SOCW 6351

 

For years, many working individuals in the United States have counted on Social Security as their primary retirement income. With the deductions from every paycheck to fund this future benefit, Americans looked forward to a comfortable retirement based on the assumption that these funds were being invested wisely. Is this a factual assumption, or is it another myth of the U.S. social welfare system?

Don't use plagiarized sources. Get Your Custom Essay on
SOCW 6351
Just from $13/Page
Order Essay

Relying on Social Security as a sole means of support in retirement is uncommon. As society’s work habits and life expectancies change, Social Security has come to mean different things to different people. For those who are unable to save and/or invest on their own, it functions like a forced retirement program that provides a financial safety net for the future. For those who become unable to work, social security often is viewed by others as a public assistance program. For others who are financially secure and prepared for retirement, it is an entitlement program where individuals draw Social Security at retirement in an effort to recoup what they paid into the program by deductions from their wages. How might these perceptions of Social Security relate to the perceptions of public assistance programs that were discussed in last week’s resources?

For this Discussion, review this week’s resources. Then, consider how Social Security is different from public assistance programs. Finally, think about how these differences are important in terms of the general perception of Social Security benefits.

By Day 3

Post an explanation of how Social Security is different from public assistance programs. Then, explain how these differences are important, in terms of the general perception of Social Security benefits.

Popple, P. R., & Leighninger, L. (2019). The policy-based profession: An introduction to social welfare policy analysis for social workers (7th ed.). Upper Saddle River, NJ: Pearson Education.

  • Chapter 7, “Aging: Social Security as an Entitlement” (pp. 138-160)

CONGRESS OF THE UNITED STATES
CONGRESSIONAL BUDGET OFFICE

CBO

Social Security

Policy

  • Options
  • JULY 2010

    Pub. No. 4140

    A

    S T U D Y

    CBO

  • Social Security Policy Options
  • July 2010

    The Congress of the United States O Congressional Budget Office

    CBO

  • Notes
  • Unless otherwise noted, all years are calendar years.

    Numbers in the text and tables may not add up to totals because of rounding.

  • Preface
  • Social Security is the federal government’s largest single program, and as the
    U.S. population grows older in the coming decades, its cost is projected to increase more
    rapidly than its revenues. As a result, under current law, resources dedicated to the program
    will become insufficient to pay full benefits in 2039, the Congressional Budget Office (CBO)
    projects. Long-run sustainability for the program could be attained through various
    combinations of raising taxes and cutting benefits; such changes would also affect the
    Social Security taxes paid and the benefits received by various groups of people. This CBO
    study examines a variety of approaches to changing Social Security, updating an earlier work,
    Menu of Social Security Options, which CBO published in May 200

    5.

    In keeping with CBO’s
    mandate to provide objective, impartial analysis, the current study makes no
    recommendations.

    The study was written by Noah Meyerson, Charles Pineles-Mark, and Michael Simpson of
    CBO’s Health and Human Resources Division, under the direction of Joyce Manchester and
    Bruce Vavrichek. Research assistance was provided by Philip Armour, Sarah Axeen, and
    L. Daniel Muldoon. James Baumgardner, Sheila Dacey, Benjamin Page, David Rafferty,
    Jonathan Schwabish, and Julie Topoleski provided helpful comments on earlier drafts.
    Andrew Biggs of the American Enterprise Institute and Paul Van de Water of the Center for
    Budget and Policy Priorities also provided useful comments. (The assistance of external
    reviewers implies no responsibility for the final product, which rests solely with CBO.)

    Kate Kelly edited the manuscript, and Leah Mazade and Sherry Snyder proofread it.
    Maureen Costantino took the cover photograph and designed the cover, and Jeanine Rees
    prepared the study for publication. Jonathan Schwabish provided help with graphics.
    Monte Ruffin produced the initial printed copies, Linda Schimmel coordinated the print
    distribution, and Simone Thomas prepared the electronic version for CBO’s Web site
    (www.cbo.gov).

    Douglas W. Elmendorf
    Director

    July 201

    0

    CBO

    www.cbo.gov

    http://www.cbo.gov/doc.cfm?index=637

    7

    MaureenC
    Doug Elmendorf

  • Contents
  • Summary
  • ix

    Introduction 1

    An Overview of Social Security 1

    Social Security Projections

    4

    Assessing Options for Changing Social Security 7

    Key Elements of Social Security

    8

    Scope of the Options 9

    Effects of the Options on the System’s Finances 11

    Effects of the Options on Payroll Taxes Paid and Benefits Received by
    Various Groups 13

    Effects of the Options on Work and Saving 1

    5

    Options That Would Change the Taxation of Earnings 1

    6

    Option 1: Increase the Payroll Tax Rate by 1 Percentage Point in 2012 17

    Option 2: Increase the Payroll Tax Rate by 2 Percentage Points Over 20 Years 17

    Option 3: Increase the Payroll Tax Rate by 3 Percentage Points Over 60 Years 17

    Option 4: Eliminate the Taxable Maximum 18

    Option 5: Raise the Taxable Maximum to Cover 90 Percent of Earnings 18

    Option 6: Tax Covered Earnings Above the Taxable Maximum;
    Do Not Increase Benefits 18

    Option 7: Tax Covered Earnings Up to $250,000; Do Not Increase Benefits 19

    Option 8: Tax All Earnings Above the Taxable Maximum at 4 Percent;
    Do Not Increase Benefits 19

    Option 9: Tax All Earnings Above $250,000 at 4 Percent;
    Do Not Increase Benefits 19

    Options That Would Change the Benefit Formula

    20

    Option 10: Raise from 35 to 38 the Years of Earnings Included in the AIME 20

    Option 11: Index Earnings in the AIME Formula to Prices 20

    Option 12: Reduce All PIA Factors by 15 Percent 21

    Option 13: Reduce the Top Two PIA Factors by Roughly One Third 21

    Option 14: Reduce the Top PIA Factor by One Third 2

    2

    Option 15: Reduce All PIA Factors by 0.5 Percent Annually 22

    Option 16: Index Initial Benefits to Changes in Longevity 22

    Option 17: Reduce PIA Factors to Index Initial Benefits to Prices Rather
    Than Earnings 23

    CBO

    VI SOCIAL SECURITY POLICY OPTIONS

    CBO

    Option 18: Lower Initial Benefits for the Top 70 Percent of Earners 23

    Option 19: Lower Initial Benefits for the Top 50 Percent of Earners 24

    Option 20: Index the Bend Points in the PIA Formula to Prices 26

    Option 21: Index Earnings in the AIME and Bend Points in the
    PIA Formula to Prices 26

    Option 22: Replace the Current PIA Formula with a New Two Part Formula 26

    Options That Would Increase Benefits for Low Earners 28

    Option 23: Modify the Special Minimum Benefit and Index It to
    Growth in Earnings 28

    Option 24: Introduce a New Poverty Related Minimum Benefit 29

    Option 25: Enhance Low Earners’ Benefits on the Basis of Years Worked 29

    Options That Would Raise the Full Retirement Age

    30

    Option 26: Raise the FRA to 68 31

    Option 27: Raise the FRA to 70 31

    Option 28: Index the FRA to Changes in Longevity 31

    Options That Would Reduce Cost-of-Living Adjustments 31

    Option 29: Reduce COLAs by 0.5 Percentage Points 32

    Option 30: Base COLAs on the Chained CPI U 32

    Appendix: Distributional Effects of Options with Similar Effects on the
    System’s Finances 47

  • Glossary
  • 51

    Options That Would Change the Benefit Formula (Continued)

    CONTENTS SOCIAL SECURITY POLICY OPTIONS VII

  • Tables
  • 1.

    Social Security’s

    Revenues

    and Outlays Under Current Law with
    Scheduled Benefits 6

    2.

    Changes to Social Security’s Finances Under Various Options with
    Scheduled Benefits 33

    3.

    Changes to Social Security’s Scheduled Benefits and Payroll Taxes for
    Different Groups Under Various Options 39

    4.

    Changes to Social Security’s Payable Benefits and Payroll Taxes for
    Different Groups Under Various Options 43

    A 1.

    Changes to Social Security’s Scheduled Benefits and Payroll Taxes for
    Different Groups Under Various Options That Have Similar
    Effects on the System’s Finances 49

  • Figures
  • S 1.

    Effects of the Policy Options on the OASDI Trust Fund Actuarial Balance xi
    1.
    Distribution of Social Security Beneficiaries, by Type of
    Benefits Received, 2010 2
    2.
    U.S. Population Age 65 or Older as a Percentage of the Population
    Ages 20 to 64, 1962 to 2080 4
    3.
    Social Security’s Revenues and Outlays with Scheduled and Payable Benefits 7
    4.
    Projected Outlays for Social Security Under Current Law and with a
    Gradual Reduction in Benefits Starting in 2012 8
    5.
    Effect of Delaying a Payroll Tax Increase or Benefit Reduction on
    Social Security’s Finances 12

    6.

    Calculating the PIA in 2010 Under the Current Social Security System 21

    7.

    Calculating Initial Benefits with Progressive Price Indexing

    25

    8.

    Calculating Initial Benefits with Indexing of Bend Points to Prices 27
    CBO

    Summary

    Social Security, the federal government’s largest
    single program, provides benefits to retired workers
    (through Old Age and Survivors Insurance, OASI), to
    people with disabilities (through Disability Insurance,
    DI), and to their families as well as to some survivors of
    deceased workers. Those benefits are financed primarily
    by payroll taxes collected on people’s earnings. In 2010,
    for the first time since the enactment of the Social Secu
    rity Amendments of 1983, Social Security’s annual out
    lays will exceed its annual tax revenues, the Congressional
    Budget Office (CBO) projects. If the economy continues
    to recover from the recent recession, those tax revenues
    will again exceed outlays, but only for a few years. CBO
    anticipates that starting in 2016, if current laws remain in
    place, the program’s annual spending will regularly exceed
    its tax revenues.

    Social Security’s dedicated revenue stream sets it apart
    from most other federal programs in that the dedicated
    revenues are credited to trust funds that are used to
    finance the program’s activities. Interest on the balances
    of those funds also is credited to the funds (which often
    are treated collectively as the OASDI trust funds). CBO
    estimates that, unless changes are made to the system, the
    trust funds combined will be exhausted in 2039. At that
    point, the resources available to the Social Security
    program will be insufficient to pay full benefits as they
    are currently structured.1

    This CBO study first provides an overview of Social
    Security and discusses some criteria for evaluating
    proposals to change the system. It then presents a variety

    1. See Congressional Budget Office, The Long Term Budget Outlook
    (June 2010), Chapter 3.

    of options for changing the Social Security system and
    analyzes the financial and distributional effects of those
    options—that is, how they would affect Social Security’s
    finances and how they would alter the benefits paid to
    people in various earnings categories and people born in
    various decades.

    The Outlook for Social Security’s
    Finances
    As the population of the United States continues to
    grow older, the number of Social Security beneficiaries
    will continue to rise, and the program’s outlays will
    increase faster than its revenues. Long term projections
    are unavoidably uncertain but, under a broad range of
    assumptions, benefits that are scheduled under current
    law will consistently exceed revenues.

    CBO projects that beginning in 2039 the Social Security
    Administration will not be able to pay those scheduled
    benefits, however. If revenues were not increased, benefits
    would need to be cut by about 20 percent in 2040 to
    equalize outlays and revenues. Those proportionately
    lower payments, which would be made to all Social
    Security recipients once the trust funds were exhausted,
    are known as payable benefits.

    A commonly used summary measure of the system’s long
    term financial condition is the 75 year actuarial bal
    ance—a figure that measures the long term difference
    between the resources dedicated to Social Security and
    the program’s costs under current law. The actuarial bal
    ance is the value of Social Security’s revenues over the
    75 year period, discounted to their value in current dol
    lars, plus the current balance in the OASDI trust funds,

    CBO

    http://www.cbo.gov/doc.cfm?index=11559

    X SOCIAL SECURITY POLICY OPTIONS

    CBO

    minus the present value of future Social Security outlays,
    minus the value of a year’s worth of benefits as a reserve at
    the end of the period.2 CBO estimates the 75 year actuar
    ial balance to be 0.6 percent of gross domestic product
    (GDP); that is, under current law, the resources dedicated
    to financing the program over the next 75 years fall short
    of the benefits that will be owed to beneficiaries by
    about 0.6 percent of GDP.3 That figure is the amount
    by which the Social Security payroll tax would have to
    be raised or scheduled benefits reduced for the system’s
    revenues to be sufficient to cover scheduled benefits. In
    other words, to bring the program into actuarial balance
    over the 75 years, payroll taxes would have to be
    increased immediately by 0.6 percent of GDP and kept
    at that higher rate, or scheduled benefits would have to
    be reduced by an equivalent amount, or some com
    bination of those changes and others would have to be
    implemented.

    The actuarial balance averages the smaller deficits that
    would occur near the beginning of the projection period
    and the larger ones that would occur near the end. In
    2084, scheduled outlays would exceed revenues by
    1.4 percent of GDP.

    Policy Options
    In this study, CBO analyzes 30 options that are among
    those that have been considered by various analysts and
    policymakers as possible components of proposals to pro
    vide long term financial stability for Social Security. The
    options follow the convention of not reducing initial ben
    efits for people who are currently older than 55, and all
    would directly affect outlays for benefits or federal
    revenues dedicated to Social Security.

    2. CBO discounts those values using a real (inflation adjusted)
    discount rate of 3 percent, equal to CBO’s estimated long term
    interest rate used to compute interest credited to the Social
    Security trust funds. The actuarial balance is calculated on the
    basis of Social Security’s scheduled benefits, which are the benefits
    specified under current law without regard to the balances in the
    system’s trust funds. Scheduled benefits are used in this study’s
    analysis of the system’s finances because, by definition, the system
    is in financial balance with payable benefits, which would be set so
    as to eliminate any system deficit.

    3. The projected actuarial balance can also be expressed as
    1.6 percent of taxable payroll.

    The options fall into five categories:

    B Increases in the Social Security payroll tax,

    B Reductions in people’s initial benefits,

    B Increases in benefits for low earners,

    B Increases in the full retirement age, and

    B Reductions in the cost of living adjustments that are
    applied to continuing benefits.

    Each option is analyzed in isolation, although most pro
    posals to make substantial changes to Social Security
    combine several provisions. Many options would interact
    with one another, so combining them might cause
    changes to the overall finances of the system that are
    larger or smaller than would be produced by a simple
    sum of the effects of several discrete options.

    This list of options is far from exhaustive. It does not
    include changes that would draw on general government
    revenues, create individual accounts, or change the trust
    funds’ investments. Other than an increase in the Social
    Security payroll tax, changes to federal tax policy are not
    considered. The options do not include any that apply
    only to people who receive DI benefits, although some of
    the options would affect OASI and DI beneficiaries alike.

    Effects of the Options
    This study analyzes the overall effect of each option on
    the finances of the Social Security system. Some options,
    such as those that would apply the payroll tax rate to all
    earnings or those that would index initial benefits to
    prices, would more than eliminate Social Security’s actu
    arial deficit; others would have far smaller financial effects
    (see Summary Figure 1).

    This study also analyzes the options’ effects on taxes that
    would be paid and benefits that would be received by var
    ious groups of program participants. For that distribu
    tional analysis, participants are grouped by the amount of
    their lifetime household earnings and by their birth
    cohort (that is, by the decade in which they were born).
    Those distributional effects of the options are measured
    relative to the outcomes that would result both from
    scheduled benefits and from payable benefits under
    current law.

    SUMMARY SOCIAL SECURITY POLICY OPTIONS XI

    Summary

    Figure 1.

    Effects of the Policy Options on the OASDI Trust Fund Actuarial Balance

    Source: Congressional Budget Office.

    Notes: The actuarial balance is the present value of revenues plus the OASDI trust fund balance at the beginning of 2010, minus the present

    value of outlays from 2010 to 2084, minus a year’s worth of benefits as a reserve at the end of the period, expressed as a percentage
    of the present value of GDP over the period.
    The AIME for a retired worker who reaches age 62 after 1990 is calculated on the highest 35 years of earnings on which that worker
    paid Social Security taxes (up to the taxable maximum, $106,800 in 2010). Earnings before age 60 are indexed to compensate for
    inflation and for real (inflation-adjusted) growth in wages; earnings after age 59 enter the computations at nominal values. Dividing
    total earnings by 420 (35 years times 12 months) yields the AIME.
    The PIA is the monthly payment to a worker who begins receiving retirement benefits at the full retirement age or to a disabled
    worker who has never received a retirement benefit reduced for age. For workers who turn 62, become disabled, or die in 2010 (for
    calculation of survivor benefits), the PIA formula is 90 percent of the first $761 of the AIME plus 32 percent of the AIME between
    $761 and

    $4,586

    plus 15 percent of the AIME over $4,586. Those percentages constitute the PIA factors.
    A COLA is an annual increase in benefits indexed to consumer prices. Under current law, the COLA equals the percentage increase in
    the CPI-W; the chained CPI-U is an alternative measure of inflation.
    OASDI = Old-Age, Survivors, and Disability Insurance; GDP = gross domestic product; AIME = average indexed monthly earnings;
    PIA = primary insurance amount; FRA = full retirement age; COLA = cost-of-living adjustment; CPI-W = consumer price index
    for all urban wage earners and clerical workers; chained CPI-U = chained CPI for all urban consumers; * = between -0.05 percentage
    points and zero.

    Base COLAs on the Chained CPI-U

    Reduce COLAs by 0.5 Percentage Points

    Index the FRA to Changes in Longevity

    Raise the FRA to 70

    Raise the FRA to 68

    Enhance Low-Earners’ Benefits on the Basis of Years Worked

    Introduce a New Poverty-Related Minimum Benefit

    Modify the Special Minimum Benefit and Index It to Growth in

    Earnings

    Replace the Current PIA Formula with a New Two-Part Formula

    Index Earnings in the AIME and Bend Points in the PIA Formula to Prices

    Index the Bend Points in the PIA Formula to Prices

    Lower Initial Benefits for the Top 50% of Earners

    Lower Initial Benefits for the Top 70% of Earners

    Reduce PIA Factors to Index Initial Benefits to Prices Rather Than Earnings

    Index Initial Benefits to Changes in Longevity

    Reduce All PIA Factors by 0.5% Annually

    Reduce the Top PIA Factor by One-Third

    Reduce the Top Two PIA Factors by Roughly One-Third

    Reduce All PIA Factors by 15%

    Index Earnings in the AIME Formula to Prices

    Raise from 35 to 38 the Years of Earnings Included in the AIME

    Tax All Earnings Above $250,000 at 4%; Do Not Increase Benefits

    Tax All Earnings Above the Taxable Maximum at 4%; Do Not Increase Benefits

    Tax Covered Earnings Up to $250,000; Do Not Increase Benefits

    Tax Covered Earnings Above the Taxable Maximum; Do Not Increase Benefits

    Raise the Taxable Maximum to Cover 90% of Earnings

    Eliminate the Taxable Maximum

    Increase the Payroll Tax Rate by 3 Percentage Points Over 60 Years

    Increase the Payroll Tax Rate by 2 Percentage Points Over 20 Years

    Increase the Payroll Tax Rate by 1 Percentage Point in 2012

    0.3

    0.6

    0.5

    0.6

    0.2

    0.9

    0.5
    0.3

    0.1

    0.1
    0.2
    0.5

    0.7

    0.1

    0.4

    0.2
    0.5
    0.4
    0.5
    0.6
    0.2

    -0.2

    -0.3

    0.1
    0.3
    0.2
    0.3
    0.2

    1.0

    *

    Change the
    Taxation of

    Earnings

    Change the
    Benefit Formula

    Increase Benefits
    for Low Earners

    Raise the Full
    Retirement Age

    Reduce Cost-of-Living
    Adjustments

    0.3
    0.6
    0.5
    0.6
    0.2
    0.9
    0.5
    0.3
    0.1
    0.1
    0.2
    0.5
    0.7
    0.1
    0.4
    0.2
    0.5
    0.4
    0.5
    0.6
    0.2
    -0.2
    -0.3
    0.1
    0.3
    0.2
    0.3
    0.2
    1.0
    *
    Change the
    Taxation of
    Earnings
    Change the
    Benefit Formula
    Increase Benefits
    for Low Earners
    Raise the Full
    Retirement Age
    Reduce Cost-of-Living
    Adjustments
    CBO

    XII SOCIAL SECURITY POLICY OPTIONS

    CBO

    Some options, such as an across the board increase in the
    payroll tax rate or a flat reduction in benefits, would
    affect all participants proportionately, but some options
    would have disparate effects on people in different earn
    ings groups. For example, some options would primarily
    affect people with higher lifetime earnings by placing an
    additional tax on earnings above a threshold or by
    increasing the progressivity of the Social Security benefit
    formula.

    Many options with similar financial effects in the
    aggregate would affect older and younger generations
    differently. In particular, the timing of the changes would
    affect their impact on different generations (as well as the

    magnitude of the change necessary to bring the system
    into balance). Some options, such as one that would
    reduce benefits by a flat 15 percent, would take effect in a
    single year and would affect all future beneficiaries the
    same way. Others would be phased in and, initially,
    would have only small effects. For example, a policy that
    gradually reduced benefits would have a much larger
    effect on people whose benefits began in 2040 than it
    would on those whose benefits began in 2020. Raising
    tax rates would increase the amounts paid by younger
    people but make little difference in the sum of taxes paid
    over a lifetime by people who already have left or are
    about to leave the workforce.

    Social Security Policy Options

    Introduction
    The federal government levies taxes on workers to pro
    vide Social Security benefits to the elderly, to disabled
    people, and to their families as well as to some survivors
    of deceased workers. Although the program is part of the
    overall federal budget, its funding differs from that of
    many other programs in the budget: Its spending is
    financed from two trust funds that are credited with the
    dedicated tax revenues and from which benefits may be
    paid, without further legislative action, as long as the
    trust funds have sufficient balances.1 The balances that
    exist today—more that $2 trillion—have accumulated
    over many years, during which tax revenues credited to
    the trust funds exceeded the benefit payments from
    those funds. Interest on the balances is credited to the
    trust funds.

