secure property rights will induce owners to take the user cost of extraction into
    account, and therefore it diminishes the incentive to over-harvest in the short run. Second,
    while access to the resource must still be enforced to restrict usage of non-owners and

    17

    control extraction by potential ‘cheaters’ in the case of a community-owned resource, the
    costs associated with such enforcement will now to a large extent be borne by the owner
    rather than the regulator. Since the resource owner likely has better knowledge about
    local enforcement issues than a regulator, costs may also be lower. To some extent
    similar devolution of enforcement is expected to occur when a multi-year tradable quota
    system is in place, with a multi-year quota amounting to just another form of property
    right. For example, when it is agreed that the aggregate cap or total harvest in any
    particular season is a function of the wild stock, then it is in the interest of all quota
    holders to monitor each other’s behavior and make sure that others do not over-harvest.
    Allowing others to over-harvest would be to one’s own detriment as this lowers next
    season’s stock and quota.

    C. Dynamic incentives: Economists generally like economic incentives because
    they provide agents with an incentive to adopt technical changes that lower costs.
    Consider the textbook case of abating emissions. A tax or tradable emission permit
    system gives an incentive to develop and adopt new and clean technologies because such
    technologies will enable firms to sell permits (or avoid buying them), or avoid paying the
    tax. Further, market instruments provide incentives to change products, processes and so
    on, as marginal costs and benefits change over time. Because firms are always trying to
    avoid the tax or paying for emission rights, they tend to respond quickly to technological
    change.

    D. Economic instruments may raise revenues: As mentioned under B; regulating
    firms requires monitoring and enforcement – costly activities for the regulator. When
    market instruments are used, some of these costs might be returned to the authority in the
    form of revenue. Indeed, regulation can turn into a net revenue-raising activity, and there
    is ample evidence that many environmental taxes are used exactly for this purpose in
    OECD countries. It is evident that a tax system raises revenues, but creation of property
    rights or tradable quota may have a similar effect. This happens when rights are
    auctioned off rather than grandfathered (provided free of charge to agents already
    involved in the activity). However, grandfathering of rights has a certain political appeal
    since the allocation mechanism can be used to make the trading system acceptable. For
    example, if it were possible to identify all harvesters of a certain wildlife species,
    allocating them a certain number of harvest rights (and guaranteeing those) might cause
    them to mend their ways, harvest only the allowable quota granted them, and, at the same
    time, encourage them to aid in the protection of the species.

    2.3 Relevance for the case of wildlife conservation

    How important are these four arguments in favor of economic (market) incentives
    for the particular context of wildlife conservation? First, consider the issue of least cost
    harvesting. It has been demonstrated that extensive cost savings may occur in the context
    of commercial fisheries management and pollution control (Weninger and Waters 2003,
    Cropper and Oates 1992). But it is important to realize that commercial fishers and
    polluting firms (possibly producing different goods) may constitute a much more diverse
    or heterogeneous set of actors than, say, those harvesting certain wildlife species in a
    developing country.

    18

    When (i) harvesting techniques are low-tech, labor-intensive and capital-extensive,
    and fairly uniform across all contributing agents, and (ii) the ecological conditions under
    which the species lives, and their local densities, are rather similar across space, then the
    efficiency gains in terms of equating marginal harvesting costs across agents must be
    small. In other words, if marginal costs across harvesters are rather similar, the
    efficiency gains from trade or EIs will be small. How “similar” are marginal harvesting
    cost functions for wildlife harvesters? This should be assessed on a case-by case basis.
    There are likely cases where efficiency gains from tradable quota or taxes are
    considerable. When harvesting technologies vary greatly (WWI rifles versus helicopters
    and high precision rifles); when habitat is diverse (common lands versus private reserves,
    game ranches); or when demand for wildlife harvesting originates from different markets
    (e.g. commodity versus trophy markets, nuisance harvesting), such gains can be
    considerable. In contrast, when a homogenous group of people is harvesting a single
    species for a common market, using similar techniques, then the gains are small. The
    conclusion is that efficiency gains are context-dependent, depending on conditions of
    heterogeneity. They may be smaller for the management of many wildlife species than
    have been observed in many other sectors, but this is not certain.

    Next, the case for dynamic efficiency (i.e., the incentive to spur technical change) is
    not very compelling in the context of species harvesting. It can be debated whether
    encouraging harvesting efficiency is to be applauded in this context. More important,
    however, is the following observation: perhaps economic incentives will have no impact
    on dynamic efficiency whatsoever. The important textbook insight discussed above
    depends on the assumption that firms produce output and create pollution as a byproduct
    (that can be controlled or abated at some cost). It does not spill over to the case of
    wildlife conservation where the separation between product and byproduct does not exist.
    By inventing more efficient harvest techniques, firms cannot sell quota (in fact, they will
    presumably buy more of them), nor can they save on their tax obligations.

    This implies that the main advantages of market incentives will likely be the impact
    on enforcement costs and the potential to raise revenues, and possibly (in certain cases)
    standard efficiency gains from adopting EIs. The former is clearly important for
    conservation purposes, as emphasized above. The relevance of revenue raising is slightly
    more dubious. Economists usually consider distributional issues (like transferring money
    from private parties to the government) of secondary importance, but in the context of a
    developing country facing difficulties in raising revenues to provide basic public goods,
    this issue obviously becomes relevant as well (as already noted above). In addition, as
    will become clear in section 3.2, distributional issues may be of importance when the
    amount of habitat is endogenous, or chosen by local agents.

    2.4 Summary

    To achieve optimal use of resources typically involves regulation of users. Regulation is
    necessary to internalize spillover effects and, when use or property rights are not secure,
    to account for the inter-temporal user cost associated with harvesting. We argue that
    defining property rights in physical or legal space is an important first step towards
    optimal resource management. In this sense, EIs can often be fruitfully applied. To

    19

    capture spillover benefits (if any) the regulator can choose either additional economic
    instruments, or command and control. It has been documented in other sectors such as
    commercial fisheries that adopting EIs may result in substantial efficiency gains. In this
    section we argue that the scope for such additional efficiency gains may be modest in the
    case of wildlife harvesting. Whether no additional regulation is preferable, or
    intervention through C&C or EIs instead, should be determined at the case study level.
    The costs and benefits of the various options will vary greatly, depending on
    characteristics of the species, the habitat and the parties involved in harvesting.

    3. ECONOMIC INSTRUMENTS: WILDLIFE HARVESTING AND HABITAT

    The main threats to wildlife are introduction of exotic species (invasives),
    overexploitation and habitat conversion. Trade arguably affects all three threats, for
    example, by shipping species from one location to another or by changing relative prices
    of factors and commodities. For trade in threatened species and/or wildlife, that is CITES,
    the most important threats are overexploitation and habitat conversion. Economic
    incentives may affect both the incentive to harvest species, and the incentive to convert
    natural habitat for some competing purpose. We will return to these two threats in this
    section.

    3.1 Regulating harvesting

    Under open-access no individual harvester has an economic incentive to conserve
    the wildlife, and none can efficiently conserve the wildlife by delaying harvest. Doing so
    will only enhance the harvest opportunities of competitors. New harvesters will be
    attracted to the activity, or existing ones will expand their efforts so long as they earn
    more than the (opportunity) cost of their effort. The consequence of ignoring user costs
    by individuals is that all rents are dissipated, and eventually total cost equals total
    revenue. Excessive hunting effort and too small resource stocks represent the
    fundamental problem of open access. Various management instruments can be used to
    combat rent dissipation and protect wild stocks. It will become clear that while most
    instruments are theoretically able to protect stocks, only some will actually be able to
    maximize resource rents.