    In 2010, for the first time since the enactment of the
    Social Security Amendments of 1983, the Congressional
    Budget Office (CBO) projects that Social Security’s
    annual outlays will exceed its annual revenues, excluding
    interest credited to the trust funds. As the baby boom
    generation (the group of people born between 1946 and
    1964) continues to age, the number of Social Security
    beneficiaries will increase, and outlays will rise faster than
    revenues. In part because of this growth, the federal bud
    get is on an unsustainable path: Without significant
    changes in government policy, in coming decades the
    aging of the population and rising health care costs will
    boost federal outlays sharply relative to the size of the
    economy under any plausible assumptions about future
    trends in the economy, demographics, and health care
    costs.2 Also because of the growing number of Social
    Security beneficiaries, CBO projects that, under current
    law, the Social Security trust funds will be exhausted in

    1. Spending for Social Security benefits and receipts from Social
    Security taxes are part of the unified federal budget but are
    categorized as “off budget” for certain budget enforcement
    procedures.

    2039. Thereafter, the Social Security Administration
    will not have the legal authority to pay the full benefits
    specified in law.

    This study analyzes the effects of 30 options for changing
    Social Security. The options are among those commonly
    proposed by policymakers and analysts for bringing long
    term financial stability to the program.3 This study
    describes the options’ effects on the finances of the Social
    Security system, on the taxes the program’s participants
    pay, and on the benefits participants receive. Participants
    are grouped by their lifetime household earnings and
    birth cohort (that is, by the decade of their birth).

    An Overview of Social Security
    The Social Security Act of 1935 created the federal gov
    ernment’s largest single program. Currently, 53 million
    people receive Social Security benefits, and, although
    Social Security is commonly thought of as a retirement
    program, only 69 percent of its beneficiaries are retired
    workers, their spouses, and children (see Figure 1).
    Another 12 percent of beneficiaries are survivors of
    deceased workers, and the remaining 19 percent are peo
    ple who are receiving Disability Insurance (DI) benefits

    2. See Congressional Budget Office, The Long Term Budget Outlook
    (June 2010).

    3. CBO presented an analysis of various long term Social Security
    options in Menu of Social Security Options (May 25, 2005).
    Versions of some of the options presented in this study also were
    discussed in Congressional Budget Office, Budget Options,
    Volume 2 (August 2009). The Chief Actuary of the Social Security
    Administration has published a list of policy options that would
    address the solvency of the Social Security trust funds and other
    issues related to Social Security benefits and financing. That
    document, Individual Changes Modifying Social Security, is
    available at www.ssa.gov/OACT/solvency/provisions/index.html.
    The Social Security Administration’s Office of Retirement and
    Disability Policy has published a series of policy briefs that analyze
    the distributional effects of various options, available at
    www.ssa.gov/policy/docs/policybriefs/index.html.

    CBO

    http://www.cbo.gov/ftpdocs/63xx/doc6377/Social_Security_Menu-CBO_baseline

    http://www.cbo.gov/ftpdocs/102xx/doc10294/08-06-BudgetOptions

    http://www.ssa.gov/OACT/solvency/provisions/index.html

    http://www.ssa.gov/policy/docs/policybriefs/index.html

    http://www.cbo.gov/doc.cfm?index=11559

    2 SOCIAL SECURITY POLICY OPTIONS

    CBO
    Figure 1.

    Distribution of Social Security
    Beneficiaries, by Type of Benefits
    Received, 20

    10

    Sources: Congressional Budget Office; Social Security
    Administration, data for May 2010.

    as disabled workers or who are the spouses and children
    of disabled workers. Social Security is an important
    source of income for the elderly. In 2008, almost 90 per
    cent of people over age 65 received Social Security bene
    fits. Among the population age 65 or older, those benefits
    were the major source of income (providing at least
    50 percent of total income) for 57 percent of families and
    90 percent or more of income for almost a third of such
    families.4 Consequently, if Social Security benefits were
    reduced, many people would respond by working and
    saving more. The responses would be greater if such
    reductions were announced well in advance of the
    changes.

    Social Security now consists of two parts: Old Age and
    Survivors Insurance (OASI), which pays benefits to
    retired workers and their dependents and to survivors of
    deceased workers; and Disability Insurance, which pays
    benefits to workers who become disabled when they are

    4. See Social Security Administration, “Income Sources,” in Income
    of the Aged Chartbook, 2008, www.ssa.gov/policy/docs/
    chartbooks/income_aged/2008/iac08.html#income.

    Retired Workers

    Disabled Workers

    Spouses and
    Children of

    Disabled Workers
    Survivors of
    Deceased
    Workers

    Spouses and
    Children of
    Retired Workers

    (5%)

    (12%)

    (15%)

    (4%)

    (64%)

    younger than the full retirement age (FRA, the age at
    which people can receive unreduced retirement benefits)
    and to their dependents. Old Age and Survivors Insur
    ance currently accounts for 82 percent of benefits, and
    Disability Insurance accounts for 18 percent. CBO pro
    jects that outlays for the program in fiscal year 2010 will
    total $708 billion, roughly one fifth of the federal bud
    get. Since 1989, administrative expenses have totaled
    1 percent or less of program outlays.

    During the program’s first four decades, spending for
    Social Security benefits increased significantly relative to
    the size of the economy, reaching about 4 percent of gross
    domestic product (GDP) in the mid 1970s. The costs
    spiked to nearly 5 percent of GDP in the early 1980s, the
    period that saw the most recent major legislative changes
    to the program. In the 1990s and early 2000s, spending
    for Social Security benefits fluctuated between 4.1 per
    cent and 4.6 percent of GDP. During the recent eco
    nomic downturn, GDP contracted and Social Security
    outlays increased more rapidly than they would have with
    stable economic growth because the number of OASI and
    DI claimants increased as the job market deteriorated.
    Social Security’s outlays rose to 4.8 percent of GDP in
    2009, and CBO projects they will remain at that level
    in 2010.

    Taxes. Social Security has two primary sources of dedi
    cated tax revenues: payroll taxes and taxes on benefits.
    Roughly 97 percent of dedicated tax revenues are col
    lected from a payroll tax of 12.4 percent that is levied on
    earnings and split evenly by workers and their employers
    at 6.2 percent apiece. Self employed workers pay the
    entire 12.4 percent tax on earnings themselves. The pay
    roll tax applies only to taxable earnings—earnings up to a
    maximum annual amount ($106,800 in 2010).

    Taxable

    earnings are about 83 percent of total covered earnings,
    which are all earnings—from wages and from self
    employment income—for employment covered by Social
    Security. In addition, some Social Security benefits are
    subject to taxation: In 2009, about 3 percent of Social
    Security’s dedicated tax revenues came from the income
    taxes that higher income beneficiaries paid on their Social
    Security benefits.

    Benefits. In general, workers are eligible to receive
    Social Security retirement benefits if they are age 62 or
    older and have paid a sufficient amount of Social Security

    http://www.ssa.gov/policy/docs/chartbooks/income_aged/2008/iac08.html#income

    SOCIAL SECURITY POLICY OPTIONS 3

    taxes for at least 10 years.5 Retirement benefits are
    reduced for workers who begin to collect Social Security
    before reaching the full retirement age, currently 66.
    Workers who are judged unable to perform substantial
    work because of a physical or mental disability can
    become eligible for DI benefits at an earlier age and, in
    many cases, with a shorter employment history. Various
    rules for determining eligibility and benefits apply to
    family members of retired, disabled, or deceased workers.

    When retired or disabled workers first claim Social
    Security benefits, payments are based on their average
    lifetime earnings. The formula used to translate average
    earnings into benefits is progressive; that is, the replace
    ment rate—the ratio of benefits received to a worker’s
    past earnings—is higher for people with lower average
    earnings than for people with higher earnings. The Social
    Security Administration estimates that workers who had
    average annual earnings throughout their careers and who
    claim benefits in 2010 at age 65 will be eligible for an
    annual benefit of about $16,500, an amount that will
    replace about 40 percent of their average preretirement
    earnings.

    For the purpose of calculating average earnings to deter
    mine the initial benefit, the amounts earned in earlier
    years are converted to current year values based on
    changes in average annual earnings in the economy as a
    whole. Because average national earnings are projected to
    grow faster than inflation, that indexation will cause aver
    age initial benefits to grow in real (inflation adjusted)
    terms and will keep the average replacement rate stable.
    (In later decades, the replacement rate will be slightly
    lower for workers with average earnings who claim bene
    fits at age 65, mainly because of the scheduled increase in
    the full retirement age.)

    An adjustment is made to retirement benefits on the basis
    of the age at which a recipient chooses to start claiming
    benefits: The longer someone waits (up to age 70), the
    higher the benefits will be. That adjustment is intended
    to be actuarially fair, so that a person’s total lifetime bene
    fits will have an approximately equal value regardless of
    the age at which he or she begins collecting them. For all

    5. Most workers need to earn 40 credits (each credit is known as
    “a quarter of coverage”) to be eligible for retirement benefits.
    Workers can earn up to four credits per year on the basis of the
    amount they earn for employment that is covered under the
    program. In 2010, one credit is earned for each $1,120 in wages,
    so any worker who earns at least $4,480 will receive four credits
    for the year.

    types of benefits, a cost of living adjustment (COLA) is
    made each year after the initial benefits are received to
    keep pace with annual changes in consumer prices.6

    Trust Funds. Revenues from payroll taxes and from taxes
    on benefits, along with intragovernmental interest pay
    ments, are credited to the two Social Security trust
    funds—one for OASI and one for DI. The program’s
    benefits and administrative costs are paid from those
    funds. Legally, the two funds are separate, but they often
    are described collectively as the OASDI trust funds.

    Federal trust funds, including those for Social Security,
    essentially constitute an accounting mechanism. In a
    given year, the sum of receipts to a fund along with the
    interest that might be credited on previous balances, less
    spending for benefits and administrative costs, constitutes
    a fund’s surplus or deficit. The cash generated by a sur
    plus in any year is turned over to the Treasury in
    exchange for special Treasury securities. The Treasury
    uses the cash to finance the government’s ongoing activi
    ties. If the trust funds’ cash receipts are less than their
    outlays, the Treasury securities they hold are redeemed for
    cash as needed. The Treasury obtains that cash from
    other revenues or by borrowing from the public.

    The trust funds are part of the federal government, so
    transactions between Social Security and the Treasury are
    intragovernmental and have no net effect on federal bor
    rowing from the public or on the unified budget. Any
    increase in revenues credited to the trust funds or
    decrease in outlays from the funds makes available addi
    tional cash that can be used to finance other government
    activities without requiring new government borrowing
    from the public; the trust fund surpluses that were gener
    ated in previous years have been used in that way. Simi
    larly, any increase in outlays or decrease in revenues for
    the OASDI trust funds in some future year will represent
    a draw on the government’s cash in that year. Thus, the
    balances in the OASDI trust funds (in the form of
    government securities) are an asset to the Social Security

    6. Social Security benefits are indexed to inflation as measured by the
    consumer price index for urban wage earners and clerical workers
    (CPI W). The Social Security Administration generally adjusts
    benefits paid in January on the basis of the change in the CPI W
    through the third quarter of the previous calendar year. If the
    resulting adjustment is negative, no COLA is given. The next
    COLA is made when the CPI W for the third quarter of the
    calendar year exceeds the CPI W for the third quarter of the last
    year in which an adjustment occurred.

    CBO

    4 SOCIAL SECURITY POLICY OPTIONS

    CBO

    Figure 2.

    U.S. Population Age 65 or Older as a Percentage of the Population Ages 20 to 64,
    1962 to

    2080

    (Percent)

    Sources: Congressional Budget Office; Social Security Administration.

    1962 1970 1978 1986 1994 2002 2010 2018 2026 2034 2042 2050 2058 2066 2074

    0
    5
    10

    15

    20
    25
    30

    35

    40

    45

    Actual Projected

    system but a liability to the rest of the government. The
    resources to redeem government securities in the OASDI
    trust funds and thereby pay for Social Security benefits in
    some future year must be generated from taxes, other
    government income, or government borrowing in that
    year.

    Social Security Projections
    Under current law, the cost of Social Security benefits will
    escalate in coming decades.7 Economic growth leads to
    higher average benefits because benefits are based on past
    earnings. In addition, changes in the nation’s demo
    graphic structure will cause total benefits to grow faster
    than the economy: As the baby boom generation reaches
    retirement age, and as decreasing mortality leads to

    7. This study uses projections for Social Security as published in
    Congressional Budget Office, The Long Term Budget Outlook,
    Chapter 3, based on An Analysis of the President’s Budgetary
    Proposals for Fiscal Year 2011 (March 2010). Future revenues from
    income taxes on benefits will depend on future income tax rates.
    The projections used here reflect the assumptions underlying the
    extended baseline scenario published in The Long Term Budget
    Outlook, namely, that income tax law does not change and income
    taxes on benefits grow as a share of Social Security benefits
    throughout the 75 year projection period. Under that report’s
    alternative fiscal scenario, in contrast, income taxes on benefits are
    assumed to remain a constant share of benefits after 2020. As a
    result, projected Social Security revenues are slightly lower under
    the alternative fiscal scenario.

    longer lives and longer retirements, a larger share of the
    population will be drawing Social Security benefits.8

    Rising Cost of Benefits. Between now and 2035, the
    number of people age 65 or older will increase by about
    90 percent, compared with an increase of more than
    10 percent in the number of people between the ages of
    20 and 64, CBO projects. Today, that older population is
    one fifth the size of the younger population; at those
    growth rates, it will be more than one third the size of the
    younger group by 2035 (see Figure 2). In 2035, about
    93 million people will collect Social Security benefits,
    compared with 53 million today, and the average benefit
    will have grown nearly as rapidly as GDP per person.

    As more baby boomers begin collecting benefits, spend
    ing for the program will climb from 4.8 percent of GDP
    in 2010 to 6.2 percent of GDP in 2035, CBO projects.
    Spending as a share of GDP will decline slightly over the
    15 years after that, to 5.9 percent of GDP, as an
    increasing number of baby boomers die. However,

    8. Expectations regarding how the baby boomers will fare financially
    in retirement are summarized in Congressional Budget Office,
    The Retirement Prospects of the Baby Boomers, Issue Brief (March
    18, 2004); for additional details, see Baby Boomers’ Retirement
    Prospects: An Overview (November 2003) and Will the Demand for
    Assets Fall When the Baby Boomers Retire? Background Paper
    (September 2009).

    http://www.cbo.gov/doc.cfm?index=11559

    http://www.cbo.gov/ftpdocs/112xx/doc11280/03-24-apb

    http://www.cbo.gov/ftpdocs/51xx/doc5195/03-18-BabyBoomers

    http://www.cbo.gov/ftpdocs/48xx/doc4863/11-26-BabyBoomers

    http://www.cbo.gov/ftpdocs/105xx/doc10526/09-08_Baby-Boomers

    SOCIAL SECURITY POLICY OPTIONS 5

    demographers generally anticipate that life expectancy
    will continue to increase, and CBO projects that Social
    Security outlays will resume their upward trajectory rela
    tive to GDP after 2050, reaching 6.3 percent in 2080.9

    The aging of the population is primarily responsible for
    the growth in Social Security’s outlays as a percentage of
    GDP. If the age distribution of the population remained
    constant, Social Security outlays would decline slightly,
    from 4.8 percent of GDP today to 4.3 percent of GDP in
    2035 and remain approximately at that level thereafter;
    the decline would occur because the full retirement age
    will continue to rise under current law, effectively reduc
    ing benefits. Social Security’s total benefits would remain
    a generally constant share of GDP in the absence of aging
    because scheduled benefits are indexed to growth in earn
    ings and (after initial benefits are received) to inflation. If
    that indexation were changed in certain ways, average
    benefits could be significantly lower than those under
    current law. For example, if initial benefits grew at the
    same rate as average prices (rather than at the same rate as
    average wages as they do under current law), average ben
    efits—and thus total outlays—would be one third lower
    by 2060 and one half lower by 2080. Alternatively, if
    continuing benefits were increased by a smaller COLA
    than provided under current law, average benefits would
    be smaller. CBO estimates that, in years after 2040, more
    than 25 percent of the benefit payments under current
    law will be the result of COLAs provided between now
    and then.

    Worsening System Finances. CBO projects that, in 2010,
    for the first time since the Social Security reforms of the
    early 1980s, benefit payments from the trust funds will
    exceed trust fund receipts from the public. Receipts from
    the public consist mostly of revenues from payroll taxes
    and exclude interest on Treasury securities held by the
    trust funds. As the economy recovers from the recent
    recession, receipts will again exceed benefit payments, but
    only until 2016. If benefits are paid as specified under
    current law, outlays will exceed revenues by 0.3 percent of

    9. For details on CBO’s methodology for projecting Social Security’s
    revenues and outlays, see Congressional Budget Office,
    CBO’s Long Term Projections for Social Security: 2009 Update
    (August 2009), p. 4.

    GDP in 2020, CBO projects, and by 1.0 percent to
    1.3 percent between 2040 and 2080 (see Table 1).

    Trust Fund Exhaustion. CBO projects that the Disability
    Insurance Trust Fund will be exhausted in fiscal year
    2018, with the sum of the balance in the fund at the
    beginning of the year and projected revenue in that year
    falling $15 billion below projected expenditures. Once
    the trust fund balance has fallen to zero and current reve
    nues are insufficient to cover the benefits that are speci
    fied in current law, the DI program will be unable to
    meet its obligations fully without changes in law. CBO
    projects that the Old Age and Survivors Insurance Trust
    Fund will be exhausted in 2042.

    The DI trust fund has been close to exhaustion before.
    The 1994 Annual Report of the Social Security Board of
    Trustees projected that the DI trust fund would be
    exhausted in 1995.10 That outcome was prevented by leg
    islation that redirected revenue from the OASI trust fund
    to the DI trust fund. In part because of that experience, it
    is a common analytical convention to consider the DI
    and OASI trust funds as combined, and CBO projects
    that, if legislation to shift resources from the OASI trust
    fund to the DI trust fund was enacted, the combined
    OASDI trust funds would be exhausted in 2039.

    Scheduled and Payable Benefits. Benefits as calculated
    under the Social Security Act, regardless of the balances in
    the trust funds, are known as scheduled benefits.11 How
    ever, the Social Security Administration lacks authority
    to pay scheduled benefits if those payments would
    exceed the available balances. If the trust funds became
    exhausted, payments to beneficiaries would be reduced or
    otherwise modified as necessary to make outlays from the

    10. See Board of Trustees of the Federal Old Age and Survivors
    Insurance and Disability Insurance Trust Funds, 1994 Annual
    Report, 78 187 (April 11, 1994), www.ssa.gov/history/reports/
    trust/1994/1994 .

    11. CBO prepares cost estimates for legislation under the assumption
    that scheduled payments will be made, which is consistent with a
    long standing statutory requirement that CBO, in its baseline
    projections, assume that laws are implemented as specified and
    that funding for entitlement programs is adequate to make all
    payments. See section 257 of the Balanced Budget and Emergency
    Deficit Control Act of 1985, Public Law 99 177, as amended;
    2 U.S.C. 907.

    CBO

    http://www.cbo.gov/ftpdocs/104xx/doc10457/08-07-SocialSecurity_Update

    http://www.ssa.gov/history/reports/trust/1994/1994

    6 SOCIAL SECURITY POLICY OPTIONS

    CBO

    Table 1.

    Social Security’s Revenues and Outlays Under Current Law with
    Scheduled Benefits
    (Percentage of GDP)

    Source: Congressional Budget Office.

    Notes: The 75-year period is 2010 through 2084. Revenues consist of payroll taxes and income taxes on benefits (but not interest credited to
    the trust funds) in the specified year. Outlays consist of Social Security benefits and administrative costs. The balance is the surplus or
    deficit, which is the difference between revenues and outlays. The 75-year present value of revenues includes the current Old-Age,
    Survivors, and Disability Insurance trust fund balance. The 75-year present value of outlays includes a year’s worth of benefits as a
    reserve at the end of the period.

    GDP = gross domestic product.

    Revenues 4.9 4.9 4.9 4.9 5.0 5.2 14.4
    Outlays 4.8 5.2 6.2 6.0 6.3 5.8 16.0
    Balance 0.1 -0.3 -1.3 -1.1 -1.3 -0.6 -1.6

    75-Year Present Value

    Taxable
    2060

    Payroll

    as a

    Percentage of

    20802020
    Actual
    2009 GDP2040

    funds equal revenues to the funds.12 Benefits reduced or
    modified in that way are known as payable benefits. Under
    those circumstances, all receipts to the trust funds would
    be used and the trust fund balance would remain essen
    tially at zero.

    In 2040, CBO projects, payroll tax revenues and revenues
    from the taxation of benefits will be 80 percent of sched
    uled benefits for OASI and DI. At that time, payable
    benefits will be 20 percent lower than scheduled benefits
    for all beneficiaries. By 2084, the gap between scheduled
    and payable benefits will be 24 percent, CBO estimates
    (see Figure 3).

    Cutting scheduled benefits or raising Social Security taxes
    during the next few decades would extend the solvency of
    the OASDI trust funds. For example, under a policy
    option with a gradual reduction in benefits such as a
    reduction in cost of living adjustments by 0.5 percent
    annually starting in 2012, the trust fund exhaustion date
    would be extended by nine years to 2048—such that

    12. See Kathleen Romig, Social Security: What Would Happen If the
    Trust Funds Ran Out? Report for Congress RL33514
    (Congressional Research Service, Updated April 25, 2008). The
    report notes the entitlement created under the Social Security Act,
    cites other law that prohibits officials from making expenditures
    in excess of available funds, and acknowledges that the two create
    a potential conflict that must be resolved by the Congress or in the
    courts.

    benefits from 2039 through 2048 would be higher than
    payable benefits under current law (see Figure 4).

    Actuarial Balance. A commonly used measure of the sus
    tainability of a program that has a trust fund and a dedi
    cated revenue source is its actuarial balance, a single
    measure of the difference between the trust fund’s
    resources and projected expenditures over a specified
    period. The actuarial balance is calculated as the present
    value of projected revenues, plus the trust fund balance at
    the beginning of the period, minus the present value of
    projected outlays and the cost of maintaining a reserve
    equal to a year’s worth of benefits at the end of the
    period, expressed as a percentage of the present value of
    GDP or (in the case of Social Security) as a percentage
    of taxable payroll over the same period. CBO estimates
    that over the 75 year period from 2010 to 2084, dedi
    cated revenues for Social Security will fall short of sched
    uled benefits by 0.6 percent of GDP, assuming a real
    interest rate of 3 percent (see Table 1). (As a percentage of
    taxable payroll—the amount of earnings subject to the
    Social Security payroll tax—the shortfall is 1.6 percent.)