    Most textbooks on resource economics (e.g. Conrad and Clark, 1987) demonstrate
    that management agencies or the CITES management authority can force harvesters to
    recognize user costs by either imposing the appropriate tax on harvests (reducing
    revenues) or harvesting effort (raising costs by either a license fee or effort tax). While
    the resulting outcome is theoretically efficient and does not involve tedious monitoring of
    effort, a few major problems remain. First and foremost is that taxes may be politically
    infeasible as it transfers all of the economic rent to the government, and harvesters will
    use their (political) power to prevent such a policy from being implemented. This is the
    most important reason why tax policies are hardly implemented anywhere in the world to
    regulate commercial fisheries (Brown 2000). Second, the authority may have difficulty in
    computing the optimal tax, which depends on factors such as demand for wildlife

    20

    products and biological processes. Taxing harvesting effort can be difficult because
    fishers have an incentive to substitute types of effort that are not taxed for types that are
    taxed. Finally, enforcement of a harvest tax and its collection may be difficult.

    Much more common than tax schemes in actual renewable resource management
    policies are quota schemes. In the case of wildlife, an annual harvest quota can be
    determined from information about the species’ population dynamics and minimum
    viable population, and other (economic) factors, and then allocated in some fashion. At
    the national level, quota can be distributed amongst individual hunters or communities, or
    hunting can remain open until the national quota is reached. While a quota system may
    result in conservation of the stock and optimal harvesting levels (provided that the
    authority has access to all the relevant data, and that monitoring and enforcement occur),
    a quota system will not always result in efficient allocation of effort. For example, if the
    hunting is opened up until the country’s quota is reached, it is possible to end up in a
    situation where the wrong animals (e.g., females of child bearing age) are taken with
    more effort than needed as hunters/communities rush to capture quota before others get
    there first. Such rushing is likely to dissipate rents as the situation is not unlike
    (controlled) open-access. The only difference is that wildlife stocks are protected from
    over-exploitation by the quota.

    Open-access problems can be overcome if property rights are allocated to
    individuals or communities/groups. If a hunter has the right to harvest a certain quantity
    in a specified time interval (say, per year), she will decide to use her effort so that harvest
    costs are minimized if discounted prices are constant, for example, or that her supply is
    concentrated in periods of high demand and high prices. Economic efficiency occurs at
    the firm level, but from society’s point of view it is still possible to improve the
    allocation of effort by allocating harvest to least-cost agents. This may be accomplished
    by auctioning them off or by allowing trade in harvest rights.2 If either of these options is
    implemented, the quota scheme is both efficient (maximizes resource rents) and
    conserves the wild stock.

    If a particular wildlife species is found in more than one country and global
    management is desired (as may be the case for elephant), an overall harvest quota can be
    determined and allocated among the individual countries which would then allocate quota
    internally. Again each nation’s harvest rights can be traded domestically or, perhaps,
    even internationally. The latter option enables society to earn further gains from trade by
    exploiting international differences in harvesting cost. A condition for such a scheme to
    maximize welfare, however, is that the conservation value of elephants is the same for
    elephants in different countries, If this condition is violated, trading with an “exchange
    rate” reflecting differences in spillover values may be introduced.

    2 Quota constitutes a property right that has value. The price of quota is the value of the in situ
    resource, which is simply the market price minus the marginal harvesting cost, or the scarcity
    rent. Of course, enforcement of quota rights is a necessary condition for quota prices to reflect
    scarcity rent. Agents with low costs will bid more for quota; likewise, if quota is tradable, low
    cost ‘firms’ will buy quota from high cost ones, thereby making everyone better off. In
    equilibrium, the price of transferable quota is equal to the resource rent (Anderson 1995).

    21

    The allocation of quota can be used as a policy tool. Quota can be auctioned each
    year to the highest bidders, thereby earning rents that the government can use to monitor
    and enforce the scheme and fund wildlife management and habitat protection programs.
    Revenue can also be used to reduce tax distortions elsewhere, or finance the provision of
    other public goods. Quota can also be allocated to local communities that can then sell
    the quota, harvest specimens themselves or protect them from harvest (perhaps to
    enhance tourism). In this case, the local communities have a greater interest in wildlife
    management than if they are left out of the system entirely.

    To sum up, when backed by sufficient enforcement and monitoring effort,
    economic instruments (and C&C measures alike) are capable to contribute to the
    conservation of wildlife by restricting harvest effort. In theory, an ‘optimal’ or efficient
    level of harvesting effort can be implemented by appropriate choice of regulatory
    stringency. However, only some economic instruments (notably taxes and tradable quota)
    are able to maximize the resource rent associated with harvesting.

    3.2 Case study: Commercial use of The Vicuña

    The vicuña (Vicugna vicugna) is one of the South American camelids along with
    the guanaco (Lama guanicoe), the llama (Lama glama) and the alpaca (Lama pacos).
    While vicuña and guanacos are wild, the llamas and alpacas are their domesticated
    counterpart, a process of selection that appears to have started between 7,000 and 6,000
    years ago. The vicuña inhabits the Andean highlands, between 3,000 and 4,600 m. Its
    range currently extends over large areas of Perú (80,000), north of Argentina (23,000)
    and Chile (25,000), and west of Bolivia (12,000).

    Hunted for their precious wool, which is the one of the finest in the world, the
    vicuña was near to extinction by the late 1960s. With the European invasion, a trade in
    fibre was developed, involving the killing of the animal. The few attempts to regulate the
    use of vicuñas up to this century failed and uncontrolled hunting continued until the species
    reached near extinction, with just an estimated 10,000 individuals left in the 1950’s.

    Vicuña wool has been long praised for its softness and fineness. Its current scarcity
    also adds to the high prices commanded by the few items traded internationally. Vicuña
    wool (or rather fleece) is regarded as a luxury fibre along with Alpaca, Angora, Cashmere,
    Camel hair, Mohair, Musk Ox and, Yak, which are noted for their fineness, scarcity, unique
    appearance and status. It is a very exclusive market, with production of all luxury fibres
    representing less than 3% of annual sheepwool production by weight. Vicuña is considered
    the finest and rarest of all, and its softness and colour are highly valued, commanding the
    highest prices. Archaeological findings and ethnic history archives indicate three distinct
    phases of interaction between the vicuña and human populations. In a first stage, in the
    Arcaic era of the Central Andes (7,000–2,000 B.C.), human population in the highlands was
    significant and the vicuña was popular prey of the highland hunters (Hurtado 1987).

    In the second stage, from the late Arcaic area to the advent of agriculture, in parallel,
    hunting and livestock rearing took place, with hunting being reduced in importance. Llamas
    and alpacas, both domesticated species, provided food, wool and fuel, and the llama could

    22

    be used to carry loads. A more complex sociopolitical system emerged and the hunting of
    vicuña was banned for religious reasons. Wool was still obtained, although this was done
    through a management system imposed from political authorities. A live capture technique
    called chaku was used because it allowed the shearing and release of the animal with little
    impact on the population. These practices were clearly directed to the conservation and
    sustainable use of resources, where the vicuña wool was only used for special robes for the
    nobles and royals (Hurtado 1987).