    Thus, to bring the program into actuarial balance over
    the 75 year period—that is, for the system’s projected rev
    enues to be sufficient to cover the benefits prescribed by
    current law—payroll taxes could be increased immedi
    ately by 0.6 percent of GDP and kept at that higher rate,
    or scheduled benefits could be reduced by an equivalent
    amount, to give two examples. (Such an increase in

    SOCIAL SECURITY POLICY OPTIONS 7

    Figure 3.

    Social Security’s Revenues and Outlays with Scheduled and Payable Benefits
    (Percentage of gross domestic product)

    Source: Congressional Budget Office.

    Note: Revenues consist of payroll taxes and income taxes on benefits (but not interest credited to the trust funds). Outlays consist of Social
    Security benefits and administrative costs. Benefits as calculated under the Social Security Act, regardless of the balances in the trust
    funds, are known as scheduled benefits. If the trust funds became exhausted, payments to beneficiaries would be reduced to make
    outlays from the funds equal revenues to the funds; such benefits are known as payable benefits. In that case, total revenues would
    decline slightly because revenues from taxation of benefits would decline.

    1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 2020 2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 2050 2055 2060 2065 2070 2075 2080
    0
    4

    5
    6
    7

    Outlays with Payable Benefits

    Actual Projected

    Outlays with Scheduled Benefits

    Outlays

    Revenues

    payroll taxes would generate about 13 percent more reve
    nue than the amount projected under current law.) More
    generally, a combination of tax and benefit changes that
    in combination improved the 75 year actuarial balance
    by 0.6 percent of GDP could be implemented over time.

    Trust Fund Ratio. Another common measure of Social
    Security’s finances is the ratio of the trust fund balance to
    the program’s annual outlays. That calculation indicates
    how many years’ worth of benefits could be financed by a
    given balance if outlays per year remained the same. The
    trust fund ratio for 2010—the balance in the Social
    Security trust funds at the beginning of the year divided
    by projected 2010 outlays for the program—was 3.6,
    CBO estimates. The ratio is projected to peak in 2010
    and then to decline quickly until the trust funds are
    exhausted in 2039.

    Sustainable Solvency. Some analysts suggest that changes
    to Social Security should have two financial objectives:
    balancing the system’s finances over the 75 year projec
    tion period and putting the system on a sustainable path
    thereafter, a goal known as sustainable solvency.13 The
    actuarial balance, as a single number, usefully summarizes
    the entire stream of revenues and outlays over the 75 year
    period (after adjusting for the starting balance in the trust

    funds), but it does not convey any information about
    whether the pattern of annual finances is sustainable
    beyond 75 years. A proposal that would attain sustainable
    solvency would produce positive trust fund ratios
    throughout the 75 year projection period as well as stable
    or rising ratios at the end of the period.

    Assessing Options for Changing
    Social Security
    In this study, CBO examines 30 options for altering vari
    ous elements of Social Security that have been considered
    by various analysts and policymakers. The options mostly
    involve changes to the system’s current structure that
    would have a marked influence on Social Security’s
    finances. Several criteria can be applied to analyze the var
    ious options’ effects. This study considers how the
    options would affect Social Security’s finances over time
    and discusses distributional outcomes, such as the
    amount of taxes collected from or the amount of benefits

    13. See, for example, Social Security Administration, Report of the
    1994–1996 Advisory Council on Social Security, Volume I: Findings
    and Recommendations (January 1997), www.ssa.gov/history/
    reports/adcouncil/report/toc.htm.

    CBO

    http://www.ssa.gov/history/reports/adcouncil/report/toc.htm

    8 SOCIAL SECURITY POLICY OPTIONS

    CBO

    Figure 4.

    Projected Outlays for Social Security Under Current Law and with a
    Gradual Reduction in Benefits Starting in 2012
    (Percentage of gross domestic product)

    Source: Congressional Budget Office.

    Note: Outlays consist of Social Security benefits and administrative costs. Benefits as calculated under the Social Security Act, regardless of
    the balances in the trust funds, are known as scheduled benefits. If the trust funds became exhausted, payments to beneficiaries
    would be reduced to make outlays from the funds equal revenues to the funds; such benefits are known as payable benefits. The
    gradual reduction in benefits would begin in 2012, reducing cost-of-living adjustments by 0.5 percent annually.

    1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 2020 2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 2050 2055 2060 2065 2070 2075 2080
    0
    4
    5
    6

    7
    Actual Projected

    With Payable Benefits Assuming
    Gradual Reduction in Benefits

    With Scheduled Benefits
    Under

    Current Law

    With Payable Benefits
    Under Current Law

    paid to people in different groups according to lifetime
    earnings or year of birth. Changes in economic incentives
    also are important; they are discussed below, although
    they are not analyzed in detail.

    Key Elements of Social Security
    Each policy option would alter at least one significant
    element of Social Security that determines its revenues or
    outlays under current law. Descriptions of the key
    elements appear below.

    Payroll Taxes. Several options would affect the amount of
    Social Security payroll taxes people would pay. The cur
    rent system operates as follows:

    B Tax Rate. Employers and employees each pay half of
    the 12.4 percent payroll tax (self employed people pay
    the entire amount).

    B Taxable Maximum. The payroll tax is imposed on
    earnings up to a maximum that increases as average
    earnings rise. In 2010, that taxable maximum is
    $106,800.

    Benefit Formula. Social Security benefits are determined
    by a formula that constructs summary measures of life
    time earnings. That formula has several key elements:

    B Average Indexed Monthly Earnings. Social Security
    benefits are determined by earnings over a person’s
    lifetime, expressed as average indexed monthly earn
    ings (AIME). For anyone who reaches age 62 after
    1990, the total earnings amount is calculated based on
    earnings that are subject to Social Security taxes, using
    the highest 35 years of those earnings. For retirees,
    earnings before age 60 are indexed to compensate both
    for inflation and for economywide real growth in
    earnings; earnings at age 60 and later enter the com
    putations at their actual amounts. For disabled work
    ers, earnings in the two years before initial benefit
    computation enter at their actual amounts, and earlier
    earnings are indexed. For retirees, dividing the result
    ing value for total earnings by 420 (35 years multi
    plied by 12 months) yields the AIME.

    B Primary Insurance Amount. The primary insurance
    amount (PIA) is the monthly amount payable to a
    worker who begins to receive Social Security retire
    ment benefits at the age at which he or she is eligible

    SOCIAL SECURITY POLICY OPTIONS 9

    for full benefits or the amount payable to a disabled
    worker who has never received a retirement benefit.
    For workers who turn 62 or become disabled in 2010,
    for all of their dependents, and for dependents of
    workers who die in 2010, the PIA is calculated as
    90 percent of the first $761 of the AIME, plus 32 per
    cent of the AIME between $761 and $4,586, plus
    15 percent of the AIME above $4,586. Actual
    monthly benefits paid to retired workers and their
    dependents differ from the PIA if an individual claims
    retirement benefits prior to or later than his or her full
    retirement age.

    B PIA Factors. The rates by which the components of the
    AIME are multiplied—90 percent, 32 percent, and
    15 percent—are the PIA factors. The PIA formula is
    progressive; it replaces a larger share of preretirement
    earnings for people with lower average earnings than it
    does for people with higher earnings.

    B Bend Point. The threshold at which a PIA factor
    changes is called a bend point. Under current law,
    there are two: In 2010, they are $761 and $4,586. The
    bend points change every year with changes in the
    average annual earnings for the workforce as a whole.
    Consequently, bend points occur at approximately the
    same place in the distribution of the AIMEs each year
    (the 11th and 71st percentiles, respectively, of AIMEs
    for people who are age 62 and eligible for OASI bene
    fits in 2010), and average initial benefits rise at a pace
    that matches the increase in average earnings over
    time.

    Special Minimum Benefits for Low Earners. Beneficiaries
    receive the larger of the standard benefit or a special min
    imum benefit. For people who had very low earnings for
    more than 10 years, the special minimum benefit is
    sometimes larger than the standard benefit. The special
    minimum benefit increases over time, keeping pace with
    prices. Because the standard benefit formula increases
    with earnings, which tend to grow faster than prices, the
    special minimum benefit affects fewer people every year;
    it is projected to have no effect on beneficiaries who
    become eligible to collect benefits after 2010.

    Full Retirement Age. Social Security’s full retirement age,
    also called the “normal retirement age,” is the age at
    which someone is eligible to receive full retirement bene
    fits. For workers born before 1938, the FRA is 65. Under
    current law, the FRA is increasing gradually; it will be

    67 for people born in 1960 or later. The age at which
    workers may start receiving reduced benefits—age 62—
    remains the same. For each year that a worker claims ben
    efits before reaching the FRA, benefits are reduced by an
    amount that ranges from 5 percent to 6 2/3 percent. For
    most current new beneficiaries, benefits are increased by
    8 percent for each year after the FRA that initial receipt
    of benefits is delayed, until age 70. (The increase is less
    than 8 percent for people born before 1943.)14

    Cost-of-Living Adjustments. At the end of each year, the
    Social Security Administration adjusts each beneficiary’s
    PIA by an amount that is equal to any increase in the
    consumer price index for urban wage earners and clerical
    workers (CPI W). (When prices decline, the COLA is set
    at zero, as occurred in 2010.)

    Scope of the Options
    This study focuses on options that would directly affect
    outlays for Social Security benefits or federal revenues ded
    icated to Social Security. Most would increase the trust
    fund balances, but a few would reduce balances because
    they would raise benefits for people with low lifetime earn
    ings. Each option is considered in isolation even though
    any substantial proposal to change the Social Security pro
    gram probably would include several provisions.

    Options that would reduce initial benefits are assumed to
    take effect in 2017; other options are assumed to take
    effect in 2012. Although some would affect all beneficia
    ries, including those who receive disability insurance,
    CBO did not examine any options that are specific to DI.
    Options that are outside the current system’s structure
    and those that would not have sizable effects on the sys
    tem’s finances are excluded from the study.

    Timing of Implementation. The options that CBO has
    analyzed are not detailed legislative proposals and are
    generally presented in a simplified form. Several, for
    example, would involve abrupt reductions in benefits, so
    workers born a year apart would receive substantially dif
    ferent amounts. In practice, policymakers might choose
    to introduce major changes gradually, as they have done
    in the past. Introducing changes incrementally ensures
    that people of similar ages and circumstances will be sub
    ject to similar tax and benefit rules. (For all the options,

    14. See Social Security Administration, “Effect of Early or Delayed
    Retirement on Retirement Benefits” (November 12, 2009),
    www.ssa.gov/OACT/ProgData/ar_drc.html.

    CBO

    http://www.ssa.gov/OACT/ProgData/ar_drc.html

    10 SOCIAL SECURITY POLICY OPTIONS

    CBO

    as under current law, benefit rules that are applicable to
    an individual are those in force in the year in which that
    person becomes entitled to benefits, not the year he or
    she chooses to begin receiving benefits.)

    Proposals to change Social Security commonly would not
    reduce benefits for people older than 55 in the year a
    reform proposal is considered. Therefore, options in this
    study that would reduce initial benefits would not affect
    anyone older than 55 in 2010. Because retired workers
    become entitled to benefits at age 62, the changes in
    initial benefits would generally apply to people in birth
    cohorts that will become entitled to benefits in 2017
    or later.

    Options That Would Affect Recipients of Disability
    Insurance. Some of the options would affect all Social
    Security beneficiaries, including people who receive DI
    benefits (see, for example, Options 12, 13, 14, and 15).
    If policymakers wanted to offset some of the effects on
    DI benefits of an option that changed retirement and dis
    ability benefits alike, they could add an offsetting policy
    change that increased DI benefits.

    Disability Insurance accounts for one sixth of Social
    Security benefits, and DI expenditures have increased
    rapidly over the past 20 years.15 Consequently, options
    specific to Disability Insurance could have substantial
    consequences for the system’s finances by reducing or
    increasing DI outlays. However, this study does not
    include options (such as those that would affect eligibility
    for benefits, adjust initial DI benefits, or apply different
    cost of living adjustments to DI benefits) that would
    affect DI beneficiaries only.

    Options Not Encompassed by This Study. This study
    focuses on changes to the current structure of Social
    Security that could have sizable effects on the program’s
    finances. Thus, two main categories of options are
    excluded: options outside the context of the existing pro
    gram and options within the program’s existing structure
    that would not have sizable effects on the system’s
    finances.

    15. The growth in spending for Disability Insurance has been driven
    largely by an increase in the number of people receiving benefits.
    In 1980, 4.7 million people received DI benefits; by 2009, there
    were 9.7 million beneficiaries. See Congressional Budget Office,
    Social Security Disability Insurance: Participation Trends and Their
    Fiscal Implications, Issue Brief (forthcoming).

    The creation of individual accounts is a frequently dis
    cussed possibility that would make changes outside the
    existing Social Security program. (The resources available
    to an account holder at retirement would depend on how
    much had been paid into such an account, most likely
    through a payroll tax, and the rate of return on the
    account’s assets during the account holder’s working life.)
    Most proposals that would introduce individual accounts
    also would involve changes to the current program, and
    the interactions between the accounts and the altered
    Social Security program are generally critical to such
    proposals. Although in the past CBO has analyzed com
    prehensive proposals that would combine the establish
    ment of individual accounts with changes to various
    elements of the Social Security system, such analyses are
    beyond this study’s scope.16

    This study also includes no options that would draw on
    general government revenues for Social Security or that
    would change the form of investment for the trust funds.
    In addition, because this study does not consider revenue
    options that would directly affect taxes other than the
    Social Security payroll tax, it does not examine what
    might happen if income taxes on Social Security benefits
    were increased. Such changes could have sizable effects on
    the system’s finances.

    Many other changes could achieve various policy goals
    for Social Security, although they would not produce a
    substantial change in the system’s long run finances.17
    Several possibilities that have received attention elsewhere
    are not included in this study:

    B Changes could be aimed at reducing poverty by
    increasing benefits as Social Security beneficiaries get
    older. Poverty tends to be greater among the very old
    than among younger retirees, so directing benefit
    increases to the oldest beneficiaries could reduce
    poverty by more than if the same total amount of
    additional benefits were distributed more broadly.
    For example, benefits could be increased by fixed
    amounts or by percentages tied to beneficiaries’ ages.
    Alternatively, the COLA could rise as people age so
    that the oldest beneficiaries would receive larger
    increases.

    16. For example, see Congressional Budget Office, letter to the
    Honorable Paul Ryan about an analysis of the Roadmap for
    America’s Future Act of 2010 (January 27, 2010).

    17. Some options of this type that CBO has presented elsewhere
    are not analyzed here. See Congressional Budget Office,
    Budget Options, Volume 2, pp. 141–155.

    http://www.cbo.gov/doc.cfm?index=10851

    http://www.cbo.gov/ftpdocs/102xx/doc10294/08-06-BudgetOptions

    SOCIAL SECURITY POLICY OPTIONS 11

    B The treatment of spousal benefits could be changed to
    reduce the disparity between the benefits due to dual
    and single income couples with the same earnings. For
    example, spousal benefits for couples with similar
    earnings could be increased, decreased, or adjusted
    after the death of a spouse. (Under current law, an eli
    gible spouse of a retired or disabled worker is entitled
    to a spousal benefit that is equal to 50 percent of the
    worker’s benefit, but only if it is higher than the
    spouse’s own earned benefit. Therefore, benefits gen
    erally replace a larger portion of lifetime earnings for
    couples with one earner than for couples with two
    earners.)

    B Benefit increases could be targeted toward parents
    who had low earnings during years when they were
    caring for children.

    B The earnings of those state and local government
    workers who now are exempt from the Social Security
    payroll tax could be taxed, and coverage could be
    made mandatory for all public sector employees.

    Effects of the Options on the System’s Finances
    As a summary measure of the consequences of each
    option, CBO estimated the change in the actuarial bal
    ance as a percentage of GDP. That change is estimated
    using scheduled benefits because, by definition, the sys
    tem is in financial balance with payable benefits, which
    would be automatically reduced to eliminate any short
    fall. The calculations are based on the projections
    described in CBO’s 2010 The Long Term Budget Outlook,
    and the effects of various options were analyzed using
    CBO’s long term Social Security model.18 Analysis of the
    effects of uncertainty in the projected values on the
    results for each option is outside the scope of this study.19

    Some options would, by themselves, eliminate most or all
    of the actuarial imbalance of 0.6 percent of GDP (see

    18. The results presented in this study are based on a single simulation
    for each option, reflecting CBO’s long term demographic and
    economic assumptions. For a description of the model, see
    Congressional Budget Office, CBO’s Long Term Model: An
    Overview, Background Paper (June 2009).

    19. For more information, see Congressional Budget Office,
    Quantifying Uncertainty in the Analysis of Long Term Social Security
    Projections, Background Paper (November 2005).

    Table 2 on page 33). For example, Option 2 would
    increase the payroll tax by 2 percentage points over the
    next two decades, and Option 12 would cut benefits for
    all new recipients by 15 percent. Most individual options
    could be altered to have a smaller or larger effect on the
    actuarial balance by affecting the same key elements of
    the system, but with different tax rates, benefit calcula
    tion rates, or speed at which the policy would phase in.
    Depending on the timing of the changes encompassed by
    the option, eliminating the actuarial imbalance might or
    might not avert exhaustion of the trust fund balance.

    Most of the options presented would not eliminate the
    75 year imbalance on their own; to achieve that goal, it
    would be necessary to combine several. For simplicity,
    however, CBO evaluated each policy in isolation. Com
    bining several options might introduce changes to the
    overall finances of the system that were larger or smaller
    than would be produced by summing the effects of those
    options, because they would interact with one another.

    Some options would have their full effect immediately,
    and they would change annual revenues or outlays by
    roughly the same percentage each year (such as Options 6
    to 9, which would increase payroll tax rates in 2012).
    Others would phase in slowly, resulting in increasingly
    larger changes in annual revenues or outlays (such as
    Option 3, which would increase taxes gradually, or
    Options 15 to 21, which would reduce benefits gradu
    ally). Although most options would improve the system’s
    finances, three (Options 23 to 25) would focus on
    increasing benefits for people with low lifetime earnings.
    Those options would increase scheduled outlays and,
    taken alone, would worsen the system’s finances.

    Effects of Delayed Implementation. The effects of an
    option would be sensitive to the date of its implementa
    tion. In particular, changing the year in which scheduled
    benefits are reduced could interact with changes in demo
    graphics that will occur over the next 30 years. Delaying
    the start of such a reduction could help people to make
    informed decisions about preparing for retirement
    because they would have earlier warning about changes in
    Social Security’s rules. With every year that goes by, how
    ever, larger changes would be needed to create a balance
    over the next 75 years between scheduled revenues and
    scheduled benefits. To demonstrate the effect of delaying

    CBO

    http://www.cbo.gov/doc.cfm?index=11559

    http://www.cbo.gov/ftpdocs/103xx/doc10328/06-26-CBOLT

    http://www.cbo.gov/ftpdocs/68xx/doc6873/11-16-MonteCarlo

    12 SOCIAL SECURITY POLICY OPTIONS

    CBO

    Figure 5.

    Effect of Delaying a Payroll Tax Increase or Benefit Reduction on
    Social Security’s Finances
    (Trust fund ratio)

    Source: Congressional Budget Office.

    Notes: The trust fund ratio is the ratio of the trust fund balance (the amount in the OASDI trust funds at the beginning of a year) to one year’s
    outlays (Social Security benefits and administrative costs). The trust funds are exhausted when the trust fund ratio reaches zero.
    Under current law, the trust funds cannot incur negative balances. A negative balance is a projected shortfall, reflecting the trust
    funds’ inability to pay scheduled benefits out of current-law revenues.

    OASDI = Old-Age, Survivors, and Disability Insurance; PIA = primary insurance amount.

    Option 12: Reduce All PIA Factors by 15 Percent

    Option 2: Increase the Payroll Tax Rate by 2 Percentage Points Over 20 Years

    1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 2020 2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 2050 2055 2060 2065 2070 2075 2080
    -10

    -8

    -6

    -4

    -2

    0
    2
    4
    6

    8
    Actual Projected

    Option Starts in 2022

    Option Starts in 2012

    Current Law
    1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 2020 2025 2030 2035 2040 2045 2050 2055 2060 2065 2070 2075 2080
    -10
    -8
    -6
    -4
    -2
    0
    2
    4
    6
    8

    Current Law
    Option Starts in 2027

    Option Starts in 2017

    Actual Projected

    the implementation of Social Security reforms, CBO
    analyzed the effects of varying the start dates for two
    options.

    In the first case, CBO estimated the effect of boosting the
    payroll tax rate by 2.0 percentage points gradually over
    two decades (Option 2) but starting in 2022 instead of
    2012. If the increase started in 2012, the Social Security
    trust funds would not be exhausted until 2083 (see the
    top panel of Figure 5). However, if the onset of payroll
    tax increases were delayed by 10 years, until 2022, the

    result would be quite different: The Social Security
    trust funds would be exhausted by 2056. If policymakers
    wanted to delay implementation by 10 years and still
    achieve the same improvement in the 75 year actuarial
    balance, the increase in the tax rate would need to be
    more than a quarter larger: The tax rate would have to
    increase by 2.6 percentage points rather than by
    2.0 percentage points.

    In the second instance, CBO evaluated the effect of a flat
    15 percent cut in benefits for new beneficiaries

    SOCIAL SECURITY POLICY OPTIONS 13

    (Option 12) but implemented in 2027 rather than in
    2017. Beginning this cut in 2017 would be nearly
    sufficient to restore Social Security to solvency over 75
    years, and the trust funds would be exhausted in 2076
    (see the bottom panel of Figure 5). With a 10 year delay,
    however, the trust fund exhaustion date would be 2044,
    only five years later than CBO projects under current law.
    If policymakers wanted to implement a benefit reduction
    in 2027 and still achieve the same improvement in the
    75 year actuarial balance as a 15 percent reduction in
    2017, the benefit cut in 2027 would need to be one third
    larger: 20 percent, rather than 15 percent.