    The system, however, was affected by the European invasion, giving way to a third
    phase where the planned chaku was gradually dismantled and hunting of vicuñas increased,
    coupled with a regional land struggle between native communities and the Europeans. The
    few attempts to regulate the use of vicuñas failed (Hurtado 1987) and uncontrolled hunting
    continued until significant control measures were set in place in the 1950s by which time the
    population was nearing extinction, with an estimated 10,000 individuals left (Torres 1992).

    Conservation efforts to protect the vicuña started in Perú in 1969, with the creation
    of the Pampa Galeras National Reserve. Subsequently, range states have coordinated
    conservation efforts through several agreements. In 1969 the first agreement for the
    protection of the vicuña was signed. Peru and Bolivia signed in 1969, with Argentina
    joining in 1971 and Chile in 1972. The agreement banned all international and internal
    trade in vicuña products and prohibited the export of fertile individuals to third parties. The
    vicuña was also listed in Appendix I of CITES in 1975, ratified by all range states and
    banning all international trade in the species.

    These coordination efforts for conservation at the international level created a
    strong base for cooperation among range states. As a result, the vicuña experienced an
    impressive recovery during the last 30 years, particularly in Perú. From an estimated 6,000
    over the four range countries in 1965, the vicuña reached 10,000 by 1970, 101,215 in 1983
    and around 154,000 by 1992. Management areas have also increased from 248,000ha in
    1965 to more than 7,289,896 ha in 1982 to some 20,800,000 ha currently under protection
    status. Conservation efforts have been particularly successful in Peru and Chile, where
    population levels increased significantly during the early years. However, financial and
    physical requirements to effectively protect those areas have not grown at the same rate.

    Although vicuñas have natural predators such as pumas and foxes, the most
    important limiting factors appear to be poaching by humans and the availability of food, for
    which they compete with other livestock, like llamas and alpacas. It is the first factor which
    motivated governments to protect the species and ban all use; it is the second, however,
    which has caused most social conflict as communities resent the competition of the vicuña
    for the scarce bofedales in the highlands. Studies in Chile suggest that the vicuña population
    has reached the carrying capacity of the habitat (given the existing livestock densities),
    which would account for the oscillating pattern in the population levels registered since
    1990 (Torres and Nuñez 1994). Every hundred vicuñas in the highlands eat the same
    quantity of food as 75 alpacas, or 61 llamas or 72 sheep. The total stock of domesticated
    livestock in the management zones, is estimated to be the equivalent of 51,864 heads of
    vicuña. The 21,620.2ha of bofedal available in the management areas of the Parinacota
    Province, is therefore estimated to be capable of supporting 25,969 vicuñas in the

    23

    management areas of the Parinacota Province. However, in 1992 the vicuña population in
    the area was estimated in 26,144, indicating that it is at carrying capacity and is in
    competition with domestic livestock for food.

    At the regional level, some areas show significant overstocking, as in the Lauca
    National Park. As populations recovered, the competition over habitat with domestic
    livestock (llamas and alpacas) increased, this being one of the factors behind the increase in
    poaching. These factors made the involvement of the local communities essential for the
    long term protection of the species. One way to create incentives for conservation and
    protection of the vicuña at the local level was to reopen trade in vicuña wool, which can be
    extracted by shearing live vicuñas with little impact on wild populations, and generating
    revenue for local communities. This was the philosophy behind the second vicuña
    agreement in 1979. It provided a use-based rationale for the local communities to become
    interested in the conservation of the vicuna.

    In 1987, Vicuña populations in the Laguna Blanca Reserve (Catamarca province)
    were examined to assess their potential contribution to the indigenous peasant economy.
    This is primarily a subsistence economy, with a small but increasing involvement in the
    market economy. The two main sources of income are from sheep and llama spun wool.
    The potential harvest of the Vicuña population was estimated using simulation techniques,
    calculating the maximum sustainable yield and the carrying capacity of the area
    (Rabinovich et al., 1991). If the Vicuña population were allowed to grow from its current
    size of 5,000 animals to around 8,000, 15.2% of that population could be harvested each
    year. The monetary value of each Vicuña is estimated at US$64: $19 for the wool, $10 for
    the meat (assuming a 20kg animal fetches $0.50 per kg) and $35 for the hide. The
    estimated total income that could be derived from sustainable management of the Vicuña is
    US$94,464 per year. This would provide an annual household income to the peasant
    community of the Laguna Blanca Reserve of almost US$1,000 if equally distributed among
    the 95 families. This would clearly provide an incentive for these peasant farmers to share
    their lands with the wild vicuna.

    To sum up, strict conservation through use restrictions, when properly enforced,
    will conserve wildlife. However, in the long run strict conservation can undermine the
    stated objectives. Vicuñas and livestock compete for forage, and use restrictions on the
    former remove the incentives of peasant farmers to share their land with Vicuñas.
    Establishing property rights in land and wildlife provides such an incentive and therefore
    represents a major step towards sustainable development. Whether tradable quota (an EI) or
    non-tradable quota (a form of command and control) are implemented to regulate
    management is of secondary importance. A main point of this study is that establishment of
    property rights is important, and EIs or government regulation will contribute little more to
    the protection of species.

    3.3 Instruments and habitat conversion

    The problem of wildlife conservation is intimately related to the protection of
    wildlife habitat, which implies that it is bound up in land use and land ownership. In the
    previous section, we examined economic instruments and incentives related to the harvest

    24

    of wildlife. In this section, we consider wildlife habitat and land use. Of course, property
    rights to wildlife, regulations concerning take and incentives to ensure that wildlife are
    not over harvested affect the value of land. That is, any harvest and wildlife protection
    policies that increase the value of wildlife might increase the value of land in habitat.

    Economists usually consider distributional issues of secondary importance. The
    focus is generally on maximizing social surplus, and whether that surplus accrues to the
    regulator or private agents typically matters less. In this section, however, we argue that
    distribution may be of the utmost importance for the case of wildlife conservation. The
    reason is as follows. In any economy, there are agents (private or public) that decide
    about land use. Supposedly such agents compare the present values of net returns from
    alternative land uses – they compare the returns of habitat conservation and sustainable
    resource management to those of agricultural conversion. When intervention lowers the
    decision maker’s returns to habitat conservation and resource harvesting, it becomes
    more likely that habitat will make place for other uses of the land.

    Above we established that taxing, auctioned quota, subsidies and grandfathered
    quota are equally efficient in restricting harvest effort. However, as mentioned, there is a
    distributional difference. Taxing and auctions imply resource rents for the regulator,
    whereas subsidies and grandfathered quota imply rents for the harvester. This translates
    into different incentives to conserve habitat.

    Often landowners have little incentive to protect wildlife habitat because the value
    of land in habitat for agricultural producers and foresters may be very small or non-
    existent. As noted earlier, wildlife and wildlife habitat are a public good and private
    landowners have little if any incentive to protect wildlife habitat on their land. Indeed, as
    the enactment of the Endangered Species Act in the United States has demonstrated and
    as we argue further below, landowners may have every incentive to do the opposite –
    convert habitat to crops. Therefore, economic instruments are required to ‘encourage’
    landowners to protect wildlife habitat.