    Sustainable Solvency. Different policies can have similar
    effects on the actuarial balance but different effects on
    Social Security’s finances at various points in time. For
    example, a policy that would implement large tax
    increases or benefit cuts in 30 years could eliminate the
    75 year actuarial imbalance but not prevent trust fund
    exhaustion. And a policy that would immediately cut
    benefits or increase taxes by a flat percentage could elimi
    nate the 75 year imbalance and delay exhaustion beyond
    the projection period but still allow large and growing
    imbalances to remain in the 76th year and beyond.

    One way to sustain solvency is to have a trust fund ratio
    that is positive throughout the projection period and then
    stable or growing after 75 years. Neither increasing the
    payroll tax by 2.0 percentage points over two decades nor
    cutting benefits by 15 percent would result in sustainable
    solvency; the trust funds would be exhausted around
    the end of the projection period and the trust fund ratio
    would still be declining after 75 years (see Figure 5). Only
    one option CBO analyzed (Option 17) would, by itself,
    result in sustainable solvency.

    Effects of the Options on Payroll Taxes Paid and
    Benefits Received by Various Groups
    Some options would affect people in all earnings groups
    similarly; others could have greater effects on people with
    higher or lower earnings or on members of other specific
    populations. In addition, some options would have
    greater effects on people born earlier or later. This section
    discusses the distributional effects of various options on
    initial benefits, lifetime benefits, and lifetime payroll
    taxes. It assumes that scheduled benefits are paid, consis
    tent with the discussion of the Social Security system’s
    finances (see Table 2 on page 33). (For an analysis of the
    distributional effects of the options on scheduled bene
    fits, see Table 3 on page 39; for an analysis of the
    distributional effects of the options on payable benefits,

    see Table 4 on page 43.) Specifically, CBO examined
    three measures to identify distributional effects:

    B The percentage change in initial benefits for retirees
    (calculations were made under the assumption that all
    workers claim benefits at age 65);

    B The percentage change in the present value at age 62
    of lifetime benefits; and

    B The percentage change in the present value at age 62
    of lifetime payroll taxes.

    Present values were computed using a real discount rate
    of 3 percent.

    An option could have different effects on initial benefits
    and lifetime benefits. The initial benefits presented here
    are the initial retirement benefits that would be received
    by workers, assuming that all people claim retiree benefits
    at age 65.20 Lifetime benefits, by contrast, include the
    present value of all payments to recipients over time,
    including cost of living adjustments, and they include
    payments to disabled workers and to dependents and sur
    vivors. Unlike the estimated initial benefits, the projected
    lifetime benefits take into account the age at which each
    person is actually expected to claim benefits.21

    CBO examined the way changes resulting from the
    various policy options would affect beneficiaries in
    the low, middle, and high quintiles (the lowest, middle,
    and highest fifths) of households’ lifetime earnings in
    three 10 year birth cohorts: people born in the 1960s,
    people born in the 1980s, and people born in the
    2000s.22

    20. Values are based on earnings through age 61 and are net of the
    income taxes paid on benefits that are credited to the Social
    Security trust funds.

    21. Values are net of the income taxes paid on benefits that are
    credited to the Social Security trust funds. The measure includes
    benefits received by old age workers, disabled workers, old age
    spouses, and old age widows. Because there are insufficient data
    on benefits received by young widows and children for years
    before 1984, young widows, spouses of disabled workers, and
    child beneficiaries are excluded from this measure.

    22. Each person who lives at least to age 45 is ranked by lifetime
    household earnings. For someone who is single in all years,
    lifetime earnings equals the sum of real earnings over a lifetime. In
    any year a person is married, the earnings measure is a function of
    his or her earnings plus those of his or her spouse (adjusted for
    economies of scale in household consumption). A person’s lifetime
    earnings consist of the present value of those annual amounts.

    CBO

    14 SOCIAL SECURITY POLICY OPTIONS

    CBO

    In all, therefore, the effects are identified for nine groups
    of people, measured in terms of how the option would
    affect the median value of each outcome; in other words,
    CBO’s analysis assesses the options’ effects on the person
    at the middle of the distribution of outcomes in a group.
    Outcomes for half of the people in the group would be
    lower and outcomes for half would be higher. In this
    study, “benefits for low earners” refers to median benefits
    for people in the lowest quintile of lifetime household
    earnings. A “change in taxes (or benefits) for high earn
    ers” refers to the percentage change caused by a policy
    option, relative to current law, in the median of the pres
    ent value of lifetime taxes (or benefits) at age 62 for peo
    ple in the highest quintile of lifetime household earnings.

    Outcomes shown in Table 3 and Table 4 are estimated
    percentage changes from the outcomes that would occur
    under current law. They are rounded to the nearest three
    percentage points to give a sense of likely effects on bene
    fits and taxes without showing numerous small differ
    ences in outcomes that are not analytically meaningful.
    The estimates are based on samples of people from the
    relevant groups, and different characteristics of people
    sampled can lead to small differences in outcomes across
    groups that are not meaningful from a policy perspective.
    For example, if an unusually high number of sampled
    people in a group were to turn out to have a shorter than
    average lifespan, then an option that would reduce
    COLAs would result in smaller changes in median life
    time benefits for that group than in a more representative
    sample of the particular group, and the difference could
    lead to somewhat misleading comparisons with other
    groups.

    To analyze distributional consequences of several policies
    that would produce the same effect on Social Security’s
    finances, CBO also analyzed eight variants of the main
    options in this study, each of which would improve the
    actuarial balance by one quarter, or by 0.15 percentage
    points of GDP (see the Appendix).

    Options with Proportionate Effects on People in
    Different Earnings Categories. Several options presented
    in this study would make a proportionate change in ini
    tial benefits for people of a particular age, regardless of
    their earnings:

    B Change All PIA Factors. Among the possibilities CBO
    examined are a one time flat reduction (Option 12)
    and a gradual reduction over time (Option 15). Other

    approaches that would phase in the reduction of
    scheduled benefits over time could link reductions in
    the PIA factors to the increasing longevity of the U.S.
    population (Option 16) or to real growth in earnings
    (Option 17).

    B Increase the Full Retirement Age. An increase by one
    year in the FRA would reduce monthly benefits by
    between 5 percent and 8 percent, depending on the
    age at which a person chose to begin receiving bene
    fits. Changes could be phased in either at a constant
    rate (Options 26 and 27) or according to the increase
    in life expectancy (Option 28).

    An option that reduced all benefits by a similar percent
    age would nevertheless have different consequences for
    different categories of beneficiaries. In dollar terms, the
    reduction would be larger for people who receive higher
    benefits. But measured as a percentage of total income,
    the reduction would be greatest for people who rely most
    heavily on Social Security. For example, someone who has
    no income other than Social Security would find a
    10 percent cut in benefits more burdensome than some
    one for whom Social Security provides just one quarter of
    retirement income. (In 2008, Social Security benefits
    accounted for 90 percent or more of income for 21 per
    cent of retired married couples who were beneficiaries.
    Forty three percent of beneficiaries who were not cur
    rently married received 90 percent or more of their
    income from Social Security.)23

    For the most part, options that would have proportionate
    effects for people in all earnings categories would have
    greater effects on younger people. However, instituting a
    one time reduction in the PIA factors would have similar
    effects on everyone born in 1955 or later.

    Options with Very Different Effects on High and Low
    Earners. Some options would have much greater effects
    on the amount of payroll taxes levied on people or on the
    benefits they are scheduled to receive, depending on their
    lifetime earnings.

    B Change the Maximum Amount of Earnings Subject to
    Payroll Taxes. The method for setting the taxable
    maximum (which usually increases to keep pace with
    average nominal earnings) could be changed. The tax
    able maximum could be eliminated (Option 4) or

    23. See Social Security Administration, “Income Sources.”

    SOCIAL SECURITY POLICY OPTIONS 15

    increased so a larger percentage of covered earnings
    would be subject to payroll taxes (Option 5).
    Changing the taxable maximum also would change
    benefits, because the amount of earnings included in
    the AIME would change.

    B Impose Taxes on Earnings Above the Current Taxable
    Maximum. Changing the taxable maximum would
    affect benefits, but an additional tax could be applied
    solely to raise revenue without affecting benefits. Such
    a policy could extend the existing tax rate to all earn
    ings (Option 6) or to earnings up to a higher thresh
    old (Option 7), or it could apply a different rate above
    the taxable maximum (Options 8 and 9) with no
    effect on benefits.

    B Change the PIA Factors Applied to Higher Earnings.
    The top two PIA factors (currently 32 percent and
    15 percent) could be changed (Option 13), or the
    top factor alone could be changed (Option 14). The
    benefit formula could be changed so that it would
    have four different PIA factors rather than three
    (Options 18 and 19); that approach, commonly called
    progressive price indexing, would then reduce the top
    two PIA factors gradually until they reached zero.

    B Increase Benefits for Low Earners. Benefits for people
    with low lifetime earnings could be boosted by
    increasing the existing special minimum benefit or
    by creating a new minimum benefit with a different
    structure (Options 23 and 24). Alternatively, benefits
    for people who have many years of low earnings
    could be increased by raising their standard benefit
    (Option 25).

    Most of those options would have greater effects on peo
    ple born later. Effects of a one time reduction in one or
    two of the top PIA factors would not vary much from
    one birth cohort to another.

    Effects of the Options on Work and Saving
    Social Security affects people’s decisions about how much
    to work, when to retire, and how much to save for retire
    ment. Changing the rates and structure of Social Security
    taxes and benefits would influence those decisions.
    Because those behavioral responses are difficult to quan
    tify, this study’s analysis of the effects on Social Security’s
    finances generally does not incorporate changes in behav
    ior that might result from implementing the various

    options, such as the potential for alterations in a worker’s
    lifetime earnings.24

    Like all taxes on earnings, Social Security taxes reduce the
    reward from work, which tends to decrease how much
    people work. At the same time, Social Security taxes and
    other taxes on earnings reduce take home pay for any
    given amount of work, and the desire to earn a certain
    amount of take home pay can lead people to work more.
    The net effect of taxes on work reflects the balance of
    those forces; most economists conclude that, on average,
    the negative effects of lower after tax earnings for each
    additional hour worked slightly outweigh the positive
    effects of lower after tax income from current working
    hours.25 Thus, in CBO’s estimation, increasing Social
    Security tax rates would tend to decrease modestly the
    hours of labor that workers supply. Increasing payroll tax
    rates also would encourage workers to shift some of their
    compensation to tax exempt fringe benefits. High earn
    ers, who tend to have more flexibility about how to struc
    ture their compensation, are particularly likely to reduce
    their taxable earnings by electing to receive more of their
    compensation as tax exempt fringe benefits.

    Options that would result in increased tax rates only up
    to a particular amount would affect all earners regardless
    of whether their earnings were above or below that
    amount. For example, Option 1 would increase the tax
    rate but would not change the existing taxable maximum;
    Option 5 would raise the taxable maximum but would
    not change the tax rate. People whose earnings would be
    well above the range of earnings affected by changes in
    tax rates would not confront the same disincentives to
    work, but they would have less income after taxes, which
    might tend to slightly increase their work effort.

    24. The current analysis incorporates some small changes in work
    behavior in response to changes in expected lifetime benefits. See
    Congressional Budget Office, Projecting Labor Force Participation
    and Earnings in CBO’s Long Term Microsimulation Model,
    Background Paper (October 2006).

    25. For discussion, see Congressional Budget Office, The Effect of Tax
    Changes on Labor Supply in CBO’s Microsimulation Tax Model,
    Background Paper (April 2007), and Labor Supply and Taxes,
    CBO Memorandum (January 1996). The 1996 memorandum
    assumed that the spouse of a household’s primary breadwinner
    would be more responsive to higher taxes on earnings than would
    the primary worker in a household. In recent years, CBO has
    revised downward its estimates of the responsiveness of such
    spouses because of evidence that their responsiveness has declined
    over time as their participation in the labor force has grown.

    CBO

    http://www.cbo.gov/ftpdocs/76xx/doc7676/10-27-LaborForce

    http://www.cbo.gov/ftpdocs/79xx/doc7996/04-12-LaborSupply

    http://www.cbo.gov/ftpdocs/33xx/doc3372/labormkts

    16 SOCIAL SECURITY POLICY OPTIONS

    CBO

    Workers would probably consider not only the Social
    Security taxes they pay but also the benefits they expect to
    receive. Therefore, Option 6, which would eliminate the
    taxable maximum but would not affect benefits, would
    probably have a larger effect on work incentives than
    would Option 4, which would eliminate the maximum
    but include the additional taxable earnings in the benefit
    computation.

    Options that would modify the way benefits are deter
    mined also would influence how long people remain in
    the workforce and how much they work while they
    are in the workforce. If workers expected lower Social
    Security benefits, for example, they might stay in the
    workforce longer to claim benefits at a later age.26 How
    ever, a reduction in benefits also could mean (depending
    on the formula through which benefits are reduced) that
    an extra year of work would increase future benefits by a
    smaller amount; that would amount to an increased tax
    on earnings, which would discourage work. On net, older
    workers would probably choose to work longer in
    response to a reduction in benefits, leading to an increase
    in the size of the labor force.27

    The decision about how long someone would remain in
    the workforce would be influenced differently by options
    that would change benefits and by options that would
    raise the full retirement age. Because many workers claim
    benefits at the full retirement age, increasing that age
    would probably result in beneficiaries’ claiming benefits
    later than they would if an effectively identical policy
    were implemented through adjustments in the benefit
    formula.

    Increasing the full retirement age also would create a
    somewhat stronger incentive for some older workers—
    particularly those in poor health—to leave the labor force
    and apply for DI benefits rather than continue to
    work and then claim Old Age benefits at age 62 in a

    26. Before the recent recession, the increase in the full retirement age
    caused a benefit cut that led many workers to delay claiming
    Social Security benefits. See Jae Song and Joyce Manchester, Have
    People Delayed Claiming Retirement Benefits? Responses to Changes
    in Social Security Rules, Congressional Budget Office Working
    Paper 2008 04 (May 2008).

    27. A reduction in scheduled benefits would extend the date of trust
    fund exhaustion and would result in higher payable benefits for
    several years (see Figure 5 on page 12), so a reduction in scheduled
    benefits might actually discourage work during that period.

    decreased amount.28 (Changes in the full retirement age
    would not affect the benefits of workers who qualify for
    Disability Insurance.) Under current law, workers who
    claimed retirement benefits at age 62 in 2033 would
    receive 70 percent of their PIA (the benefit they would
    have received if they had claimed benefits at their full
    retirement age); if they qualified for DI benefits, however,
    they would receive 100 percent of that amount. Increas
    ing the full retirement age would increase the difference
    between retirement and DI benefits if retirement benefits
    are claimed before a worker reaches the FRA.

    Social Security also affects private saving. People who
    expect to receive Social Security benefits probably save
    less for their retirement than they would if there were no
    such program. In effect, Social Security substitutes to
    some extent for retirement saving: Some workers view the
    tax on their wages as a form of saving money each month
    for retirement; instead of accumulating assets to draw
    down when they retire, those workers are counting on
    receiving benefits from the government.29 Therefore, ben
    efit reductions would probably result in higher personal
    saving.

    To the extent that changes in Social Security increase pri
    vate saving without increasing government deficits, those
    changes also would increase national saving—the total
    amount of saving in the economy by the government and
    private sector. Over time, greater national saving would
    raise the stock of capital and result in greater total wealth
    and larger incomes.

    Options That Would Change the
    Taxation of Earnings
    Payroll taxes for Social Security are proportional to earn
    ings below the taxable maximum, and they are not col
    lected on earnings above that amount. Currently, about
    93 percent of workers have earnings below the taxable
    maximum, and they pay Social Security taxes on all of
    their earnings. The remaining 7 percent have some

    28. Empirical evidence of the response in DI enrollment is discussed
    in Mark Duggan, Perry Singleton, and Jae Song, “Aching to
    Retire? The Rise in Full Retirement Age and Its Impact on the
    Social Security Disability Rolls,” Journal of Public Economics,
    vol. 91 (2007), pp. 1327–1350.

    29. See Congressional Budget Office, Social Security and Private
    Saving: A Review of the Empirical Evidence, CBO Memorandum
    (July 1998).

    http://www.cbo.gov/ftpdocs/90xx/doc9077/2008-04

    http://www.cbo.gov/doc.cfm?index=731

    SOCIAL SECURITY POLICY OPTIONS 17

    earnings that are not taxed and therefore have a lower
    average tax rate on their earnings.

    The options in this section would increase Social Security
    revenues beginning in 2012 by making changes to pay
    roll taxes. Options that increased the taxable maximum
    without making other changes to the system also would
    increase the amount of earnings used in the computation
    of benefits, so in those options, a portion of the increase
    in revenues would be offset by increased outlays. (See
    Table 2 on page 33 for the effects of the options on
    Social Security’s finances, Table 3 on page 39 for effects
    on distributional outcomes assuming that scheduled
    benefits are paid, and Table 4 on page 43 for effects on
    distributional outcomes assuming that only payable
    benefits are paid.)

    Option 1: Increase the Payroll Tax Rate by
    1 Percentage Point in 2012
    This option would raise the payroll tax rate for employers
    and employees by 0.5 percentage points each, beginning
    in 2012. The overall rate would be 13.4 percent: 6.7 per
    cent paid by employers and by employees. (As with the
    other options discussed in this section, the tax rate for
    self employed workers would increase in line with the
    combined tax rate on employers and employees.)

    Social Security’s total revenues would increase by about
    0.4 percentage points of GDP in 2040, or by about
    7 percent, relative to current law. (Taxable earnings are
    only a portion of GDP, so a 1 percentage point increase in
    the payroll tax rate leads to significantly less than a 1 per
    centage point increase in revenues as a share of GDP.)
    This option would improve the 75 year actuarial balance
    by 0.3 percentage points of GDP and would extend the
    trust fund exhaustion date by 17 years, to 2056. As a
    result, payable benefits would be higher for people who
    receive benefits in 2039 or later (because, under current
    law, total payable benefits are determined by total reve
    nue during that period). The percentage increase in life
    time payroll taxes paid would be similar for people in all
    categories of lifetime earnings within the same birth
    cohort.

    Option 2: Increase the Payroll Tax Rate by
    2 Percentage Points Over 20 Years
    Whereas Option 1 would increase taxes by a fixed
    amount in 2012 and later, this option would raise the
    combined payroll tax rate gradually, by 0.1 percentage

    point (0.05 percentage points each for employers and
    employees) every year from 2012 to 2031. By the end
    of that period, the rate would stand at 14.4 percent—
    7.2 percent apiece for employers and employees—a
    total of 2 percentage points higher than the current rate
    of 12.4 percent.

    The Social Security payroll tax rate would increase by
    16 percent under this option relative to current law,
    but Social Security revenues would rise a bit less because
    the option would not affect income taxes on benefits.
    This option would improve the 75 year actuarial balance
    by 0.6 percentage points of GDP and would extend the
    trust fund exhaustion date to 2083. As a result, payable
    benefits would be higher for people who receive benefits
    in 2039 or later.

    Lifetime payroll taxes would increase by a small amount
    for people born in the 1960s and by about 15 percent for
    those born in the 2000s. After the option is fully phased
    in, the percentage increase in lifetime payroll taxes paid
    would be similar for people in all categories of lifetime
    earnings.

    Option 3: Increase the Payroll Tax Rate by
    3 Percentage Points Over 60 Years
    Under this option, the combined payroll tax rate would
    increase gradually, by 0.05 percentage points (0.025 per
    centage points each for employers and employees) every
    year from 2012 to 2071. By that time, the rate would
    stand at 15.4 percent (3 percentage points higher than
    the current rate of 12.4 percent), with employers and
    employees each paying 7.7 percent. This option is similar
    to Option 2, except that the tax increase would be imple
    mented more gradually and ultimately the tax rate would
    be higher. Under both options, the tax rate would be
    14.4 percent in 2051. Before that, it would be higher
    under Option 2, and in later years, it would be higher
    under this option.

    Social Security’s total revenues would increase by about
    10 percent under this option in 2040, or by 0.5 percent
    age points of GDP relative to current law. After the
    option was fully phased in (by 2071), revenues would
    increase by 20 percent. The option would improve the
    75 year actuarial balance by 0.5 percentage points of
    GDP and would extend the trust fund exhaustion date by
    19 years, to 2058. As a result, payable benefits would be
    higher starting in 2039.

    CBO

    18 SOCIAL SECURITY POLICY OPTIONS

    CBO

    Lifetime payroll taxes would increase by a small amount
    for people born in the 1960s and by about 15 percent for
    the 2000s cohort. The percentage increase in lifetime
    payroll taxes paid would be similar for people in all cate
    gories of lifetime earnings within the same birth cohort.

    Option 4:

    Eliminate the Taxable Maximum

    In 1983, 91 percent of all earnings from jobs covered by
    the Social Security program were below the maximum
    taxable amount. That percentage declined as the earnings
    of workers in the highest income groups grew faster than
    average earnings did. Thus, in 2009, about 83 percent of
    earnings from employment covered by OASDI (corre
    sponding to 93 percent of workers, as mentioned above)
    was below the maximum taxable amount, now set at
    $106,800. Under this option, all covered earnings would
    be taxed at the current rate of 12.4 percent (6.2 percent
    paid by the employer and 6.2 percent paid by the
    employee) in 2012 and later. The additional taxable earn
    ings would be included in benefit computations, resulting
    in higher benefits for the higher earning workers who
    would be subject to the additional tax.

    Social Security’s total revenues would increase by 0.9 per
    centage points of GDP in 2040, or by 19 percent relative
    to current law, and outlays would increase by 0.3 percent
    age points of GDP, with further increases in subsequent
    years. This option would improve the 75 year actuarial
    balance by 0.6 percentage points of GDP and extend the
    trust fund exhaustion date to 2083.

    This option would primarily affect taxes paid by high
    earners. The increase in taxes for high earners would be
    12 percent, 15 percent, and 18 percent for people born in
    the 1960s, 1980s, and 2000s, respectively. The increase
    would be greater for people with the very highest earn
    ings. Among people born in the 1980s, lifetime taxes
    would rise by at least 40 percent for people in the top
    5 percent of lifetime earnings. The increase in benefits for
    the highest earners would be slightly smaller than the
    increase in their payroll taxes in percentage terms.30 In
    dollar terms, benefits would increase by much less than
    taxes because, under current law, over their lifetimes most
    high earners receive much less in benefits than they pay in
    taxes.