    In many political jurisdictions, rural land continues to be largely publicly owned,
    or, if not owned outright, agricultural and other users of rural land have ill-defined or
    weak property rights. Peasants lack property rights to wildlife and often gain the right to
    land only by actively farming it. Even productive forestland might be sacrificed and
    wildlife habitat lost because peasants cannot demonstrate ownership of land unless they
    ‘develop’ it – that is, conduct cropping or grazing activities – and this inevitably results in
    conflicts with wildlife. The appropriate assignment (and protection) of property rights to
    undeveloped land that also serves as wildlife habitat might encourage peasants not to
    develop it; peasant landowners might earn a living through sustainable, small-scale
    forestry and/or harvest of non-timber forest products, including wildlife if they are given
    a right to animals on their property.

    However, this would require a change in the way most developing countries
    allocate land and other property rights. Moreover, and importantly, the earnings from
    habitat and wildlife exploitation must exceed that of agriculture. While government
    policies related to wildlife (and forestry) can affect returns, it can be the case that such

    25

    activities cannot compete with cropping, even supposing that the ‘correct’ institutions
    were in place to enable landowners the rights to all the products produced on their land.
    When the social benefits of habitat conversion exceed the social benefits of conservation
    (including international positive external effects), economists recommend conversion of
    natural lands into alternative uses.

    The most interesting case exists where habitat conservation “does not pay” from a
    private perspective, but would be optimal from a social (global) perspective. In other
    words, when the positive external effects associated with conservation of habitat and
    wildlife are sufficiently great to topple the balance from conversion to conservation. In
    this case economic instruments can be used to encourage private landowners or land
    users to take into account the negative external effects of their land-use decisions on
    wildlife. What instruments might be employed that directly affect land management?

    Regulation

    Regulations specify what landowners can and cannot do on their land. The
    Endangered Species Act is an example of regulation in that it prohibits destruction of the
    habitat of wildlife on private land. Regulatory approaches often entail expensive
    monitoring and enforcement, and can still be ineffective if social norms and formal rules
    do not coincide (Ostrom 1990; Nielson 2003). In fact, it is possible that regulations may
    lead to perverse incentives that discourage conservation (‘shoot, shovel, and shut up’) if
    restrictions on established property right owners are onerous (Polasky 2001).

    Taxes and subsidies

    Tax incentives can be designed to give farmers an incentive to protect wildlife
    habitat on farmland. However, evidence from developing countries indicates that tax
    policies are not, by themselves, capable of compensating rural landowners for providing a
    public good (wildlife habitat) at private expense. As evidence has accumulated that
    preferential tax assessments do more to subsidize farmland owners than to conserve
    farmland, governments have increasingly initiated programs to purchase development
    rights and conservation easements (Wiebe et al. 1996). These programs involve
    separating and purchasing some but not all of an owner’s rights to a property: separated
    rights might include, for example, the right to build residential or commercial buildings,
    to drain sloughs, to burn associated uplands, or to remove endangered species of trees. In
    the United States, most purchases have been in the form of agricultural conservation
    easements that restrict residential, commercial or industrial uses, but that allow active
    farming (Hardie et al. 2004).

    Subsidies are perhaps better than tax incentives for protecting nature on
    agricultural lands. In developed countries, subsidies are used to take land out of
    production, keep extant wetlands or other critical wildlife habitat from being converted to
    agriculture, or establish wildlife habitat through tree planting, plant of dense nesting
    cover for migratory waterfowl, et cetera. Similar programs can be used in developing

    26

    countries, although financing such programs will pose a greater challenge and likely
    prevent them from being implemented.

    The subsidy approach most-often mentioned in the literature is that of
    compensating farmers for losses from wildlife depredation. While not providing
    incentives to prevent legal and illegal taking of wildlife, compensation may at least
    reduce the incentives of local peasants to go out and destroy wildlife to prevent the
    agricultural damage that they may cause. On the other hand, wildlife damage programs
    may encourage additional conversion of habitat into cropland as they essentially amount
    to a subsidy to agriculture (Rondeau and Bulte 2003).

    Finally, one way to arrive at a globally optimal level of habitat conversion is
    through subsidies at the international level. Fair compensation for positive external
    effects of conservation implies a transfer flow from North to South. While some of this
    could presumably be arranged through NGO involvement (see below) and current
    opportunities provided by the Global Environmental Facility (GEF), it is an open
    question whether this is enough to safeguard sufficiently large areas of nature in the long
    run. The public good characteristics of nature conservation, and the implied incentives to
    free ride on other’s efforts, could mean additional, cooperative efforts, should be
    undertaken. One can think of large-scale programs to finance the provision of ecological
    services (such as now pioneered in Costa Rica), funded through taxation in the North.

    Transfer of development rights

    Transferable development rights and wildlife habitat banking constitute cases
    where separation of development rights can be integrated with land use planning.
    Wildlife habitat banking (WHB) allows landowners to develop wildlife habitat on their
    property if they have sufficient credits from investment in the completed rehabilitation of
    a WHB site. Land use planning enters this program through the designation of the WHB
    sites (see Fernandez and Karp 1998). Sites can be chosen that provide large high-quality
    habitats with superior potential to sustain desired ecosystems. Given good choices, the
    investments in the WHB can provide greater community-wide environmental benefits
    than equivalent investments in the maintenance of habitat on sites that are being
    developed. Good planning is crucial to obtain higher benefits, because WHB is a ‘no net
    loss’ program that links area restored to wildlife habitat area removed by conversion of
    habitat to agriculture (Hardie et al. 2004).

    An important difference between preferential tax assessments and purchase of
    development rights is the potential role of planning. Preferential tax assessments are
    typically extended to all eligible landowners regardless of the location of their property.
    However, purchases can be targeted to sites where the social or environmental benefits
    are deemed to be particularly high, such as along a wildlife corridor or within a region
    under particular agricultural pressure. While the potential for targeting exists, it generally
    is not realized (see Hardie et al. 2004). Zoning-based transferable development right
    (TDR) programs are initiated by dividing an area that is being opened for agricultural
    conversion, or one that has already been converted, into a zone where agricultural
    development is permitted and one where agriculture is limited or prohibited entirely,

    27

    thereby protecting crucial habitat. The government partially takes private property rights
    in ‘down-zoned’ area in order to protect an environmental amenity – wildlife habitat (see
    Johnston and Madison 1997; Hardie et al. 2004). When the down-zoning occurs,
    landowners in the affected (source) areas are granted the option to sell the separated
    development rights to landowners in designated agricultural development (‘up-zoned’)
    areas or sinks. It is the owners of property in the up-zoned or target areas that must
    purchase the transferable development rights in order to be able to farm their land.
    Landowners who lose property rights are compensated in a development rights market,
    but at rates driven by the opportunity costs created by zoning instead of by willingness to
    pay for cropland. Of course, governments incur costs of planning and administration of
    such a TDR program, and the TDR system is only meant to make the separated zoning
    politically palatable. It is unlikely that this type of instrument will work to protect
    wildlife habitat in developing countries unless property rights of all kinds are made
    stronger (see section 4).

    One variant that might work in areas where forest concessionaires are active is to
    require the forest companies to purchase TDRs from landowners who have been down
    zoned. That is, a forest concessionaire would be required to purchase a certain number of
    TDRs that protect wildlife habitat in exchange for the right to harvest a certain volume of
    timber.

    Direct purchase of conservation easements to protect wildlife habitat also
    constitutes a form of property rights purchase. In this case, the state simply purchases the
    right to develop land for agriculture from the landowner. Since this might be too costly
    for many developing countries, one alternative is to permit NGOs (or even foreign
    governments) to purchase these rights, as indicated above. Like the case of TDRs, this
    option requires that economic institutions exist so that development rights can be
    separated from ownership of land (and that ownership of land is well defined and
    protected by the courts – see section 4 below). There may also be opposition to the idea
    of selling development rights to foreigners, whether foreign governments or NGOs.

    The problem is that there is no guarantee that earnings from (perhaps marginal)
    agricultural land are sufficient to enable compensation to take place. If this is the case,
    illegal conversion of all land capable of producing crops will still occur. It is not a simple
    matter to construct a land protection scheme that includes restrictions on land use with
    transferable development rights to compensate losers (see van Kooten 1993). In
    developing countries, the obstacles standing in the way of implementing such a scheme
    may again be too large to surmount.

    Transferring income through NGO involvement

    The private sector might also be relied upon to a greater extent than currently.
    Environmental NGOs are perhaps the best means for transferring wildlife conservation
    funds from rich to poor countries. Nonprofit private land trusts, such as the Nature
    Conservancy, The Conservation Fund and the Trust for Public Land have become active
    in the conservation of open space and wildlands in the United States (see Hardie et al.
    2004). These organizations purchase properties or easements on lands that provide

    28

    environmental benefits (such as wildlife habitat) and seek to protect land slated for urban
    development. Purchased land may be turned over to state and/or local governments, but
    might be managed by the NGOs in order to guarantee that contributors in developed
    countries receive the non-market amenity values purchased in developing countries
    where the record of government management of public lands is perhaps not as good. Of
    course, for this option to work, it is important that property rights are clearly delineated
    and protected by the courts in the developing countries. NGOs are unlikely to purchase
    property or wildlife easements on land if these property rights are non-enforceable.

    Kontoleon and Swanson (2003) have shown that, in the context of giant panda
    preservation (in the Wolong reserve, China), the non-use values associated with panda
    conservation in the “wild” are sufficiently large to warrant setting aside extensive
    stretches of land as a reserve – such that not only the flagship ‘panda’, but many other
    species as well can be supported. However, when such elusive non-use values are not
    backed up by true transfer flows, it will be in the interest of local people to allocate the
    land to other uses. Capturing and channeling non-use values through international
    transfer payments, perhaps actual purchase or lease of land by environmental NGOs, may
    be one good means to protect species.

    3.4 Summary

    In this section we, again, demonstrate that defining property rights and benefit-sharing
    programs are vital in promoting conservation of wildlife. We show that EIs are in theory
    capable of maximizing resource rents, but argue that their main role could be in
    promoting habitat conservation. There are various EIs that can be used to make sure that
    habitat conservation occurs at the lowest cost (tradable development rights, habitat
    conversion taxes). Equally important, to our opinion, will be the use of international EIs
    that capture and channel nonuse values from North to South, and to promote habitat
    conservation through transfers and subsidies.

    4. IMPLEMENTING ECONOMIC INSTRUMENTS TO PROTECT WILDLIFE

    What is the scope for adopting EIs in developing countries to promote
    conservation of wildlife and enable a transition towards sustainable development? We
    argue that the perspective is mixed. EIs are not a panacea, and it is an open question
    whether they can be effectively employed in all contexts. Institutions and social capital
    are important if economic incentives are to be used to manage and protect wildlife
    populations. For example, in their review of emissions trading, Tietenberg et al. (1998)
    indicate that it is impossible to institute any system of emissions trading unless the
    requisite legal and other institutions are in place for monitoring, measuring, certifying
    and enforcing trades, and that lack of appropriate institutions is probably the most
    important obstacle to the use of market incentives for addressing climate change. For a
    democratic market economy to function properly, or for market-oriented economic
    policies to have effect, three criteria or factors other than markets and private property are

    29

    required (Fukuyama 2002). These criteria relate to economic institutions, the role of the
    state, and culture.

    While a full-fledged analysis of these issues is far beyond the scope of the current
    study, we would like to note that it is by no means guaranteed that the current state of
    economic institutions (be it formal or informal) and governments in many resource-rich
    countries is sufficient to exploit the gains from employing EIs. This can be illustrated for
    the case of elephant harvesting and ivory trade. In Table 3 we summarize key
    institutional indicators for (i) OECD countries, (ii) Asian consuming states, and (iii) main
    ivory producers. An examination of the Table suggests that the prospects of
    implementing EIs in producer states are not promising. By all measures, range states are
    the least capable of preventing illegal harvests and sales of ivory. They lack the required
    economic institutions (courts, rule of law, government effectiveness) and social capital
    (control of corruption) for enforcing and policing ivory trade. Establishing the
    infrastructure to guide successful implementation of EIs comes at a cost that is unknown.

    Table 3: Measures of the Effectiveness of Economic Institutions and Levels of Social
    Capital in Industrial Countries, Ivory Importing States and Elephant Range States,
    2000-2001

    Measure Eight Industrialized
    Countries

    Five Major Asian
    Buyer States

    30 Range States
    (Africa & Asia)

    Voice & Accountability 1.453 0.106 -0.563

    Political Stability 1.275 0.971 -0.801

    Government
    Effectiveness

    1.586 1.048 -0.625

    Regulatory Quality 1.165 0.899 -0.3

    37

    Rule of Law 1.628 1.073 -0.516

    Control of Corruption 1.878 0.946 -0.524

    Source: World Bank (2002) and calculation

    5. CONCLUSIONS AND POLICY RECOMMENDATIONS

    Economic instruments have great potential to address spillovers associated with wildlife
    management. Economic incentives appear particularly useful for the following reasons.
    First, they are theoretically able to achieve objectives at the lowest cost. They encourage
    efficient use of resources and therefore have the smallest impact on economic growth and
    development. The flexibility, efficiency and cost-effectiveness associated with the use of

    30

    EIs is presumably nowhere more important than in developing countries. Second,
    instruments such as auctioned tradable quota and taxes are capable of generating
    government revenues, enabling the government to provide a variety of public goods. In
    countries where the scope for raising revenues is small because of limited administrative
    capacity, this effect could be important. The administrative requirements of EIs are
    different – for example, raising revenues through auctioning off trophy quotas is much
    easier than raising funds through taxing households involved in harvesting of a species.
    Third, compared to command and control measures, the information requirements of EIs
    are modest. C&C requires the planner to make decisions that allocate resources across
    activities. In contrast, by simply providing a setting or context, “the market” will take
    care of an efficient allocation of resources when EIs are used. EIs have lower institutional
    and human resource requirements than C&C – an important advantage in an information-
    sparse environment.

    In spite of these advantages, EIs are not a panacea that can be straightforwardly
    implemented across the board. The following critical comments are a useful reminder of
    the key restrictions. First off, and perhaps obviously, EIs are not a substitute for
    monitoring and enforcement. Conservation of wildlife will critically depend on these
    activities, regardless of whether C&C or EIs are used to allocate resources. (However, as
    argued in section 2, public authorities may be able to shift the burden of enforcement and
    monitoring onto private agents if property rights to resources are defined in either a
    physical or legal sense.) Without effective monitoring and enforcement, economic
    incentives cannot work – prices paid for tradable quota will be too low and could
    approach zero (as harvesting without quota is also feasible) and tax evasion will occur on
    a large scale. One potential advantage of some EIs is that they can generate the resources
    that are required to support the enforcement effort that is needed to enable the EIs to
    work. However, there may be circumstances where adequate enforcement and monitoring
    is too costly. In that case, it may be optimal to opt for the private optimum rather than the
    social one; that is, establish property rights to wildlife and ignore spillover benefits
    associated with conservation. While harvest levels will be “too large” in the short run,
    such that species stocks will be “too low” eventually, the costs associated with this
    imperfection may be small compared to the costs of achieving the first best outcome.