    Option 5: Raise the Taxable Maximum to Cover
    90 Percent of Earnings
    Because the earnings of workers in the highest income
    groups have grown faster than average earnings in recent

    decades, the share of all earnings from jobs covered by the
    Social Security program that were below the taxable max
    imum has fallen from about 91 percent in 1983 to about
    83 percent in 2009. This option would raise the taxable
    maximum so that, beginning in 2012, 90 percent of earn
    ings would be taxable; the additional amounts subject to
    the payroll tax would be used in benefit calculations. The
    taxable maximum in 2012 would be about $156,000
    under this option, CBO estimates, an amount 38 percent
    higher than the maximum of $113,700 estimated under
    current law. (The current taxable maximum is $106,800.)
    After 2012, the taxable maximum would increase so that
    90 percent of covered earnings would continue to be sub
    ject to payroll taxes.

    Social Security’s total revenues would increase by about
    0.4 percentage points of GDP in 2040, or by about
    8 percent, relative to current law. This option would
    improve the 75 year actuarial balance by 0.2 percentage
    points of GDP and would extend the trust fund exhaus
    tion date by 11 years, to 2050. As a result, payable bene
    fits would rise, especially for those who receive benefits in
    the 2040s.

    This option would primarily affect high earners, whose
    taxes would increase by about 6 percent for the 1960s
    cohort and by approximately 15 percent for the 2000s
    cohort. Benefits would be affected in the same manner
    as under Option 4.

    Option 6: Tax Covered Earnings Above the Taxable
    Maximum; Do Not Increase Benefits
    Under this option, starting in 2012, all covered earnings,
    including earnings above the taxable maximum, would be
    taxed at 12.4 percent (6.2 percent paid by the employer
    and 6.2 percent paid by the employee). This option
    would levy the same taxes as Option 4, but the taxable
    maximum under current law would still be used to

    30. The change in lifetime benefits is greater than that of initial
    benefits for two main reasons. First, lifetime benefits are based on
    the highest 35 years of earnings at any age. In contrast, initial
    benefits shown in this study are calculated on the basis of the
    highest 35 years of earnings through age 61 (and they omit
    earnings at older ages, including any earnings after age 61 above
    the taxable maximum). Second, lifetime benefits include spousal
    benefits on the basis of the earnings of the household’s primary
    earner (including earnings above the taxable maximum), whereas
    initial benefits shown here are calculated based on the spouse’s
    own earnings.

    SOCIAL SECURITY POLICY OPTIONS 19

    calculate benefits, and the option would therefore have no
    direct effect on scheduled benefits.

    Under this option, Social Security’s total revenues would
    increase by about 0.9 percentage points of GDP in 2040,
    or by about 18 percent relative to current law. This
    option would improve the 75 year actuarial balance by
    0.9 percentage points of GDP and would extend the trust
    fund exhaustion date beyond the 75 year projection
    period. As a result, payable benefits would be higher from
    2039 onward, especially for people born later.

    This option would primarily affect taxes paid by high
    earners. The effects on payroll taxes would be the same as
    in Option 4, but there would be no effect on scheduled
    benefits.

    Option 7: Tax Covered Earnings Up to $250,000;
    Do Not Increase Benefits
    Under this option, starting in 2012, all covered earnings
    between the taxable maximum and $250,000 would be
    taxed at 12.4 percent (6.2 percent paid by the employer
    and 6.2 percent paid by the employee). The $250,000
    threshold would cover 93 percent of earnings in 2012
    and, in future years, the threshold would be indexed to
    earnings. Because the taxable maximum under current
    law would continue to be used to calculate benefits, the
    option would have no direct effect on scheduled benefits.
    This option is similar to Option 6, although the increase
    in the payroll tax would be smaller, as would be the finan
    cial effects.

    Social Security’s total revenues would increase by about
    0.5 percentage points of GDP in 2040, or by about
    11 percent relative to current law. This option would
    improve the 75 year actuarial balance by 0.5 percentage
    points of GDP and would extend the trust fund exhaus
    tion date by 38 years, to 2077. Payable benefits would be
    higher in 2039 and later. There would be no increase in
    scheduled benefits.

    Like Option 6, this option would primarily affect taxes
    paid by high earners. Their taxes would increase by
    about 12 percent for the 1960s cohort and by approxi
    mately 18 percent for the 2000s cohort.

    Option 8: Tax All Earnings Above the Taxable
    Maximum at 4 Percent; Do Not Increase Benefits
    Under this option, starting in 2012, all covered earnings
    above the taxable maximum would be taxed at 4 percent.

    Because the current law maximum would still be used for
    calculating benefits, this option would have no direct
    effect on scheduled benefits. This option is similar to
    Option 6, but the payroll tax rate above the taxable
    maximum would be substantially smaller, as would be the
    financial effects on the trust funds.

    Social Security’s total revenues would increase by
    about 0.3 percentage points of GDP in 2040, or by about
    6 percent, relative to current law. The option would
    improve the 75 year actuarial balance by 0.3 percentage
    points of GDP and would extend the trust fund exhaus
    tion date by 12 years, to 2051. Although there would be
    no increase in scheduled benefits, higher payroll taxes
    would result in higher payable benefits in 2039 and later.

    This option would primarily affect taxes paid by high
    earners. For high earners born in the 1960s, lifetime taxes
    would increase by about 6 percent; high earners born in
    the 2000s would see their taxes increase by about 9 per
    cent. The increase would be greater for people with the
    very highest earnings.

    Option 9: Tax All Earnings Above $250,000 at
    4 Percent; Do Not Increase Benefits
    Like Option 8, this option would institute a 4 percent tax
    on high earners, but the tax would apply only to covered
    earnings above $250,000. (The Social Security payroll tax
    would not apply to earnings between the taxable maxi
    mum and $250,000.) That threshold would apply to less
    than 1 percent of people with earnings in 2012. In future
    years, the threshold would rise at the rate of average wage
    growth. The current law taxable maximum would still be
    used for calculating benefits, so this option would have
    no direct effect on scheduled benefits.

    Social Security’s total revenues would rise by approxi
    mately 0.1 percentage point of GDP in 2040, or by
    about 3 percent relative to current law. This option
    would improve the 75 year actuarial balance by 0.1 per
    centage point of GDP and would extend the trust fund
    exhaustion date by 4 years, to 2043. There would be no
    increase in scheduled benefits, but higher payroll taxes
    would result in higher payable benefits in 2039 and later.

    This option would primarily affect high earners, whose
    taxes would typically increase by a small percentage. The
    increase would be greatest for people with the very high
    est earnings.

    CBO

    20 SOCIAL SECURITY POLICY OPTIONS

    CBO

    Options That Would Change the
    Benefit Formula
    The formulas for calculating earnings histories for Social
    Security and translating those amounts into initial
    monthly benefits could be changed in many ways. The
    options in this section either would make a single change
    that would affect all new beneficiaries or they would
    make gradual changes that would have larger effects for
    people born later rather than earlier. All options would be
    implemented beginning in 2017.

    Some options would affect high earners more than low
    earners, for whom Social Security benefits generally
    constitute a larger percentage of lifetime earnings. CBO
    projects, for example, that under current law, scheduled
    lifetime benefits would be 15 percent of lifetime taxable
    earnings for low earners born in the 1960s and 8 percent
    of lifetime taxable earnings for high earners in the same
    birth cohort.

    All of the options in this section would produce small
    effects on revenues, in addition to their main effects on
    outlays, because changes in benefits would change the
    amount collected in taxes on those benefits. (See Table 2
    on page 33 for the effects of the options on Social
    Security finances, Table 3 on page 39 for effects on distri
    butional outcomes assuming that scheduled benefits are
    paid, and Table 4 on page 43 for effects on distributional
    outcomes assuming that only payable benefits are paid.)

    Option 10: Raise from 35 to 38 the Years of
    Earnings Included in the AIME
    For a person who reaches age 62 after 1990, the calcula
    tion of average indexed monthly earnings under current
    law incorporates the highest 35 years of indexed earnings
    in which that person paid Social Security taxes. This
    option would extend the period for the AIME calculation
    by 3 years, phased in between 2017 and 2019. Beginning
    in 2019, the calculation would take the average of the
    38 highest years of indexed monthly earnings. The new
    average would apply only to newly eligible retired work
    ers, so there would be no effect on DI benefits.31

    This option would reduce Social Security’s total outlays
    by about 0.1 percentage point of GDP in 2040, or by
    2 percent, relative to currently scheduled outlays. As a

    31. For a more detailed analysis of this option, see Congressional
    Budget Office, Budget Options, Volume 2, p. 146.

    result, it would improve the 75 year actuarial balance by
    0.1 percentage point of GDP; however, it would not
    significantly extend the trust fund exhaustion date. (That
    is, by CBO’s estimate, the option would change the
    exhaustion date by two years or less.)

    This option would reduce scheduled lifetime benefits by
    a similar amount for all birth cohorts. It would have the
    largest effect on people who worked for fewer than
    38 years, because they would have additional years with
    no earnings included in the calculation of their benefits.
    However, the option would reduce benefits even for
    workers who worked 38 or more years, because those
    people would almost always have had lower average earn
    ings in the additional computation years than they would
    have had in the 35 years of their highest earnings. The
    reduction would, on average, be larger for women than
    for men, because women tend to spend more years out of
    the workforce.

    Option 11: Index Earnings in the
    AIME Formula to Prices
    Under current law, as part of the computation of a retired
    worker’s average indexed monthly earnings, past earnings
    are indexed to total average earnings nationwide through
    the year that is two years prior to benefit eligibility, thus
    incorporating rising prices and growth in real earnings.
    Under this option, those earnings would be indexed to
    the growth in prices only.32 As a result, initial benefits
    would be lower than those calculated under current law.

    This option would reduce Social Security’s outlays by
    0.1 percentage point of GDP in 2040, or by 2 percent
    compared with currently scheduled outlays. It would
    improve the 75 year actuarial balance by 0.2 percentage
    points of GDP. The effects would be small initially, so the
    option would not significantly extend the trust fund
    exhaustion date.

    The magnitude of the reduction in benefits would
    increase over time, and by 2040, the average AIME

    32. Specifically, in computing the AIME, all earnings from 2016 and
    earlier would be increased by the growth in the average wage index
    from the earnings year to the year that is two years before the
    AIME computation year. Earnings from 2017 and later would be
    increased by the growth in the CPI W from the earnings year to
    the year that is two years before the AIME computation year. The
    bend points in the PIA formula would continue to be indexed to
    nominal wage growth. Beginning in 2017, this option would
    apply to newly eligible retired and disabled workers.

    http://www.cbo.gov/ftpdocs/102xx/doc10294/08-06-BudgetOptions

    SOCIAL SECURITY POLICY OPTIONS 21

    Figure 6.

    Calculating the PIA in 2010 Under the

    Current Social Security System

    (PIA)

    Source: Congressional Budget Office.

    Notes: A bend point (represented by a dot on the line) is the threshold at which a PIA factor changes.

    PIA = primary insurance amount; AIME = average indexed monthly earnings.

    0

    1,000

    2,000

    3,000

    4,000

    5,000

    6,000

    0 3,000 6,000 9,000 12,000 15,000

    AIME

    Benefits Rise $0.90 for
    Each $1 Increase in the AIME

    Benefits Rise $0.32 for
    Each $1 Increase in the AIME

    Benefits Rise $0.15 for
    Each $1 Increase in the AIME

    $761

    $4,586

    would be 7 percent lower than it would be under current
    law. After price indexing was in place for several decades,
    the scheduled lifetime benefits for people born in the
    2000s would be reduced by about 12 percent for low
    earners and by around 6 percent for high earners. The
    reduction in benefits would be smaller for high earners
    because the reduction in the AIME would be multiplied
    by the 90 percent replacement rate for most low earners
    but multiplied by the 15 percent replacement rate for a
    large fraction of earnings among high earners. Payable
    lifetime benefits would not fall as much as scheduled
    benefits because benefits before the exhaustion of the
    trust funds (and the gap between outlays and revenues
    that would have to be closed by reducing scheduled
    benefits) would be lower.

    Option 12: Reduce All PIA Factors by 15 Percent
    Under current law, the primary insurance amount factors
    used in calculating initial benefits are 90 percent (applied
    to the first $761 of the AIME in 2010), 32 percent
    (applied to the AIME between $761 and $4,586 in
    2010), and 15 percent (applied to the AIME over $4,586
    in 2010) (see Figure 6). This option would reduce the
    PIA factors for newly eligible beneficiaries, including dis
    abled workers, by 15 percent in 2017 (to 77 percent,
    27 percent, and 13 percent), thus reducing initial benefits

    by 15 percent. For example, if the change was applied in
    2010, a worker with an AIME of $5,000 would have a
    monthly benefit of $1,672 instead of the current system’s
    benefit of $1,971.

    Social Security’s total outlays would decline by 0.7 per
    centage points of GDP in 2040, or by 12 percent relative
    to currently scheduled outlays. This option would
    improve the 75 year actuarial balance by 0.5 percentage
    points of GDP and would extend the trust fund exhaus
    tion date by 37 years, to 2076.

    Percentage reductions in scheduled lifetime benefits for
    people affected by the change would be similar. Payable
    lifetime benefits would be lower than under current law
    for people in older cohorts but higher for people who
    were born in the 1980s and 2000s.

    Option 13:

    Reduce the Top Two PIA Factors by
    Roughly One-Third

    Starting in 2017, this option would reduce the top two
    primary insurance amount factors for newly eligible
    retired and disabled workers from 32 percent to 20 per
    cent and from 15 percent to 10 percent. In contrast to
    Option 12, the benefit reduction under this option
    would be greater for people with higher earnings.

    CBO

    22 SOCIAL SECURITY POLICY OPTIONS

    CBO

    Social Security’s total outlays would decline by 1.0 per
    centage point of GDP in 2040, or by 16 percent from
    currently scheduled outlays. This option would improve
    the 75 year actuarial balance by 0.7 percentage points of
    GDP and extend the trust fund exhaustion date beyond
    the 75 year projection period. As a result, payable life
    time benefits would generally be higher than under
    current law for people other than high earners who
    receive benefits in 2039 and several decades thereafter.
    However, this option is not sustainably solvent because
    outlays would increase more rapidly than revenues after
    implementation.

    Scheduled lifetime benefits would fall by 24 percent for
    high earners and by about 3 percent for low earners. Peo
    ple with an AIME below the first bend point would not
    be affected.

    Option 14: Reduce the Top PIA Factor by One-Third
    This option would implement one part of Option 13: It
    would reduce the top primary insurance amount factor
    for newly eligible retired and disabled workers from
    15 percent to 10 percent in 2017. It would affect only
    those new beneficiaries whose AIMEs were above the
    second bend point (in 2010, $4,586; 29 percent of
    62 year olds). For example, under this option, in 2017
    that bend point would be $5,114 in 2010 dollars, and a
    worker with an AIME of $6,000 would receive monthly
    benefits that were $44 lower than under current law.

    Social Security’s total outlays would decline by 0.1 per
    centage point of GDP in 2040, or by 2 percent from cur
    rently scheduled outlays. This option would improve the
    75 year actuarial balance by 0.1 percentage point of GDP,
    and it would not significantly extend the trust fund
    exhaustion date.

    This option would primarily affect high earners, whose
    scheduled lifetime benefits would be reduced by approxi
    mately 6 percent. Payable lifetime benefits would be
    slightly lower than under current law for high earners
    and slightly higher for others who receive benefits in
    2039 or later.

    Option 15: Reduce All PIA Factors by
    0.5 Percent Annually
    Beginning in 2017, this option would reduce the primary
    insurance amount factors for newly eligible retired and
    disabled workers by 0.5 percent annually. Specifically,
    each year’s PIA factors would equal the previous year’s
    factors multiplied by 0.995. By 2080, the PIA factors

    would be 65 percent, 23 percent, and 11 percent, equal
    to about three quarters of what they are now. In 2048,
    this option would match the reduction in initial benefits
    provided by Option 12 (which would cut benefits by
    15 percent in 2017), but it would provide for smaller cuts
    in earlier years and larger reductions in later years.

    Social Security’s total outlays would decline by about
    0.3 percentage points of GDP in 2040, or by about
    6 percent from currently scheduled outlays. This option
    would improve the 75 year actuarial balance by 0.4 per
    centage points of GDP and would extend the trust fund
    exhaustion date by 3 years, to 2042.

    Scheduled lifetime benefits would be reduced by about
    3 percent and 21 percent for people born in the 1960s
    and 2000s, respectively. This option would have little
    effect on lifetime payable benefits.

    Option 16:

    Index Initial Benefits to
    Changes in Longevity

    Under this option, benefits for newly eligible retired
    workers would be reduced in proportion to the increase
    in life expectancy at age 62; reductions would begin in
    2017. For example, life expectancy at age 62 in 2040 will
    be about 8 percent longer than in 2016, CBO projects, so
    initial benefits would be reduced by about 8 percent in
    2040. The option would not affect DI beneficiaries, but
    benefits would decline for disabled beneficiaries when
    they converted to OASI (conversion occurs automatically
    when a beneficiary reaches the full retirement age).33

    Under this option, increases in average life expectancy
    would not result in higher average retirement benefits
    paid over a lifetime.34 However, the computation would
    be based on the average life expectancy of the entire

    33. Under this option, when a disabled beneficiary reached the full
    retirement age, DI benefits would be reduced by an amount
    proportional to the number of years between age 22 and age 62
    that the beneficiary was not entitled to receive benefits. For
    example, someone who became entitled to benefits at 62 without
    receiving any DI benefits would experience the full reduction,
    whereas the reduction for someone who became disabled at age 42
    would be half as large.

    34. The reduction would not exactly equal the change in life
    expectancy after 2016 because it would be implemented by
    adjusting PIA factors by a ratio of the life expectancy at age 62
    for the birth cohort reaching age 62 in 2013 to the life expectancy
    at age 62 for the birth cohort reaching age 62 three years before
    the birth cohort in question. (The computation depends on life
    expectancy from three years before the year in question because
    of the lag in collecting and processing mortality data.)

    SOCIAL SECURITY POLICY OPTIONS 23

    population. On average, low earners have shorter life
    expectancies than high earners do, and some evidence
    suggests that the gap is growing.35 If that trend continues,
    the reduction in lifetime benefits per percentage point of
    additional life expectancy would be greater for low earn
    ers than for high earners (rather than equal, as it would be
    if low and high earners were to have the same increase in
    life expectancy).

    Social Security’s total outlays would decline by 0.2 per
    centage points of GDP in 2040, or by 3 percent from
    currently scheduled outlays. This option would improve
    the 75 year actuarial balance by 0.2 percentage points of
    GDP. The early effects of the option would be too small
    to significantly extend the trust fund exhaustion date.

    The reduction in scheduled lifetime benefits would
    increase over time, reaching about 12 percent for people
    born in the 2000s. This option would have little effect on
    payable lifetime benefits.

    Option 17: Reduce PIA Factors to Index Initial
    Benefits to Prices Rather Than Earnings
    Under this option, often called “price indexing,” the bend
    points in the benefit formula would be indexed to earn
    ings, as under current law, but the PIA factors would be
    reduced each year by measured growth in real earnings
    from two years earlier. Beginning in 2017, average initial
    benefits for newly eligible retirees would increase with
    prices rather than with prices and real earnings. Given
    CBO’s long term projections for growth in real earnings,
    initial benefits would be 1.3 percent lower in the first year
    than under current law, the next year they would be 2.6
    percent lower, and they would decline in the same way in
    each succeeding year.36 In reality, however, the incremen
    tal reduction would vary from year to year, depending on
    actual growth in real earnings. The reductions would be
    smaller during periods of slower earnings growth and
    larger when earnings grew more quickly. By 2060, sched
    uled initial benefits would be 48 percent below those pro
    jected under current law, CBO estimates. The percentage
    reductions in initial benefits for retired workers would be
    the same for all beneficiaries in a birth cohort.

    35. See Congressional Budget Office, Growing Disparities in Life
    Expectancy, Issue Brief (April 17, 2008).

    36. CBO projects that growth in real wages will average 1.3 percent
    annually (see Congressional Budget Office, CBO’s Long Term
    Projections for Social Security: 2009 Update, p. 9).

    This option is similar in structure to Option 15, but
    instead of reducing benefits at a fixed rate, the reduction
    relative to benefits scheduled under current law would
    vary each year with growth in real earnings. Under cur
    rent law, average real scheduled benefits grow over time,
    and the ratio of initial scheduled benefits to average earn
    ings (as measured by the AIME) remains roughly con
    stant. Under this option, average real benefits would
    remain constant, and the ratio of initial scheduled bene
    fits to the AIME would decline over time from an average
    of 0.44 for people retiring in 2010 to 0.29 for people
    who retire in 2060.37 This option would not affect people
    who collect DI benefits, but, as under Option 16, the
    decline in benefits upon conversion to OASI would be
    smaller for people who had received DI benefits for a
    longer period.

    Social Security’s total outlays would decline by 0.9 per
    centage points of GDP in 2040, or by 14 percent from
    currently scheduled outlays. The savings would continue
    to grow. This option would improve the 75 year actuarial
    balance by 1.0 percentage point of GDP and would result
    in long term sustainable solvency.

    For people born in the 1980s, scheduled lifetime benefits
    would decline by about 30 percent; later cohorts would
    face bigger reductions. Payable lifetime benefits also
    would be lower than those under current law, but the
    cuts would not be as large as under scheduled benefits
    because payable benefits are lower to begin with.

    Option 18: Lower Initial Benefits for the Top
    70 Percent of Earners
    This option, often called “progressive price indexing,” is
    similar to Option 17. However, scheduled benefits for
    people in the bottom 30 percent of lifetime average earn
    ings would not change relative to current law, and the
    reductions for people at the high end of the earnings dis
    tribution would be greater than those for people closer to
    the low end. Under this option, the PIA factors applicable
    to the top 70 percent of earners would be gradually
    reduced so that initial benefits for such earners would
    decline over time relative to those scheduled under current
    law. Beginning in 2017, initial benefits for newly eligible
    Social Security beneficiaries who earned the taxable maxi
    mum for 35 years—“maximum earners”—would increase
    from year to year with prices (as in Option 17) rather
    than with prices and real earnings. For beneficiaries

    37. See Congressional Budget Office, Budget Options, Volume 2,
    p. 143.

    CBO

    http://www.cbo.gov/ftpdocs/91xx/doc9104/04-17-LifeExpectancy_Brief

    http://www.cbo.gov/ftpdocs/102xx/doc10294/08-06-BudgetOptions

    http://www.cbo.gov/ftpdocs/104xx/doc10457/08-07-SocialSecurity_Update

    24 SOCIAL SECURITY POLICY OPTIONS

    CBO

    whose lifetime earnings were between those two groups—
    above the 30th percentile but below the taxable maxi
    mum—average initial benefits would increase more rap
    idly than prices but more slowly than earnings.38 This
    option would not affect people who collect DI benefits,
    but, as under Option 16, the decline in benefits upon
    conversion to OASI would be smaller for people who had
    received DI benefits for a longer time.

    This option would be implemented by adding a third
    bend point to the PIA formula in 2017, initially set at the
    30th percentile (encompassing the lowest 30 percent) of
    earners. In 2040, the new bend point would be at about
    $2,560, between the first bend point at $1,130 and the
    highest bend point at $6,830 (see Figure 7). Between the
    first bend point and the new one, the PIA factor would
    remain at 32 percent. The PIA factors in the next two
    brackets initially would be 32 percent and 15 percent,
    but they would be reduced annually—at the rate needed
    to keep a maximum earner’s initial benefits growing with
    prices.

    The top two PIA factors would fall to zero by about
    2080, CBO projects, when monthly benefits for a worker
    with earnings at the new bend point (which would have
    increased at the rate of earnings growth) would be about
    $2,560, roughly the same as the benefits paid to maxi
    mum earners (which would have increased at the rate of
    prices). Thereafter, scheduled initial benefits for all newly
    retired beneficiaries would increase with earnings, but
    benefits would effectively be capped at the amount
    received by workers with earnings at the new bend point.

    Social Security’s total outlays would decline by 0.4 per
    centage points of GDP in 2040, or by 7 percent from
    currently scheduled outlays. This option would improve
    the 75 year actuarial balance by 0.5 percentage points of
    GDP but would extend the trust fund exhaustion date
    only by five years, to 2044, because it would be phased in
    slowly.

    Lifetime scheduled benefits for low earners would be
    essentially unchanged; those for high earners born in the
    1980s would decline by approximately 30 percent; later
    cohorts would face bigger reductions. Lifetime payable
    benefits would be similar to those paid under current law

    38. Ibid.

    for people in the middle of the earnings distribution but
    reduced for high earners and increased for low earners.

    Option 19: Lower Initial Benefits for the
    Top 50 Percent of Earners
    This option differs from Option 18 in that benefits
    would remain as scheduled under current law for benefi
    ciaries in the bottom 50 percent of career average earn
    ings, rather than for those in the bottom 30 percent.
    Under this option, the PIA factors applicable to the top
    50 percent of earners would be gradually reduced so that
    initial benefits would decline over time relative to those
    scheduled under current law. The change would be
    achieved by adding a bend point to the PIA formula
    between the first and second bend points. In 2017, the
    new bend point would be set initially at the 50th percen
    tile of the lifetime earnings distribution, which CBO
    estimates would be 74 percent of the way between the
    original first and second bend points.

    The top two factors would fall to zero in 2057, CBO
    estimates. The top two factors reach zero earlier than in
    Option 18 because the new second bend point occurs at a
    higher level of earnings. At that time, benefits for a
    worker with earnings at the new bend point (which
    would have increased at the rate of earnings) would equal
    the benefits received by maximum earners (which would
    have increased at the rate of prices). Thereafter, scheduled
    initial benefits for retired beneficiaries would be indexed
    to earnings, but those benefits would effectively be
    capped at the new bend point. This option would not
    affect people collecting DI benefits, but their benefits
    would decline upon conversion to OASI. That reduction
    would be smaller for people who had received DI benefits
    for a longer period, as under Option 16.

    Social Security’s total outlays would decline by 0.4 per
    centage points of GDP in 2040, or by 6 percent from
    currently scheduled outlays. This option would improve
    the 75 year actuarial balance by 0.4 percentage points of
    GDP and would extend the trust fund exhaustion date by
    four years, to 2043. By 2060, the reduction in outlays
    would be about 40 percent of what it would be with
    indexing to prices (as in Option 17) and about
    80 percent of the amount it would be with progressive
    price indexing for the top 70 percent of earners (as in
    Option 18).

    SOCIAL SECURITY POLICY OPTIONS 25

    Figure 7.

    Calculating Initial Benefits with

    Progressive Price Indexing

    (PIA in 2010 dollars)

    Source: Congressional Budget Office.

    Notes: Progressive price indexing is the subject of Option 18: Lower Initial Benefits for the Top 70 Percent of Earners. In 2010, the bend
    points (represented by the dots on the lines) under current law are $761 and $4,586. In 2040, the bend points (in 2010 dollars) are
    $1,130 and $6,830 under current law and $1,130, $2,560, and $6,830 with progressive price indexing. In 2080, the bend points (in
    2010 dollars) are $1,890 and

    $11,380

    under current law and $1,890, $4,270, and $11,380 with progressive price indexing. A bend
    point is the threshold at which a PIA factor changes.

    PIA = primary insurance amount; AIME = average indexed monthly earnings.
    0
    1,000
    2,000
    3,000
    4,000
    5,000
    6,000
    0 3,000 6,000 9,000 12,000 15,000

    AIME in 2010 Dollars

    0
    1,000
    2,000
    3,000
    4,000
    5,000
    6,000
    0 3,000 6,000 9,000 12,000 15,000
    AIME in 2010 Dollars

    2040

    2080
    Current Social Security System
    Current Social Security System
    Progressive Price Indexing
    Progressive Price Indexing

    $1,130

    $1,130

    $6,830

    $6,830

    $2,560

    $1,890

    $1,890

    $11,380

    $4,270

    $11,380
    CBO

    26 SOCIAL SECURITY POLICY OPTIONS

    CBO

    Scheduled lifetime benefits for middle earners born in the
    2000s would decrease by about 9 percent; those for high
    earners would decline by around 36 percent. Payable
    benefits would be reduced for high earners but increased
    somewhat for low earners who receive benefits in 2039
    or later.

    Option 20: Index the Bend Points in the
    PIA Formula to Prices
    Under this option, beginning in 2017, the bend points in
    the formula that determines the primary insurance
    amount would be indexed to prices rather than to average
    earnings, as they are under current law. (Because this
    option would change the bend points, it differs signifi
    cantly from Options 17, 18, and 19, which would mod
    ify the PIA factors.) This option would apply to newly
    eligible retired and disabled workers. (As under current
    law, workers’ earnings would still be indexed to nominal
    earnings in the computation of the AIME.)

    CBO projects that annual growth in real earnings will
    average 1.3 percent, so the bend points would increase
    1.3 percent more slowly under this option than under
    current law. By 2040, the bend points would be almost
    30 percent lower than they would be under current law
    (see Figure 8). By 2080, they would be almost 60 percent
    lower. The bend points would have remained the same in
    real terms (about $820 and

    $4,960

    in 2010 dollars) from
    2017 to 2080, whereas the bend points under current law
    would have increased markedly, to about $1,890 and
    about $11,380 (in 2010 dollars). In 2080, the PIA under
    current law would be about $1,700 for a worker with an
    AIME of $2,000; under this option, the PIA would be
    $1,100, or 35 percent less.

    Social Security’s total outlays would decline by 0.4 per
    centage points of GDP in 2040, or by 7 percent from
    currently scheduled outlays. This option would improve
    the 75 year actuarial balance by 0.5 percentage points of
    GDP, but it would extend the trust fund exhaustion date
    only by five years, to 2044, because it would be phased in
    slowly.

    Lifetime scheduled benefits for low earners born in the
    2000s would decrease by about 18 percent; for high
    earners they would decrease by approximately 24 percent.
    Payable lifetime benefits would be about the same as
    under current law.

    Option 21: Index Earnings in the AIME and
    Bend Points in the PIA Formula to Prices
    This option would combine Options 11 and 20 by
    switching from wage indexing to price indexing for com
    puting average indexed monthly earnings and for calcu
    lating the bend points in the formula for the primary
    insurance amount. Beginning in 2017, the option would
    apply to newly eligible retired and disabled workers.

    Social Security’s total outlays would decline by 0.5 per
    centage points of GDP in 2040, or by 8 percent, from
    currently scheduled outlays. This option would improve
    the 75 year actuarial balance by 0.6 percentage points of
    GDP. Even though it would result in a positive 75 year
    actuarial balance, the benefit reductions would be rela
    tively small in the first few decades. This option therefore
    would extend the trust fund exhaustion date only by
    seven years, to 2046.

    Lifetime scheduled benefits for low earners born in the
    2000s would be reduced by around 27 percent; for high
    earners, those benefits would decline by about 30 percent.
    Lifetime scheduled benefits for people born earlier also
    would decline but by a smaller proportion. Payable bene
    fits generally would be lower than those under current
    law.

    Option 22: Replace the Current PIA Formula with a
    New Two-Part Formula
    Beginning in 2017, this option would introduce a new
    formula for calculating the primary insurance amount for
    newly eligible retired workers. The PIA would equal the
    sum of two amounts: The first would provide each
    worker with a benefit based on the number of years of
    work, and the second would provide each worker with
    additional benefits proportional to the worker’s average
    indexed monthly earnings.

    The first part of the new formula would provide a fixed
    amount of benefits for every quarter of coverage accumu
    lated by a worker, regardless of earnings. As under current
    law, a retired worker would need at least 40 quarters of
    coverage to receive benefits. A newly eligible retired
    worker in 2017 would receive a monthly benefit of $6 for
    each quarter up to 160 quarters of coverage accumulated.
    The amount would increase over time at the rate of aver
    age wage growth. The second part of the formula would
    provide additional benefits proportional to earnings, cal
    culated as 15 percent of the AIME.

    SOCIAL SECURITY POLICY OPTIONS 27

    Figure 8.

    Calculating Initial Benefits with Indexing of Bend Points to Prices
    (PIA in 2010 dollars)

    Source: Congressional Budget Office.

    Notes: Price indexing of the bend points (represented by the dots on the lines) is the subject of two options, Option 20: Index the Bend Points
    in the PIA Formula to Prices and Option 21: Index Earnings in the AIME and Bend Points in the PIA Formula to Prices. In 2010, the
    bend points under current law are $761 and $4,586. In 2040, the bend points (in 2010 dollars) are $1,130 and $6,830 under current
    law and $820 and $4,960 with price indexing. In 2080, the bend points (in 2010 dollars) are $1,900 and $11,380 under current law
    and $820 and $4,960 with price indexing. A bend point is the threshold at which a PIA factor changes.

    PIA = primary insurance amount; AIME = average indexed monthly earnings.
    0
    1,000
    2,000
    3,000
    4,000
    5,000
    6,000
    0 3,000 6,000 9,000 12,000 15,000
    AIME in 2010 Dollars
    2040
    Current Social Security System

    Bend Points Indexed to Prices

    $1,130

    $820

    $6,830

    $4,960

    0
    1,000
    2,000
    3,000
    4,000
    5,000
    6,000
    0 3,000 6,000 9,000 12,000 15,000
    AIME in 2010 Dollars
    2080
    Current Social Security System
    Bend Points Indexed to Prices
    $820
    $1,890
    $11,380
    $4,960
    CBO

    28 SOCIAL SECURITY POLICY OPTIONS

    CBO

    Under this option, in 2017, a worker with 160 quarters
    of coverage and an AIME of $5,000 would have a PIA of
    $1,710. Of that amount, $960 would be attributable to
    the 160 quarters of coverage and $750 would be 15 per
    cent of the AIME. Under current law, in 2017, that
    worker would have a PIA of $2,150 (in 2017 dollars).

    Social Security’s total outlays would decline by 5 percent
    in 2040 under this option, or by 0.3 percentage points of
    GDP relative to current law. The option would improve
    the 75 year actuarial balance by 0.2 percentage points of
    GDP and would extend the trust fund exhaustion date by
    six years, to 2045.

    Scheduled lifetime benefits would decrease by roughly
    9 percent for high earners. Scheduled lifetime benefits for
    low earners would decrease for people born in the 1960s
    but increase somewhat for people born later (because ear
    lier cohorts of low earners have fewer years of work).
    Payable lifetime benefits would be slightly higher for low
    earners in later birth cohorts.

    Options That Would Increase
    Benefits for Low Earners
    One goal of Social Security is to ensure an adequate
    income for beneficiaries. In 2008, 8 percent of all Social
    Security beneficiaries over the age of 65 were considered
    poor. Only 3 percent of married beneficiaries over 65
    were poor, but 14 percent of beneficiaries who were not
    currently married and 16 percent of never married bene
    ficiaries in the same age group were poor. One reason for
    the higher poverty rates among those groups is that bene
    ficiaries who never married (or, if divorced, who had been
    married for less than 10 years) are not eligible to receive
    auxiliary benefits for widows, widowers, or divorcees. A
    minimum benefit for workers could help provide a larger
    income for those beneficiaries and others. The options in
    this section would increase worker benefits for some peo
    ple who worked and contributed to Social Security for
    many years yet had low average annual earnings and thus
    would receive low Social Security benefits under current
    law. (The options would not affect the benefits received
    by married people with low earnings if their own worker
    benefits remained less than half of their spouse’s benefits.)

    Because the options in this group are based on earnings
    during a working lifetime, they would not necessarily

    benefit people who have low income during retirement.
    In addition, the options would not distinguish between
    workers who had low annual earnings because they
    earned low hourly wages and workers who had higher
    hourly wages but worked for only part of the year. (See
    Table 2 on page 33 for the effects of the options on Social
    Security’s finances, Table 3 on page 39 for effects on dis
    tributional outcomes assuming that scheduled benefits
    are paid, and Table 4 on page 43 for effects on distribu
    tional outcomes assuming that only payable benefits are
    paid.)

    Option 23: Modify the Special Minimum Benefit and
    Index It to Growth in Earnings
    Current law includes a special minimum benefit, which
    currently can be as much as $763 a month, about
    85 percent of the federal poverty guideline for an individ
    ual.39 Beneficiaries receive the larger of the standard bene
    fit or the special minimum benefit. The special minimum
    benefit was created to increase payments to people who
    had low earnings over a long working lifetime. However,
    the benefit is indexed to prices, whereas regular Social
    Security benefits are indexed to earnings—and because
    earnings have grown faster than prices, regular Social
    Security benefits have increased in real terms, and few
    beneficiaries now qualify for the special minimum bene
    fit. After 2010, benefits computed under the standard
    formula are projected to be greater than the special mini
    mum benefit for all new beneficiaries.

    This option would restructure the primary insurance
    amount used in calculating the special minimum benefit,
    basing it on the number of years of qualifying work but
    not varying it otherwise with earnings. The effect would
    be to increase the benefit as the number of years of work
    (above the 10 needed to qualify for Social Security bene
    fits) increased, up to 30 years. For example, in 2012, the
    monthly benefit for a single person age 65 or older in that
    year who has worked for 30 years or more would be
    about $1,170, which CBO projects would equal 125 per
    cent of the poverty guideline. For someone with fewer
    than 30 years of work, the special minimum benefit
    would be reduced proportionately, down to zero for

    39. See Kelly A. Olsen and Don Hoffmeyer, “Social Security’s Special
    Minimum Benefit,” Social Security Bulletin, vol. 64, no. 2 (2001/
    2002).

    SOCIAL SECURITY POLICY OPTIONS 29

    people with 10 or fewer years of work.40 In 2013 and
    later, the dollar thresholds would increase at the same rate
    as average earnings.

    Social Security’s total outlays under this option would
    increase by 0.2 percentage points of GDP in 2040, or by
    4 percent above currently scheduled outlays. This option
    would worsen the 75 year actuarial balance by 0.2 per
    centage points of GDP, and the trust funds would be
    exhausted two years earlier, in 2037. Payable benefits
    would generally be higher for the affected low earners,
    but high earners would be affected by the earlier trust
    fund exhaustion date and by the larger gap between
    outlays and revenues thereafter.

    Under this option, scheduled lifetime benefits for low
    earners born in the 2000s would increase by about
    30 percent. In 2040, about 50 percent of new OASI ben
    eficiaries and about 35 percent of new DI beneficiaries
    would have higher initial benefits; about 45 percent of
    the group would be women.

    Option 24:

    Introduce a New Poverty-Related
    Minimum Benefit

    This option would introduce a new benefit for workers
    who have relatively low earnings over a long period. For
    someone with 20 years of earnings, the minimum PIA
    would typically be 80 percent of the poverty guideline for
    a single person age 65 or older in 2016. (In most of the
    country, the 2009 poverty guideline for a single person
    was $10,830.) With 40 years of earnings, the amount
    would be 120 percent of the poverty guideline.41 Those
    PIAs would amount to $720 and $1,080, respectively, in
    2016 (in 2010 dollars). Beneficiaries would receive the
    higher of the regular benefit or the new minimum
    benefit. This option’s minimum benefits would be higher
    than those under Option 23 for workers with

    40. Under this option, a year of coverage for the special minimum
    benefit is defined as a year in which a worker earns four quarters
    of coverage. Years of coverage would accumulate after 10 years of
    coverage but not increase beyond 30 years. That is, someone who
    worked 30 or more years would be credited with benefits based on
    20 years of coverage. The additional PIA per year of coverage
    above 10 years would be 1/20 of the benefit for a 30 year worker,
    or $58.50 in 2012. So, for example, the minimum monthly
    benefit for a worker with 15 years of coverage would be about
    $293 (5 × $58.50).

    11 to 24 years of earnings and lower for those with 25 or
    more years of earnings; neither option would provide a
    minimum benefit to workers with 10 or fewer years of
    earnings.

    Social Security’s total outlays would increase by less than
    0.05 percentage points of GDP in 2040, or by less than
    1 percent from currently scheduled outlays. This option
    would worsen the 75 year actuarial balance by less than
    0.05 percentage points of GDP and would not signifi
    cantly change the trust fund exhaustion date.

    Scheduled and payable lifetime benefits for low earners
    would be roughly 6 percent higher than under current
    law. In 2040, about 13 percent of new OASI beneficiaries
    and about 18 percent of new DI beneficiaries would
    receive higher initial benefits than under current law;
    about 55 percent of those beneficiaries would be women.

    Option 25: Enhance Low-Earners’ Benefits on the
    Basis of Years Worked
    Under this option, beginning in 2012, benefits would
    increase for workers who have both low lifetime average
    earnings and at least 20 years of covered earnings. This
    option would raise the standard benefit for qualified
    workers by a specified percentage that would depend on
    the number of years worked and a worker’s AIME. The
    largest benefit increase would be 40 percent for someone
    with 35 or more years in the workforce and an AIME at
    or below the AIME of someone who had worked full
    time and earned the minimum wage for 30 years. The
    benefit increase would be smaller for people with fewer
    years of work or higher AIMEs, and there would be no
    increase for people whose AIME was above that of a
    worker who had worked for 35 years or who always
    earned an amount equal to or greater than the average

    41. To qualify for the new benefit, a beneficiary would need to have
    worked at least 10 years. Specifically, the minimum PIA would be
    2 percent of the poverty guideline for each quarter of coverage
    above 40 (10 years of earnings) and up to 80 quarters of coverage,
    and 0.5 percent of the poverty guideline for quarters of coverage
    above 80 and up to 160. (For disabled workers, fewer quarters
    would be required because of their shortened careers.) This new
    minimum benefit would be phased in from 2012 to 2016.
    Beginning in 2016, the effective poverty guidelines would increase
    with average wages.

    CBO

    30 SOCIAL SECURITY POLICY OPTIONS

    CBO

    wage index (AWI, the average amount of total earnings in
    the United States in a year).42

    Social Security’s total outlays in 2040 would increase
    by 0.4 percentage points of GDP, or by 7 percent from
    currently scheduled outlays. This option would worsen
    the 75-year actuarial balance by 0.3 percentage points of
    GDP, and the trust funds would be exhausted in 2034,
    five years earlier than CBO anticipates otherwise. Payable
    benefits for high earners would be somewhat lower than
    under current law because of the earlier exhaustion of the
    trust funds and the larger gap between outlays and
    revenues thereafter.

    Under this policy, scheduled lifetime benefits for low
    earners born in the 2000s would increase by about
    24 percent. For people in the same cohort and in
    the middle of the household earnings distribution,
    scheduled lifetime benefits would increase by 12 percent;
    they would receive larger benefits because many of them
    would have an AIME that was less than that of a worker
    who worked for 35 years and always earned an amount
    equal to the AWI. Under this option, about 57 percent of
    new OASI beneficiaries and about 65 percent of DI ben-
    eficiaries would receive an increase in their initial benefits
    in 2040; about 53 percent of those beneficiaries would be
    women.

    42. The standard benefit would be multiplied by 1 + (40 percent ×
    AIME factor × coverage factor). The two factors range from 0 to
    1, so this option would increase benefits by as much as 40 percent.
    The AIME factor would be 1 for workers with an AIME equal to
    or less than the AIME of a full-time worker who earned the
    minimum wage for 30 years. It would be zero for workers with an
    AIME greater than the AIME of a worker who worked for
    35 years, always earning an amount equal to the AWI. For workers
    with earnings between those amounts the factor would be set
    proportionately: AIME factor for a given worker = (AIME of
    35-year AWI worker – AIME of given worker)/(AIME of 35-year
    AWI worker – AIME of minimum wage worker). The coverage
    factor would give a larger increase to workers with more quarters
    of coverage. For most retired workers the factor would be 1 if the
    worker had at least 35 years in covered employment. It would be
    zero if the worker had 20 years or less in covered employment. For
    workers whose employment was between 20 and 35 years, the
    formula would be as follows: Coverage factor = the minimum of
    1 or 1 – {[(3.5 × elapsed years) – quarters of coverage]/(1.5 ×
    elapsed years)}. “Elapsed years” would be set to 40 for retired
    workers or equal to the number of years from age 22 to the age of
    entitlement for disabled workers (see Congressional Budget
    Office, Budget Options, Volume 2, p. 154).