    Next, a key obstacle to the implementation of EIs is the availability of economic
    institutions and social capital in many wildlife-rich countries. As of yet it is unclear what
    “minimum” level of institutional infrastructure is necessary to successfully implement
    EIs, and how this minimum level compares to actual scores in key countries.
    Nevertheless, it seems plausible to argue that many countries are currently not up to the
    task to implement and guide a full-fledged tradable quota or tax scheme to regulate the
    use of wildlife species.

    This is not to say that nothing can be done to greatly improve the efficiency and
    sustainability of wildlife harvesting. While full-fledged implementation of EIs is
    cumbersome and expensive, it is often possible to make substantial improvement by
    making small steps forward. Specifically, by defining and protecting property rights to
    land and wildlife (be it at the level of the individual or a well-defined group of users,
    depending on the context), resource harvesters will be able to reach the privately optimal

    31

    level of resource harvesting and conservation. While inferior to the socially optimal level
    of harvesting and conservation, it arguably represents a significant improvement over the
    unregulated open access outcome that eventuates when property rights do not exist. To
    complement the management scheme, other instruments can be applied after property
    rights have been established. This would internalize any external effects. However,
    whether making this additional step is warranted from a cost-benefit perspective is
    something that has to be assessed on a case-by case level.

    We believe, but have not analyzed, that the scope for using complementary EIs in
    regulating harvest levels may be modest (but there clearly will be cases where this is not
    true and where the gains from implementing EIs to regulate harvesting are large). The
    efficiency gains from EIs may be modest, for example, because harvesting technologies
    are sometimes fairly homogenous, suggesting little scope for gains from trade. The
    greatest perspective for implementing EIs, we believe, is with respect to land use and
    habitat conversion. Specifically, it seems advisable to closely consider the scope of
    implementing an international transfer system from North to South to compensate for
    transboundary spillover benefits from conservation. Current transfer systems are rather
    ad hoc, and certainly incomplete. Whether the political will exists in the North to fund
    such an effort, and whether the institutional capacity exists in the South to manage the
    subsidy flows, are relevant matters that must be faced.

    To reiterate our caveat from the introduction: the current study has been written
    under great time pressure, and is therefore certainly incomplete, possibly even in key
    respects. We would therefore like to suggest some useful directions for follow-up
    research, aimed at closing the gap between what is known today and what needs to be
    known before EIs can be usefully implemented.

    1. Gains from implementing EIs: what are the potential efficiency gains from tax
    or tradable quota systems? How much heterogeneity exists among harvesters for key
    wildlife species (say: crocodiles)? How do the gains from complementary instruments
    compare to the gains from securing property rights?

    2. Costs of implementing EIs: What are minimum institutional requirements to
    successfully implement EIs? Do many countries currently have the ability in terms of
    social capital and institutions to do so (and if not, what are the associated costs of
    establishing such an institutional infrastructure)?

    3. Costs and benefits: how do the costs and benefits of implementing a system of
    EIs compare for key wildlife species? Are there general lessons to be drawn?

    4. What are the prospects for using EIs in global trade in species? How does a
    wildlife quota system work across countries? What institutions are required and how
    many countries satisfy institutional requirements for implementing EIs? How do
    dynamics affect the usual “optimal tariff” or “optimal quota” result?

    5. How important are international positive effects of wildlife conservation at the
    margin (compared to domestic benefits of sustainable wildlife management)? What is the

    32

    scope for capturing such benefits to promote habitat conservation in the South, and how
    should this be organized?

    6. Operational issues: how can one define and allocate property rights, and how
    can one implement a tax or tradable quota scheme? How high should the tax be (or how
    large the total allowable catch) in light of many real-life uncertainties? Are there many
    parallels with ITQ experiences in fisheries in developed countries, and if so: how can we
    exploit them? How much income should be allocated to wildlife management? Is there a
    role for eco-labeling?

    6. REFERENCES

    Anderson, L.G. 1995. Privatizing Open-access Fisheries: Individual Transferable Quotas.
    Chap. 20 in The Handbook of Environmental Economics (pp. 453–74) edited by
    D. W. Bromley. Cambridge MA: Basil Blackwell.

    Barichello, R.R., R.M. Porter and G.C. van Kooten. 1995. Institutions, Economic
    Incentives and Sustainable Rural Land Use in British Columbia. Managing
    Natural Resources in British Columbia. A. Scott, J. Robinson and D. Cohen, eds.,
    pp.7-53. Vancouver: UBC Press.

    Bernstein, Steven, 2001. The Compromise of Liberal Environmentalism. New York:
    Columbia University Press.

    Borregaard, Nicola, Beatriz Bustos and Matthew Stilwell,2003. The Role of Economic
    Instruments in the Context of Biodiversity Related Multilateral Environmental
    Agreements. Discussion paper commissioned by UNEP. September. 97pp.

    Bovenberg, A.L. and L.H. Goulder, 1996. Optimal Environmental Taxation in the
    Presence of Other Taxes: General-Equilibrium Analysis, American Economic
    Review 86(4): 985-1000.

    Bromley, D.W. 1999. Sustaining development: Environmental resources in developing
    countries. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.

    Brown, G.M., 2000. Renewable Natural Resource Management and Use Without
    Markets, Journal of Economic Literature 38: 875-914

    Bulte, E.H., D.P. van Soest, G.C. van Kooten and R. Schipper, 2002. Forest Conservation
    in Costa Rica: Optimal Forest Stocks under Uncertainty and Rising Nonuse
    Benefits, Am. J. of Agric. Econ. 84(February): 150-60.

    Clark, Colin W. 1990. Mathematical Bioeconomics. 2nd edition. New York: Wiley.

    Conrad, Jon M. 1995. Bioeconomic Models of the Fishery. Chapter 18 in The Handbook
    of Environmental Economics edited by D. W. Bromley. Cambridge, MA: Basil
    Blackwell. .

    33

    Conrad, Jon M. and Colin W. Clark. 1987. Natural Resource Economics: Notes and
    Problems. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    CPB (Netherlands Bureau for Economic Policy Analysis), 1997. Challenging
    Neighbours. Rethinking German and Dutch Economic Institutions. Berlin:
    Springer.

    Dasgupta, Partha. 2000. Economic Progress and the Idea of Social Capital. Social
    Capital. A Multifaceted Perspective. P. Dasgupta and I. Serageldin, eds., pp. 325-
    424. Washington: The World Bank.

    Dasgupta, P. and I. Serageldin (Eds.), 2000. Social Capital. A Multifaceted Perspective.
    Washington, DC: The World Bank.

    Easterly, William. 2001. The Elusive Quest for Growth. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press.

    Ekins, P. and T. Barker, 2001. Carbon Taxes and Carbon Emissions Trading, Journal of
    Economic Surveys 15(3): 325-52.

    Fernandez, Linda and Larry Karp, 1998. Restoring Wetlands Through Wetlands
    Mitigation Banks, Environmental and Resource Economics 12(October): 323-
    344.

    Field, Barry and Nancy Olewiler, 2002. Environmental Economics. 2nd Canadian
    Edition. Toronto: McGraw-Hill Ryerson.

    Fisher, Anthony C., 1981. Resource and Environmental Economics. Cambridge, UK:
    Cambridge University Press.

    Fukuyama, Francis, 1995. Trust. The Social Virtues and the Creation of Prosperity. New
    York: The Free Press.

    Fukuyama, Francis, 1999. The Great Disruption. Human Nature and the Reconstitution
    of Social Order. New York: The Free Press.

    Fukuyama, Francis, 2002. Social Capital and Development: The Coming Agenda, SAIS
    Review 22(Winter-Spring): 23-37.

    Gelauff, G.M.M. 2003. Sociaal kapitaal in de economie, Economisch Statistische
    Berichten Vol. 88, Nr. 4398, March 27, pp.3-5.

    Hardie, I.W., P.J. Parks and G.C. van Kooten, 2004. The Economics of Land Use at the
    Intensive and Extensive Margins. In International Yearbook of Environmental &
    Resource Economics, 2003/2004 edited by H. Folmer and T. Tietenberg.
    Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar. In press.

    34

    Harrison, David Jr., 2002. Tradable Permits for Air Quality and Climate Change. In
    International Yearbook of Environmental & Resource Economics, 2002/2003
    edited by T. Tietenberg and H. Folmer. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar: 311-372.

    Hutton, J., P. Ross and G. Webb, 2001. Using the Market to Create Incentives for the
    Conservation of Crocodilians: A Review, Report for the IUCN/SSC Crocodile
    Specialist Group

    Johnston, Robert A. and Mary E. Madison, 1997. From Landmarks to Landscapes: A
    Review of Current practices in Transfer of Development Rights, Journal of the
    American Planning Association 63(3): 365-378.

    Kinyua, Patrick I.D., 1998. Game Ranching in Machakos District, Kenya: An
    Application of Mathematical Programming to the Study of Wildlife Policy.
    Unpublished Ph.D. Dissertation, Department of Forest Resources Management,
    University of British Columbia, Vancouver, Canada.

    Knack, Stephen and Philip Keefer, 1997. Does Social Capital have an Economic Payoff?
    A Cross-Country Investigation, Quarterly Journal of Economics 112: 1251-1288.

    La Porta, R., F. Lopez-de-Silanes, A. Shleifer and R. W. Vishny. 1997. Trust in Large
    Organizations, American Economic Review 87(May): 333-38.

    La Porta, R., F. Lopez-de-Silanes, A. Shleifer and R. W.Vishny. 1999. The Quality of the
    Government, Journal of Law, Economics & Organization 15(April): 222 –279.

    Loasby, B.J., 1999. Knowledge, Institutions and Evolution in Economics. London, UK:
    Routledge.

    McKitrick, Ross and Randall M. Wigle, 2002. The Kyoto Protocol: Canada’s Risky Rush
    to Judgment. C.D. Howe Institute Commentary No. 169. Toronto: C.D. Howe
    Institute. October.

    Menon, Vivek, 2002. Tusker. The Story of the Asian Elephant. New Delhi: Penguin
    Books India.

    Ménard, C. 1995. Markets as Institutions versus Organizations as Markets? Disentangling
    Some Fundamental Concepts, Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization
    28(October): 161-182.

    Murty, M.N., 1994. Management of Common Property Resources: Limits to Voluntary
    Action, Environmental and Resource Economics 4: 581-94.

    Neher, Philip A., 1990. Natural Resource Economics: Conservation and Exploitation.
    Cambridge UK: Cambridge University Press.

    Nielsen, J.R. 2003. An analytical framework for studying compliance and legitimacy in
    fisheries management, Marine Policy 27: 425-432.

    35

    Newell, Richard G. and William A. Pizer, 2003. Discounting the Distant Future: How
    Much do Uncertain Rates Increase Valuations? Journal of Environmental
    Economics and Management 46: 52-71.

    North, D.C. 1990. Institutions, institutional change and economic performance.
    Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.

    North, Douglass C. 1984. Transaction Costs, Institutions, and Economic History, Journal
    of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 140(1984): 7-17.

    Olson, M. Jr. 1996. Distinguished Lecture on Economics in Government: Big Bills Left
    on the Sidewalk: Why Some Nations are Rich, and Others Poor, Journal of
    Economic Perspectives 10(Spring): 3-24.

    Ostrom, Elinor, 2000. Social capital: A Fad or a Fundamental Concept? Social Capital. A
    Multifaceted Perspective. P. Dasgupta and I. Serageldin, eds., pp. 172-214.
    Washington: The World Bank.

    Ostrom, Elinor, 1998. A Behavioral Approach to the Rational-Choice Theory of
    Collective Action, American Political Science Review 92(March): 1-22.

    Ostrom, Elinor. 1990. Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Collective Action.
    Cambridge University Press.

    Parry, I., R.C. Williams III and L.H. Goulder, 1999. When Can Carbon Abatement
    Policies Increase Welfare? The Fundamental Role of Distorted Factor Markets,
    Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 37: 52-84.

    Pizer, W.A., 1997. Prices vs. Quantities Revisited: The Case of Climate Change.
    Resources for the Future Discussion Paper 98-02, Washington, October. 52pp.

    Prins, H., J. Grootenhuis and T. Dolan 2002. Wildlife Conservation by Sustainable Use.
    Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic Publishers

    Polasky, Stephen. 2001. Investment, information collection, and endangered species
    conservation on private land. In Protecting Endangered Species in the United
    States: Biological Needs, Political Realities, and Economic Choices edited by
    Jason Shogren and John Tschirhart. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Putnam, R.D. 1993, March 21. The prosperous community: Social capital and public life.
    The American Prospect 4(13), 35-42.

    Richards, Kenneth R., 2000. Framing Environmental Policy Instrument Choice, Duke
    Environmental Law & Policy Forum 10(2): 221-285.

    36

    Segerson, K. and N.Li, 1999. Voluntary Approaches to Environmental Protection.
    Chapter 7 in The International Yearbook of Environmental and Resource
    Economics 1999/2000 (pp.273-306) edited by H. Folmer and T. Tietenberg.
    Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.

    Shleifer, A. and R.W. Vishny. 1998. The Grabbing Hand: Government Pathologies and
    their Cures. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Stavins, Robert N., 2002. Lessons from the American Experience with Market-Based
    Environmental Policies. In Harnessing the Hurricane: The Challenge of Market-
    Based Governance edited by J.D. Donahue and J.S. Nye Jr. New York: Brookings
    Institution Press.

    Stavins, Robert N. and Scott Barrett, 2002. Increasing Participation and Compliance in
    International Climate Change Agreements. FEEM Working Paper No.
    94.2002/Kennedy School of Government Working Paper No. RWP02-031.
    http://www.feem.it/web/activ/ _wp.html 35pp.

    Tahvonen, O. and J. Kuuluvainen. 1995. The Economics of Natural Resource Utilization.
    In Principles of Environmental and Resource Economics: A Guide for Students
    and Decision Makers edited by H. Folmer, H. L. Gabel and H. Opschoor.
    Aldershot: Edward Elgar.