    Options That Would Raise the
    Full Retirement Age
    People who turn 65 today will, on average, collect Social
    Security benefits for significantly longer than retirees did
    in the past because the average life span in the United
    States has lengthened considerably. In 1940, life expec-
    tancy at age 65 was 11.9 years for men and 13.4 years for
    women. The Social Security trustees project that life
    expectancy has increased by more than 5 years for 65-
    year-olds today, to 17.0 years for men and 19.4 years for
    women, and that those figures will increase to 18.7 years
    and 20.8 years by 2035. Therefore, a commitment to
    provide people with a specific monthly benefit for the rest
    of their lives would be more costly if made to those who
    will be 65 in 2035 than to 65-year-olds today.

    Increasing the full retirement age is, in most ways, equiv-
    alent to cutting initial benefits. In particular, for people
    who claim benefits at any given age, a higher FRA results
    in lower benefits. (The options presented here would not
    change the early eligibility age, which under current law
    is fixed at 62 for retired workers.) Depending on the age
    at which the worker claims his or her benefits, a one-year
    increase in the FRA is equivalent to a reduction in a
    retired worker’s monthly benefit of between 5 percent
    and 8 percent.43 For example, under current law, benefits
    would be reduced by 30 percent for someone with a FRA
    of 67 (that is, someone born in 1960 or later) who
    claimed benefits at age 62. The reduction would be
    35 percent for the same worker if the FRA was set at 68.

    The options in this section would increase the full retire-
    ment age to different ages at different speeds. (See Table 2
    on page 33 for the effects of the options on Social Secu-
    rity’s finances, Table 3 on page 39 for effects on distribu-
    tional outcomes assuming that scheduled benefits are
    paid, and Table 4 on page 43 for effects on distributional
    outcomes assuming that only payable benefits are paid.)

    43. When a worker claims benefits before the full retirement age,
    benefits are reduced by 5/9 of 1 percent for each month, or
    6-2/3 percent per year, before full retirement age, up to
    36 months. If the number of months exceeds 36, then the
    benefit is further reduced by 5/12 of 1 percent per month, or
    5 percent per year. People who claim benefits after reaching
    their FRA generally receive a delayed-retirement credit, which is
    8 percent for those born in 1943 and later. No additional credit
    is given after a person turns 70.

    http://www.cbo.gov/ftpdocs/102xx/doc10294/08-06-BudgetOptions

    SOCIAL SECURITY POLICY OPTIONS 31

    Option 26: Raise the FRA to 68
    This option would continue to increase the full retire
    ment age after it reaches 67 in 2022 under current law.
    Specifically, the FRA would rise by an additional two
    months per birth year for another six years, reaching 68
    for workers born in 1966, who will turn 62 in 2028.

    Social Security’s total outlays would decline by 0.2 per
    centage points of GDP in 2040, or by 3 percent from
    currently scheduled outlays. This option would improve
    the 75 year actuarial balance by 0.1 percentage point of
    GDP and would not significantly extend the trust fund
    exhaustion date.

    After this option was fully phased in, scheduled lifetime
    benefits for people born in the 1980s and 2000s would
    be reduced by about 6 percent relative to current law.
    Payable benefits would not change significantly.

    Option 27: Raise the FRA to 70
    Like Option 26, this option would continue to increase
    the full retirement age after it reaches 67 in 2022 under
    current law, but this option would ultimately make the
    age of full retirement later than would Option 26. Under
    this option, the FRA would rise by an additional two
    months per birth year for another 18 years, reaching age
    70 for workers who were born in 1978 and who will turn
    62 in 2040.44 That change, relative to Social Security’s
    original FRA of 65, would roughly match the increase in
    life expectancy that has occurred since 1940.

    Under this option, Social Security’s total outlays would
    decline by 0.4 percentage points of GDP in 2040, or by
    6 percent from currently scheduled outlays. This option
    would improve the 75 year actuarial balance by 0.3 per
    centage points of GDP and would not significantly
    extend the trust fund exhaustion date.

    After this option was fully phased in, scheduled lifetime
    benefits for people born in the 1980s and 2000s would
    be reduced by about 15 percent relative to current law.
    Payable benefits would decline by smaller percentages.

    Option 28: Index the FRA to Changes in Longevity
    This option would maintain a constant ratio of projected
    years of benefit receipt to years of work—that is, the ratio

    44. CBO has examined the effects of increasing the FRA to 70 for
    people born in 1971 and then by 1 month every second year. See
    Congressional Budget Office, Budget Options, Volume 2, p. 145.

    of life expectancy at the full retirement age to the number
    of years from age 21 to the full retirement age would be
    held constant.45 Under current law, the FRA will be 67
    starting in 2022. Under Options 26 and 27, the FRA
    would increase at a rate of two months per birth year.
    Under this option, the increase would be more gradual:
    The FRA would rise by approximately half a month per
    birth year, and the rate of increase would vary depending
    on the actual rate of mortality improvement. Under this
    approach, CBO estimates, the FRA for people born in
    1979 would be 68, and the FRA for people born in 2003
    would be 69. The FRA would reach 70 for people born
    in 2026; that group would become eligible for retirement
    benefits in 2088, which is beyond the 75 year projection
    period for this study.

    Social Security’s total outlays in 2040 would decline by
    0.1 percentage point of GDP, or by just over 2 percent,
    relative to currently scheduled outlays. This option would
    improve the 75 year actuarial balance by 0.2 percentage
    points of GDP and would not significantly extend the
    trust fund exhaustion date.

    Under this policy, scheduled lifetime benefits for people
    born in the 2000s would be reduced by roughly 12 per
    cent. Payable benefits would be reduced by a smaller
    amount.

    Options That Would Reduce
    Cost-of-Living Adjustments
    Current law requires that the benefits paid to existing
    beneficiaries generally rise each year with the application
    of a cost of living adjustment. At the end of each year,
    the Social Security Administration adjusts each benefi
    ciary’s PIA by an amount that is equal to any increase in
    the consumer price index for urban wage earners and
    clerical workers from the third calendar quarter of the
    prior year to the third calendar quarter of the current
    year. (When prices decline, the COLA is set at zero, as
    occurred in 2010.)

    Many analysts believe that the CPI W overstates increases
    in the cost of living because it does not fully account for
    the fact that consumers generally adjust their spending
    patterns as some prices change relative to others. Another

    45. Because of the delay in the availability of mortality data, this
    option would be linked to life expectancy data from three years
    before the affected year.

    CBO

    http://www.cbo.gov/ftpdocs/102xx/doc10294/08-06-BudgetOptions

    32 SOCIAL SECURITY POLICY OPTIONS

    CBO

    consideration, however, is that the cost of living could
    grow faster for elderly people than for the rest of the pop
    ulation. Inflation as measured by the CPI E, an experi
    mental version of the CPI that reflects the purchasing
    patterns of older people, has been 0.3 percentage points
    higher than the CPI W over the past three decades.

    Because most proposals to reduce the size of COLAs
    would result in an annually compounding reduction dur
    ing the course of a beneficiary’s receipt of benefits, the
    reduction in scheduled annual benefits would grow larger
    over time relative to current law. The difference in annual
    benefits would be most pronounced for beneficiaries who
    would receive benefits under a modified COLA option
    for long periods, such as very old retirees (who are more
    likely than younger retirees to be poor) and people who
    begin receiving DI benefits at an early age.

    A change in COLAs also would affect initial benefits
    claimed after the early eligibility age (currently set at 62),
    because COLAs are applied to the age 62 benefit every
    year, even for people who wait until after age 62 to
    claim benefits. Thus, a change in COLAs has a small
    effect on initial benefits at age 65. (See Table 2 on
    page 33 for the effects of the options on Social Security’s
    finances, Table 3 on page 39 for effects on distributional
    outcomes assuming that scheduled benefits are paid, and
    Table 4 on page 43 for effects on distributional outcomes
    assuming that only payable benefits are paid.)

    Option 29: Reduce COLAs by 0.5 Percentage Points
    This option would reduce the annual cost of living
    adjustment by 0.5 percentage points. The reduction
    would begin in 2012.

    Social Security’s total outlays would decline by 0.4 per
    centage points of GDP in 2040, or by 7 percent from
    currently scheduled outlays. This option would improve
    the 75 year actuarial balance by 0.3 percentage points of

    GDP and would extend the trust fund exhaustion date by
    nine years, to 2048.

    Scheduled lifetime benefits would be reduced by about
    6 percent for people born in the 1950s or later and would
    be smaller for older birth cohorts. For example, lifetime
    benefits would be reduced only slightly for people who
    turn 90 in 2012. Payable benefits would be slightly
    higher for people who will collect larger portions of their
    benefits in 2039 and later.

    Option 30:

    Base COLAs on the Chained CPI-U

    Beginning in 2012, this option would link Social Security
    cost of living adjustments to another measure of infla
    tion—the chained CPI U (consumer price index for all
    urban consumers)—which takes into account that con
    sumers generally adjust their spending patterns as some
    prices change relative to others. CBO projects that the
    chained CPI U will increase, on average, by 0.3 percent
    age points more slowly per year than will the CPI W.46

    Social Security’s total outlays would decline by 0.2 per
    centage points of GDP in 2040, or by 4 percent, from
    currently scheduled outlays. This option would improve
    the 75 year actuarial balance by 0.2 percentage points of
    GDP and would extend the trust fund exhaustion date by
    four years, to 2043.

    Compared with those scheduled under current law, life
    time benefits for people in all earnings categories would
    be reduced by about 3 percent. Payable lifetime benefits
    would not change significantly.

    46. The estimate of the effect of this option is based on CBO’s
    projection of the difference between growth in the CPI W and
    the chained CPI U, but the actual difference (and thus the effect
    of the option) would vary from year to year and could average
    more or less than 0.3 percent. For additional information, see
    Congressional Budget Office, Using a Different Measure of
    Inflation for Indexing Federal Programs and the Tax Code, Issue
    Brief (February 24, 2010), and Budget Options, Volume 2, p. 147.

    http://www.cbo.gov/ftpdocs/112xx/doc11256/CPI_brief

    http://www.cbo.gov/ftpdocs/102xx/doc10294/08-06-BudgetOptions

    SOCIAL SECURITY POLICY OPTIONS 33

    Table 2.

    Changes to Social Security’s Finances Under Various Options with Scheduled Benefits
    (Percentage of GDP)

    Continued

    2020 2040 2060 2080 Annual Finances

    Revenues and Outlaysb

    Revenues 4.9 4.9 4.9 5.0 5.2 14.4

    Outlays 5.2 6.2 6.0 6.3 5.8 16.0

    Balance -0.3 -1.3 -1.1 -1.3 -0.6 -1.6

    Change the Taxation of Earnings Change in Annual Balancec

    1 Revenues 0.4 0.4 0.3 0.3 0.3 1.0

    Outlaysd * * * * * *

    Balance 0.4 0.4 0.4 0.4 0.3 1.0

    2 Revenues 0.3 0.7 0.7 0.7 0.5 1.6

    Outlaysd * * * * * *

    Balance 0.3 0.7 0.7 0.8 0.6 1.6

    3 Revenues 0.2 0.5 0.8 1.0 0.5 1.5

    Outlaysd * * * * * *

    Balance 0.2 0.5 0.9 1.1 0.5 1.4

    4 Revenues 0.8 0.9 0.9 0.9 0.9 n.a.

    Outlays * 0.3 0.5 0.5 0.3 n.a.

    Balance 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.4 0.6 n.a.

    5 Revenues 0.3 0.4 0.4 0.4 0.4 n.a.

    Outlays * 0.1 0.2 0.2 0.1 n.a.

    Balance 0.3 0.3 0.2 0.2 0.2 n.a.

    Raise the Taxable
    Maximum to Cover 90% of

    Earningse

    75-Year

    Taxable

    Percentage-Point Change from

    Current Lawa

    Increase the Payroll Tax
    Rate by 1 Percentage Point
    in 2012

    Current Lawa
    Percentage of

    GDP

    Present Value as a

    Payroll

    Eliminate the Taxable

    Maximume

    Increase the Payroll Tax
    Rate by 2 Percentage
    Points Over 20 Years

    Increase the Payroll Tax
    Rate by 3 Percentage
    Points Over 60 years

    CBO

    34 SOCIAL SECURITY POLICY OPTIONS

    CBO

    Table 2. Continued

    Changes to Social Security’s Finances Under Various Options with Scheduled Benefits
    (Percentage of GDP)
    Continued
    2020 2040 2060 2080 Annual Finances

    Change the Taxation of Earnings (Continued) Change in Annual Balancec

    6 Revenues 0.8 0.9 0.9 0.9 0.8 n.a.

    Outlaysd * * * * * n.a.

    Balance 0.9 0.9 0.9 0.9 0.9 n.a.

    7 Revenues 0.5 0.5 0.5 0.5 0.5 n.a.

    Outlaysd * * * * * n.a.

    Balance 0.5 0.6 0.6 0.6 0.5 n.a.

    8 Revenues 0.3 0.3 0.3 0.3 0.3 n.a.

    Outlaysd * * * * * n.a.

    Balance 0.3 0.3 0.3 0.3 0.3 n.a.

    9 Revenues 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 n.a.

    Outlaysd * * * * * n.a.

    Balance 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 n.a.

    Change the Benefit Formula

    10 Revenues * * * * * *

    Outlays * -0.1 -0.1 -0.1 -0.1 -0.2

    Balance * 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.2

    11 Revenues * * * * * *

    Outlays * -0.1 -0.4 -0.6 -0.2 -0.5

    Balance * 0.1 0.4 0.5 0.2 0.5

    Tax Covered Earnings Up to
    $250,000; Do Not Increase

    Benefitse

    Tax All Earnings Above
    $250,000 at 4%; Do Not

    Increase Benefitse

    Raise from 35 to 38 the
    Years of Earnings Included
    in the AIME

    Tax Covered Earnings
    Above the Taxable
    Maximum; Do Not Increase

    Benefitse
    Percentage of

    GDP Payroll

    Percentage-Point Change from Current Lawa (Continued)

    Tax All Earnings Above the
    Taxable Maximum at 4%;

    Do Not Increase Benefitse

    Taxable
    Present Value as a

    Index Earnings in the AIME
    Formula to Prices

    SOCIAL SECURITY POLICY OPTIONS 35

    Table 2. Continued
    Changes to Social Security’s Finances Under Various Options with Scheduled Benefits
    (Percentage of GDP)
    Continued
    2020 2040 2060 2080 Annual Finances

    Change the Benefit Formula (Continued) Change in Annual Balancec

    12 Revenues * -0.1 -0.1 -0.1 * -0.1

    Outlays -0.2 -0.7 -0.9 -0.9 -0.6 -1.6

    Balance 0.2 0.7 0.8 0.8 0.5 1.5

    13 Revenues * -0.1 -0.1 -0.1 -0.1 -0.2

    Outlays -0.2 -1.0 -1.1 -1.2 -0.8 -2.1

    Balance 0.2 0.9 1.0 1.1 0.7 2.0

    14 Revenues * * * * * *

    Outlays * -0.1 -0.1 -0.1 -0.1 -0.2
    Balance * 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.2

    15 Revenues * * -0.1 -0.1 * -0.1

    Outlays * -0.3 -0.8 -1.3 -0.5 -1.3

    Balance * 0.3 0.8 1.2 0.4 1.2

    16 Revenues * * * -0.1 * -0.1

    Outlays * -0.2 -0.4 -0.7 -0.2 -0.6

    Balance * 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.2 0.6

    17 Revenues * -0.1 -0.2 -0.3 -0.1 -0.2

    Outlays * -0.9 -1.9 -2.9 -1.1 -2.9

    Balance * 0.8 1.7 2.6 1.0 2.7

    Percentage of

    Payroll
    Taxable

    GDP

    75-Year
    Present Value as a

    Percentage-Point Change from Current Lawa (Continued)

    Reduce the Top PIA Factor
    by One-Third

    Reduce All PIA Factors by
    0.5% Annually

    Reduce All PIA Factors
    by 15%

    Reduce the Top Two
    PIA Factors by Roughly
    One-Third

    Reduce PIA Factors to
    Index Initial Benefits to
    Prices Rather Than
    Earnings

    Index Initial Benefits to
    Changes in Longevity
    CBO

    36 SOCIAL SECURITY POLICY OPTIONS

    CBO
    Table 2. Continued
    Changes to Social Security’s Finances Under Various Options with Scheduled Benefits
    (Percentage of GDP)
    Continued
    2020 2040 2060 2080 Annual Finances
    Change the Benefit Formula (Continued) Change in Annual Balancec

    18 Revenues * * -0.1 -0.1 -0.1 -0.1

    Outlays * -0.4 -1.0 -1.5 -0.5 -1.5

    Balance * 0.4 0.9 1.4 0.5 1.4

    19 Revenues * * -0.1 -0.1 0 -0.1

    Outlays * -0.4 -0.8 -1.1 -0.4 -1.2

    Balance * 0.3 0.7 1.0 0.4 1.1

    20 Revenues * * -0.1 -0.1 * -0.1

    Outlays * -0.4 -0.9 -1.5 -0.5 -1.5

    Balance * 0.4 0.9 1.4 0.5 1.3

    21 Revenues * * -0.1 -0.2 -0.1 -0.1

    Outlays * -0.5 -1.2 -1.9 -0.7 -1.9

    Balance * 0.5 1.1 1.7 0.6 1.7

    22 Revenues * * * * * *

    Outlays -0.1 -0.3 -0.2 -0.3 -0.2 -0.6

    Balance 0.1 0.3 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.5

    Increase Benefits for Low Earners

    23 Revenues * * * 0.1 * 0.1

    Outlays 0.1 0.2 0.5 0.5 0.3 0.7

    Balance -0.1 -0.2 -0.4 -0.5 -0.2 -0.7

    Earnings

    Lower Initial Benefits for
    the Top 70% of Earners

    75-Year
    Present Value as a

    Percentage of
    Taxable

    GDP Payroll
    Percentage-Point Change from Current Lawa (Continued)

    Index Earnings in the AIME
    and Bend Points in the PIA
    Formula to Prices

    Modify the Special
    Minimum Benefit and
    Index It to Growth in

    Replace the Current
    PIA Formula with a New
    Two-Part Formula

    Index the Bend Points in
    the PIA Formula to Prices

    Lower Initial Benefits for
    the Top 50% of Earners

    SOCIAL SECURITY POLICY OPTIONS 37

    Table 2. Continued
    Changes to Social Security’s Finances Under Various Options with Scheduled Benefits
    (Percentage of GDP)
    Continued
    2020 2040 2060 2080 Annual Finances

    Increase Benefits for Low Earners (Continued) Change in Annual Balancec

    24 Revenues * * * * * *

    Outlays * * 0.1 * * 0.1

    Balance * * * * * -0.1

    25 Revenues * * * * * 0.1

    Outlays 0.2 0.4 0.5 0.5 0.4 1.0

    Balance -0.2 -0.4 -0.4 -0.4 -0.3 -0.9

    Raise the Full Retirement Age

    26 Revenues 0 * * * * *

    Outlays 0 -0.2 -0.3 -0.3 -0.2 -0.4

    Balance 0 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.1 0.4

    27 Revenues 0 * -0.1 -0.1 * -0.1

    Raise the FRA to 70f Outlays 0 -0.4 -0.7 -0.7 -0.4 -1.0

    Balance 0 0.3 0.6 0.6 0.3 0.9

    28 Revenues 0 * * -0.1 * -0.1

    Outlays 0 -0.1 -0.4 -0.6 -0.2 -0.5

    Balance 0 0.1 0.3 0.5 0.2 0.5

    GDP Payroll
    Percentage-Point Change from Current Lawa (Continued)

    Raise the FRA to 68f

    Index the FRA to Changes

    in Longevityf

    75-Year
    Present Value as a
    Percentage of
    Taxable

    Introduce a New Poverty-
    Related Minimum Benefit

    Enhance Low-Earners’
    Benefits on the Basis of
    Years Worked

    CBO

    38 SOCIAL SECURITY POLICY OPTIONS

    CBO
    Table 2. Continued
    Changes to Social Security’s Finances Under Various Options with Scheduled Benefits
    (Percentage of GDP)
    Source: Congressional Budget Office.

    Notes: Scheduled benefits are full benefits as calculated under current law, regardless of the amounts available in the Social Security trust
    funds.

    The 75-year period is 2010 through 2084. Revenues consist of payroll taxes and income taxes on benefits (but not interest credited to
    the trust funds) in the specified year. Outlays consist of Social Security benefits and administrative costs. The balance is the surplus or
    deficit, which is the difference between revenues and outlays. Details of specific options are contained in the text.

    GDP = gross domestic product; AIME = average indexed monthly earnings; PIA= primary insurance amount;
    FRA = full retirement age; COLA =cost-of-living adjustment; CPI-U = consumer price index for all urban consumers;
    * = between -0.05 and 0.05 percentage points, but not exactly zero; 0 = exactly zero, with no rounding; n.a. = not applicable.

    a. “Current law” refers to current Social Security provisions for calculating benefits and payroll taxes. See Congressional Budget Office,
    The Long-Term Budget Outlook (June 2010).

    b. The line graph shows projected revenues (lower line) and outlays (upper line) as a percentage of GDP over the period from 2020 to 2080.
    The range is from 3.5 percent to 7.0 percent of GDP.

    c. The area graphs depict the change in the annual trust fund balance over the period from 2020 to 2080. The range is from -1.0 percent to
    3.0 percent of GDP.

    d. For options that would increase payroll taxes but not benefits, the ratio of outlays to GDP would be slightly reduced because GDP would
    increase slightly. Although CBO’s model generally keeps GDP growth steady, adjustments in response to reduced budget deficits occur
    with a lag, allowing small variations.

    e. Under this option, the size of the tax base would change, so the changes in the 75-year present values of revenues, outlays, and the
    actuarial balance are more clearly represented as a percentage of GDP.

    f. Because this option would take effect after the FRA reaches age 67 under current law in 2022, no system finance changes are reported for
    2020.

    2020 2040 2060 2080 Annual Finances

    Reduce Cost-of-Living Adjustments Change in Annual Balancec

    29 Revenues * * * -0.1 * -0.1

    Outlays -0.2 -0.4 -0.4 -0.4 -0.3 -0.8

    Balance 0.2 0.4 0.4 0.4 0.3 0.8

    30 Revenues * * * * * *

    Outlays -0.1 -0.2 -0.2 -0.3 -0.2 -0.5

    Balance 0.1 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.5

    Reduce COLAs by
    0.5 Percentage Points

    Base COLAs on the Chained
    CPI-U

    75-Year
    Present Value as a
    Percentage of
    Taxable
    GDP Payroll
    Percentage-Point Change from Current Lawa (Continued)

    http://www.cbo.gov/doc.cfm?index=10457

    http://www.cbo.gov/ftpdocs/115xx/doc11559/

    SOCIAL SECURITY POLICY OPTIONS 39

    Table 3.