    Tietenberg, Tom, Michael Grubb, Axel Michaelowa, Byron Swift and ZhongXiang
    Zhang, 1998. International Rules for Greenhouse Gas Emissions Trading:
    Defining the Principles, Modalities, Rules and Guidelines for Verification,
    Reporting and Accountability. United Nations Publication
    UNCTAD/GDS/GFSB/Misc.6. As viewed on July 10, 2003 at:
    http://r0.unctad.org/ghg/publications/intl_rules . 123pp. No original date or
    city of publication provided.

    van Kooten, G.C., 2002. Economic Analysis of the Canada-United States Softwood
    Lumber Dispute: Playing the Quota Game, Forest Science 48: 712-721.

    van Kooten, G.C, 1993. Land Resource Economics and Sustainable Development:
    Economic Policies and the Common Good. Vancouver: UBC Press.

    van Kooten, G.C. and E.H. Bulte, 2000. The Economics of Nature. Oxford, UK:
    Blackwell.

    Wiebe, K., A. Tegene and B. Kuhn, 1996. Partial Interests in Land: Policy Tools for
    Resource Use and Conservation. Agricultural Economic Report Number 744,
    Economic Research Service, United States Department of Agriculture,
    Washington DC. 58pp.

    Weitzman, M.L., 1974. Prices vs Quantities, The Review of Economic Studies
    41(October): 477-91.

    37

    Weitzman, M.L., 2002. Land Fees vs Harvest Quotas with Uncertain Fish Stocks,
    Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 43: 325-38.

    Williamson, O.E. 1996. The Mechanisms of Governance. New York: Oxford University
    Press.

    Williamson, O.E. 1998. Transaction Cost Economics: How it Works; Where it is Headed
    De Economist 146: 23-58.

    Woerdman, Edwin., 2002. Implementing the Kyoto Mechanisms: Political Barriers and
    Path Dependency. Ph.D. Dissertation, University of Groningen, The Netherlands.
    620pp. As viewed on 30 July at: http://www.ub.rug.nl/eldoc/dis/jur/e.woerdman.

    Woolcock, M. 1997. Social capital and economic development: Toward a theoretical
    synthesis and policy framework. Theory and Society 27: 151-208.

    World Bank. 2002. Data Profiles & Country at a Glance Tables. As found July 25 at:
    http://www.worldbank.org/data/countrydata/countrydata.html.

    Required Assignment 1

    Due Date

    Friday of Week 8, May 25

    Conceptual Background

    Read Ariagada and Perrings. 2011. Paying for International Environmental Public Goods. Ambio 40:798-806

    Bulte, E., G. van Kooten, and T.Swanson. 2003. Economic Incentives and Wildlife Conservation. Working Paper.

    Assignment

    The intent of the assignment is to ensure that you understand the conceptual framework for the rest of the class.

    4-page paper (typed, double spaced, 12 Arial font, 1” margins) discussing incentives to conserve marine biodiversity within the framework of impure public goods.

    Discuss what an impure public good is, the types of externalities associated with impure public goods, the technology of public good supply (best shot, weakest link, etc.), and the types of economic incentives (positive and negative) that are created for impure public goods with different technologies of public good supply.

    What Will You Get?

    We provide professional writing services to help you score straight A’s by submitting custom written assignments that mirror your guidelines.

    Premium Quality

    Get result-oriented writing and never worry about grades anymore. We follow the highest quality standards to make sure that you get perfect assignments.

    Experienced Writers

    Our writers have experience in dealing with papers of every educational level. You can surely rely on the expertise of our qualified professionals.

    On-Time Delivery

    Your deadline is our threshold for success and we take it very seriously. We make sure you receive your papers before your predefined time.

    24/7 Customer Support

    Someone from our customer support team is always here to respond to your questions. So, hit us up if you have got any ambiguity or concern.

    Complete Confidentiality

    Sit back and relax while we help you out with writing your papers. We have an ultimate policy for keeping your personal and order-related details a secret.

    Authentic Sources

    We assure you that your document will be thoroughly checked for plagiarism and grammatical errors as we use highly authentic and licit sources.

    Moneyback Guarantee

    Still reluctant about placing an order? Our 100% Moneyback Guarantee backs you up on rare occasions where you aren’t satisfied with the writing.

    Order Tracking

    You don’t have to wait for an update for hours; you can track the progress of your order any time you want. We share the status after each step.

    image

    Areas of Expertise

    Although you can leverage our expertise for any writing task, we have a knack for creating flawless papers for the following document types.

    Areas of Expertise

    Although you can leverage our expertise for any writing task, we have a knack for creating flawless papers for the following document types.

    image

    Trusted Partner of 9650+ Students for Writing

    From brainstorming your paper's outline to perfecting its grammar, we perform every step carefully to make your paper worthy of A grade.

    Preferred Writer

    Hire your preferred writer anytime. Simply specify if you want your preferred expert to write your paper and we’ll make that happen.

    Grammar Check Report

    Get an elaborate and authentic grammar check report with your work to have the grammar goodness sealed in your document.

    One Page Summary

    You can purchase this feature if you want our writers to sum up your paper in the form of a concise and well-articulated summary.

    Plagiarism Report

    You don’t have to worry about plagiarism anymore. Get a plagiarism report to certify the uniqueness of your work.

    Free Features $66FREE

    • Most Qualified Writer $10FREE
    • Plagiarism Scan Report $10FREE
    • Unlimited Revisions $08FREE
    • Paper Formatting $05FREE
    • Cover Page $05FREE
    • Referencing & Bibliography $10FREE
    • Dedicated User Area $08FREE
    • 24/7 Order Tracking $05FREE
    • Periodic Email Alerts $05FREE
    image

    Our Services

    Join us for the best experience while seeking writing assistance in your college life. A good grade is all you need to boost up your academic excellence and we are all about it.

    • On-time Delivery
    • 24/7 Order Tracking
    • Access to Authentic Sources
    Academic Writing

    We create perfect papers according to the guidelines.

    Professional Editing

    We seamlessly edit out errors from your papers.

    Thorough Proofreading

    We thoroughly read your final draft to identify errors.

    image

    Delegate Your Challenging Writing Tasks to Experienced Professionals

    Work with ultimate peace of mind because we ensure that your academic work is our responsibility and your grades are a top concern for us!

    Check Out Our Sample Work

    Dedication. Quality. Commitment. Punctuality

    Categories
    All samples
    Essay (any type)
    Essay (any type)
    The Value of a Nursing Degree
    Undergrad. (yrs 3-4)
    Nursing
    2
    View this sample

    It May Not Be Much, but It’s Honest Work!

    Here is what we have achieved so far. These numbers are evidence that we go the extra mile to make your college journey successful.

    0+

    Happy Clients

    0+

    Words Written This Week

    0+

    Ongoing Orders

    0%

    Customer Satisfaction Rate
    image

    Process as Fine as Brewed Coffee

    We have the most intuitive and minimalistic process so that you can easily place an order. Just follow a few steps to unlock success.

    See How We Helped 9000+ Students Achieve Success

    image

    We Analyze Your Problem and Offer Customized Writing

    We understand your guidelines first before delivering any writing service. You can discuss your writing needs and we will have them evaluated by our dedicated team.

    • Clear elicitation of your requirements.
    • Customized writing as per your needs.

    We Mirror Your Guidelines to Deliver Quality Services

    We write your papers in a standardized way. We complete your work in such a way that it turns out to be a perfect description of your guidelines.

    • Proactive analysis of your writing.
    • Active communication to understand requirements.
    image
    image

    We Handle Your Writing Tasks to Ensure Excellent Grades

    We promise you excellent grades and academic excellence that you always longed for. Our writers stay in touch with you via email.

    • Thorough research and analysis for every order.
    • Deliverance of reliable writing service to improve your grades.
    Place an Order Start Chat Now
    image

    Order your essay today and save 30% with the discount code Happy