    Changes to Social Security’s Scheduled Benefits and Payroll Taxes for
    Different Groups Under Various Options

    Continued

    Lifetime
    Household
    Earnings
    Quintilea 1960 1980 2000 1960 1980 2000 1960 1980 2000

    Low 11 14 18 110 130 180 90 110 140
    Middle 20 24 32 250 300 420 320 370 490

    High 31 38 50 400 500 680 670 780 1,070

    Change the Taxation of Earnings

    1 Low 0 0 0 0 0 0 3 6 6
    Middle 0 0 0 0 0 0 3 6 9

    High 0 0 0 0 0 0 3 6 6

    2 Low 0 0 0 0 0 0 3 6 15
    Middle 0 0 0 0 0 0 3 9 15

    High 0 0 0 0 0 0 3 12 15

    3 Low 0 0 0 0 0 0 * 3 12
    Middle 0 0 0 0 0 0 * 6 15

    High 0 0 0 0 0 0 3 6 15

    4 Low * * * * * * * * *
    Middle * * * * * * * * *

    High 3 6 9 9 15 15 12 15 18

    5 Low * * * * * * * * *
    Middle * * * * * * * * *

    High 3 6 6 3 9 9 6 12 15

    6 Low 0 0 0 0 0 0 * * *
    Middle 0 0 0 0 0 0 * * *

    High 0 0 0 0 0 0 12 15 18

    7 Low 0 0 0 0 0 0 * * *
    Middle 0 0 0 0 0 0 * * 3

    High 0 0 0 0 0 0 12 15 18

    8 Low 0 0 0 0 0 0 * * *
    Middle 0 0 0 0 0 0 * * *

    High 0 0 0 0 0 0 6 6 9

    Median Initial Benefits

    for Retired Workers by Benefits by 10-Year Payroll Taxes by

    Median Lifetime Median Lifetime

    10-Year Birth Cohortb

    Birth Cohortc 10-Year Birth Cohortc

    Increase the Payroll Tax Rate by
    1 Percentage Point in 2012

    Eliminate the Taxable Maximum

    Current Lawd (Thousands of 2010 dollars)

    Increase the Payroll Tax Rate by
    2 Percentage Points Over 20 Years

    Increase the Payroll Tax Rate by
    3 Percentage Points Over 60 Years

    Percentage Change from Current Lawd

    Raise the Taxable Maximum to
    Cover 90% of Earnings

    Tax Covered Earnings Above the
    Taxable Maximum; Do Not Increase
    Benefits

    Tax Covered Earnings Up to
    $250,000; Do Not Increase Benefits

    Tax All Earnings Above the Taxable
    Maximum at 4%; Do Not Increase
    Benefits

    CBO

    40 SOCIAL SECURITY POLICY OPTIONS

    CBO

    Table 3. Continued

    Changes to Social Security’s Scheduled Benefits and Payroll Taxes for
    Different Groups Under Various Options
    Continued
    Lifetime
    Household
    Earnings
    Quintilea 1960 1980 2000 1960 1980 2000 1960 1980 2000

    Change the Taxation of Earnings (Continued)

    9 Low 0 0 0 0 0 0 * * *
    Middle 0 0 0 0 0 0 * * *

    High 0 0 0 0 0 0 3 3 3

    Change the Benefit Formula

    10 Low -3 -3 -3 -3 -3 -3 0 0 0
    Middle -3 -3 -3 -3 -3 -3 0 0 0

    High -3 -3 -3 -3 -3 -3 0 0 0

    11 Low * -6 -12 * -6 -12 0 0 0
    Middle * -9 -12 * -9 -12 0 0 0

    High * -6 -6 * -3 -6 0 0 0

    12 Low -15 -15 -15 -12 -12 -12 0 0 0
    Middle -15 -15 -15 -12 -15 -15 0 0 0

    High -15 -15 -15 -15 -12 -15 0 0 0

    13 Low -3 -3 -3 -6 -3 -3 0 0 0
    Middle -18 -18 -18 -18 -18 -18 0 0 0

    High -24 -24 -24 -24 -24 -24 0 0 0

    14 Low * * * * * * 0 0 0
    Middle * * * * * * 0 0 0

    High -3 -3 -3 -6 -6 -6 0 0 0

    15 Low -6 -15 -21 -3 -12 -18 0 0 0
    Middle -6 -15 -21 -3 -15 -21 0 0 0

    High -6 -15 -21 -6 -12 -21 0 0 0

    16 Low -3 -9 -12 -3 -6 -12 0 0 0
    Middle -3 -9 -12 -3 -9 -12 0 0 0

    High -3 -9 -12 -3 -9 -12 0 0 0

    17 Low -15 -33 -48 -12 -27 -39 0 0 0
    Middle -15 -33 -48 -12 -30 -45 0 0 0

    High -15 -33 -48 -12 -33 -48 0 0 0

    Reduce the Top PIA Factor by
    One-Third

    Reduce All PIA Factors by 0.5%
    Annually

    Index Earnings in the AIME
    Formula to Prices

    Reduce All PIA Factors by 15%

    Tax All Earnings Above $250,000 at
    4%; Do Not Increase Benefits

    Raise from 35 to 38 the Years of
    Earnings Included in the AIME

    Reduce the Top Two PIA Factors by
    Roughly One-Third

    Median Initial Benefits
    for Retired Workers by

    Index Initial Benefits to Changes in
    Longevity

    Reduce PIA Factors to Index Initial
    Benefits to Prices Rather Than
    Earnings

    Median Lifetime Median Lifetime

    Birth Cohortc 10-Year Birth Cohortc
    Benefits by 10-Year Payroll Taxes by

    Percentage Change from Current Lawd (Continued)

    10-Year Birth Cohortb

    SOCIAL SECURITY POLICY OPTIONS 41

    Table 3. Continued
    Changes to Social Security’s Scheduled Benefits and Payroll Taxes for
    Different Groups Under Various Options
    Continued
    Lifetime
    Household
    Earnings
    Quintilea 1960 1980 2000 1960 1980 2000 1960 1980 2000

    Change the Benefit Formula (Continued)

    18 Low * * * * * * 0 0 0
    Middle -6 -15 -21 -6 -15 -21 0 0 0

    High -12 -30 -45 -12 -30 -45 0 0 0

    19 Low * * * * * * 0 0 0
    Middle * * -3 -3 -6 -9 0 0 0

    High -12 -27 -36 -12 -30 -36 0 0 0

    20 Low -9 -21 -27 -6 -12 -18 0 0 0
    Middle -6 -12 -21 -3 -12 -21 0 0 0

    High -9 -18 -27 -6 -15 -24 0 0 0

    21 Low -9 -24 -36 -6 -18 -27 0 0 0
    Middle -6 -21 -30 -6 -18 -30 0 0 0

    High -9 -24 -36 -9 -21 -30 0 0 0

    22 Low -15 -6 -6 -6 3 3 0 0 0
    Middle -15 -15 -15 -9 -6 -9 0 0 0

    High -21 -21 -21 -9 -9 -12 0 0 0

    Increase Benefits for Low Earners

    23 Low * 15 24 6 24 30 0 0 0
    Middle * * * 6 9 9 0 0 0

    High * * * * * * 0 0 0

    24 Low 3 6 6 3 6 6 0 0 0
    Middle * * * * * * 0 0 0

    High * * * * * * 0 0 0

    25 Low 15 21 24 18 21 24 0 0 0
    Middle 9 15 15 9 12 12 0 0 0

    High * * * * * * 0 0 0
    Raise the Full Retirement Age

    26 Low -6 -9 -9 -3 -6 -6 0 0 0
    Raise the FRA to 68 Middle -6 -9 -9 -3 -6 -6 0 0 0

    High -6 -9 -9 -3 -6 -6 0 0 0

    Index the Bend Points in the PIA
    Formula to Prices

    Lower Initial Benefits for the
    Top 50% of Earners

    Index Earnings in the AIME and
    Bend Points in the PIA Formula to
    Prices

    Replace the Current PIA Formula
    with a New Two-Part Formula

    Introduce a New Poverty-Related
    Minimum Benefit

    Enhance Low-Earners’ Benefits on
    the Basis of Years Worked

    Modify the Special Minimum
    Benefit and Index It to Growth in

    Lower Initial Benefits for the
    Top 70% of Earners

    10-Year Birth Cohortb Birth Cohortc 10-Year Birth Cohortc

    Median Initial Benefits Median Lifetime Median Lifetime

    Percentage Change from Current Lawd (Continued)

    for Retired Workers by Benefits by 10-Year Payroll Taxes by
    CBO

    42 SOCIAL SECURITY POLICY OPTIONS

    CBO
    Table 3. Continued
    Changes to Social Security’s Scheduled Benefits and Payroll Taxes for
    Different Groups Under Various Options
    Source: Congressional Budget Office.

    Notes: Scheduled benefits are full benefits as calculated under current law, regardless of the amounts available in the Social Security trust
    funds. Percentage changes are rounded to 3 percentage points to give a sense of the likely effects on benefits and payroll taxes
    without showing numerous small differences in outcomes that are not analytically meaningful. Median values are within a group; half
    of the people in each group (defined by lifetime household earnings category and birth cohort) would have a lower value and half
    would have a higher value. Details of specific options are contained in the text.

    AIME = average indexed monthly earnings; PIA = primary insurance amount; FRA = full retirement age; COLA = cost-of-living
    adjustment; CPI-U = consumer price index for all urban consumers; * = between -1.5 percent and 1.5 percent, but not exactly zero;
    0 = exactly zero, with no rounding.

    a. The lowest fifth, middle fifth, and highest fifth of people ranked by lifetime household earnings, within a 10-year birth cohort.

    b. Assumes that all workers claim benefits at age 65.

    c. Lifetime benefits and lifetime taxes are present values discounted to age 62.

    d. “Current law” refers to current Social Security provisions for calculating benefits and payroll taxes. See Congressional Budget Office,
    The Long-Term Budget Outlook (June 2010).

    Lifetime
    Household
    Earnings
    Quintilea 1960 1980 2000 1960 1980 2000 1960 1980 2000

    Raise the Full Retirement Age (Continued)

    27 Low -6 -18 -18 -3 -15 -15 0 0 0
    Raise the FRA to 70 Middle -6 -18 -18 -3 -15 -15 0 0 0

    High -6 -18 -18 -6 -15 -15 0 0 0

    28 Low -3 -9 -15 * -6 -9 0 0 0
    Middle -3 -9 -15 -3 -9 -12 0 0 0

    High -3 -9 -15 -3 -6 -12 0 0 0

    Reduce Cost-of-Living Adjustments

    29 Low * * * -6 -6 -6 0 0 0
    Middle * * * -6 -6 -6 0 0 0

    High * * * -6 -6 -6 0 0 0

    30 Low * * * -3 -3 -3 0 0 0
    Base COLAs on the Chained CPI-U Middle * * * -3 -3 -3 0 0 0

    High * * * -3 -3 -3 0 0 0

    Index the FRA to Changes in
    Longevity

    Reduce COLAs by 0.5 Percentage
    Points

    Percentage Change from Current Lawd (Continued)
    10-Year Birth Cohortb Birth Cohortc 10-Year Birth Cohortc

    Median Initial Benefits
    for Retired Workers by Benefits by 10-Year Payroll Taxes by

    Median Lifetime Median Lifetime

    http://www.cbo.gov/doc.cfm?index=10457

    http://www.cbo.gov/ftpdocs/115xx/doc11559/

    SOCIAL SECURITY POLICY OPTIONS 43

    Table 4.

    Changes to Social Security’s Payable Benefits and Payroll Taxes for
    Different Groups Under Various Options

    Continued
    Lifetime
    Household
    Earnings
    Quintilea 1960 1980 2000 1960 1980 2000 1960 1980 2000

    Low 11 11 14 100 110 150 90 110 140
    Middle 20 20 25 230 250 320 320 370 490

    High 30 31 40 370 410 530 660 790 1,070

    Change the Taxation of Earnings

    1 Low * 21 9 3 12 9 3 6 9
    Middle * 21 12 9 15 9 3 6 9

    High * 21 9 9 12 9 3 6 6

    2 Low * 21 27 3 15 21 3 6 15
    Middle * 21 27 6 21 24 3 9 15

    High * 21 24 9 21 21 3 12 15

    3 Low * 21 21 6 15 21 * 3 12
    Middle * 21 24 9 21 24 * 6 15

    High * 21 21 9 18 21 3 6 15

    4 Low * 21 27 3 15 18 * * *
    Eliminate the Taxable Maximum Middle * 21 27 6 18 21 * * *

    High 3 30 36 21 39 42 12 15 18

    5 Low * 15 6 3 6 6 * * *
    Middle * 15 9 9 9 9 * * *

    High 3 21 12 12 15 15 6 12 15

    6 Low * 21 27 3 18 24 * * *
    Middle * 21 27 6 21 27 * * *

    High * 21 24 9 21 27 12 15 18

    7 Low * 21 27 3 18 18 * * *
    Middle * 21 27 9 21 21 * * 3

    High * 21 27 9 21 18 12 15 18

    8 Low * 18 9 6 9 9 * * *
    Middle * 18 9 9 9 9 * * *

    High * 18 9 9 9 6 6 6 9

    Current Lawd (Thousands of 2010 dollars)

    Percentage Change from Current Lawd

    Median Initial Benefits Median Lifetime Median Lifetime
    for Retired Workers by Benefits by Payroll Taxes by

    10-Year Birth Cohortb 10-Year Birth Cohortc 10-Year Birth Cohortc

    Raise the Taxable Maximum to Cover
    90% of Earnings

    Increase the Payroll Tax Rate by
    1 Percentage Point in 2012

    Tax All Earnings Above the Taxable
    Maximum at 4%; Do Not Increase
    Benefits

    Tax Covered Earnings Up to
    $250,000; Do Not Increase Benefits

    Increase the Payroll Tax Rate by
    2 Percentage Points Over 20 Years

    Increase the Payroll Tax Rate by
    3 Percentage Points Over 60 Years

    Tax Covered Earnings Above the
    Taxable Maximum; Do Not Increase
    Benefits
    CBO

    44 SOCIAL SECURITY POLICY OPTIONS

    CBO

    Table 4. Continued

    Changes to Social Security’s Payable Benefits and Payroll Taxes for
    Different Groups Under Various Options
    Continued
    Lifetime
    Household
    Earnings
    Quintilea 1960 1980 2000 1960 1980 2000 1960 1980 2000
    Change the Taxation of Earnings (Continued)

    9 Low * 3 3 3 3 3 * * *
    Middle * 3 3 3 3 3 * * *

    High * 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3

    Change the Benefit Formula

    10 Low -3 -3 * -3 -3 * 0 0 0
    Middle -3 -3 -3 * * * 0 0 0

    High -3 * * * * * 0 0 0

    11 Low * -3 -6 * -3 -3 0 0 0
    Middle * -6 -6 * -3 -3 0 0 0

    High * -3 * * * 3 0 0 0

    12 Low -15 3 9 -9 3 6 0 0 0
    Reduce All PIA Factors by 15% Middle -15 3 9 -6 6 6 0 0 0

    High -15 3 9 -6 6 3 0 0 0

    13 Low -3 18 24 * 15 21 0 0 0
    Reduce the Top Two PIA Factors by Middle -18 * 3 -12 3 6 0 0 0
    Roughly One-Third High -24 -9 -6 -18 -6 -3 0 0 0

    14 Low * * 3 * 3 3 0 0 0
    Middle * 3 3 3 3 3 0 0 0

    High -3 -3 -3 -3 -3 -3 0 0 0

    15 Low -6 -6 -6 * * * 0 0 0
    Middle -6 -6 -6 * * * 0 0 0

    High -6 -6 -6 * * * 0 0 0

    16 Low -3 -6 -6 * -3 -3 0 0 0
    Middle -3 -6 -6 * -3 * 0 0 0

    High -3 -6 -6 * -3 -3 0 0 0

    17 Low -15 -18 -33 -9 -15 -27 0 0 0
    Middle -15 -18 -33 -6 -15 -30 0 0 0

    High -15 -18 -33 -6 -18 -33 0 0 0

    10-Year Birth Cohortb 10-Year Birth Cohortc 10-Year Birth Cohortc
    Percentage Change from Current Lawd (Continued)

    Median Initial Benefits
    for Retired Workers by Benefits by Payroll Taxes by

    Median Lifetime Median Lifetime

    Tax All Earnings Above $250,000 at
    4%; Do Not Increase Benefits

    Raise from 35 to 38 the Years of
    Earnings Included in the AIME
    Reduce All PIA Factors by 0.5%
    Annually
    Index Initial Benefits to Changes in
    Longevity

    Index Earnings in the AIME Formula
    to Prices

    Reduce the Top PIA Factor by
    One-Third

    Reduce PIA Factors to Index Initial
    Benefits to Prices Rather Than
    Earnings

    SOCIAL SECURITY POLICY OPTIONS 45

    Table 4. Continued
    Changes to Social Security’s Payable Benefits and Payroll Taxes for
    Different Groups Under Various Options
    Continued
    Lifetime
    Household
    Earnings
    Quintilea 1960 1980 2000 1960 1980 2000 1960 1980 2000

    Change the Benefit Formula (Continued)
    18 Low * 12 24 3 12 27 0 0 0

    Middle -6 -3 -3 * * * 0 0 0
    High -12 -24 -33 -6 -18 -30 0 0 0

    19 Low * 9 18 3 12 18 0 0 0
    Middle * 6 15 3 6 9 0 0 0

    High -12 -24 -24 -9 -21 -24 0 0 0

    20 Low -9 -12 -12 * -3 * 0 0 0
    Middle -3 * * * * * 0 0 0

    High -9 -12 -12 * -3 -3 0 0 0

    21 Low -9 -12 -21 -3 -3 -9 0 0 0
    Middle -6 -6 -9 3 -3 -9 0 0 0

    High -9 -12 -18 * -6 -9 0 0 0

    22 Low -15 * -3 -3 6 9 0 0 0
    Replace the Current PIA Formula Middle -15 -9 -12 -3 -3 -3 0 0 0
    with a New Two-Part Formula High -21 -18 -21 -6 -9 -9 0 0 0

    Increase Benefits for Low Earners

    23 Low * 9 12 3 15 21 0 0 0
    Middle * -6 -6 * 3 3 0 0 0

    High * -6 -9 -3 -6 -9 0 0 0

    24 Low 3 6 6 3 6 6 0 0 0
    Middle * * * * * * 0 0 0
    High * * * * * * 0 0 0

    25 Low 15 12 12 9 12 12 0 0 0
    Middle 9 6 6 * 6 3 0 0 0

    High * -6 -9 -9 -6 -9 0 0 0

    Raise the Full Retirement Age

    26 Low -6 -6 -3 * -3 * 0 0 0
    Raise the FRA to 68 Middle -6 -6 -3 -3 * * 0 0 0

    High -6 -6 -3 * -3 -3 0 0 0

    10-Year Birth Cohortb 10-Year Birth Cohortc 10-Year Birth Cohortc
    Percentage Change from Current Lawd (Continued)
    Median Initial Benefits
    for Retired Workers by Benefits by Payroll Taxes by
    Median Lifetime Median Lifetime

    Modify the Special Minimum Benefit
    and Index It to Growth in Earnings

    Index the Bend Points in the PIA
    Formula to Prices
    Lower Initial Benefits for the
    Top 70% of Earners
    Lower Initial Benefits for the
    Top 50% of Earners
    Index Earnings in the AIME and
    Bend Points in the PIA Formula to
    Prices
    Introduce a New Poverty-Related
    Minimum Benefit
    Enhance Low-Earners’ Benefits on
    the Basis of Years Worked
    CBO

    46 SOCIAL SECURITY POLICY OPTIONS

    CBO
    Table 4. Continued
    Changes to Social Security’s Payable Benefits and Payroll Taxes for
    Different Groups Under Various Options
    Source: Congressional Budget Office.

    Notes: Payable benefits are benefits as calculated under current law, reduced as necessary to make outlays equal the Social Security system’s
    revenues. Percentage changes are rounded to 3 percentage points to give a sense of the likely effects on benefits and payroll taxes
    without showing numerous small differences in outcomes that are not analytically meaningful. Median values are within a group; half
    of the people in each group (defined by lifetime household earnings category and birth cohort) would have a lower value and half
    would have a higher value. Details of specific options are contained in the text.

    AIME = average indexed monthly earnings; PIA = primary insurance amount; FRA = full retirement age; COLA = cost-of-living
    adjustment; CPI-U = consumer price index for all urban consumers; * = between -1.5 percent and 1.5 percent, but not exactly zero;
    0 = exactly zero, with no rounding.
    a. The lowest fifth, middle fifth, and highest fifth of people ranked by lifetime household earnings, within a 10-year birth cohort.
    b. Assumes that all workers claim benefits at age 65.
    c. Lifetime benefits and lifetime taxes are present values discounted to age 62.

    d. “Current law” refers to current Social Security provisions for calculating benefits and payroll taxes. See Congressional Budget Office,
    The Long-Term Budget Outlook (June 2010).

    Lifetime
    Household
    Earnings
    Quintilea 1960 1980 2000 1960 1980 2000 1960 1980 2000
    Raise the Full Retirement Age (Continued)

    27 Low -6 -12 -9 * -6 -3 0 0 0
    Raise the FRA to 70 Middle -6 -12 -9 * -6 -6 0 0 0

    High -6 -12 -9 * -9 -6 0 0 0

    28 Low -3 -6 -9 * -3 -3 0 0 0
    Middle -3 -6 -9 * -3 -3 0 0 0

    High -3 -6 -9 * -3 -6 0 0 0

    Reduce Cost-of-Living Adjustments

    29 Low -3 12 6 * 3 3 0 0 0
    Middle * 12 6 * 3 * 0 0 0

    High * 12 6 3 * * 0 0 0

    30 Low * 3 3 * * 3 0 0 0
    Middle * 3 6 * * * 0 0 0

    High * 3 3 * * * 0 0 0

    Percentage Change from Current Lawd (Continued)
    10-Year Birth Cohortb 10-Year Birth Cohortc 10-Year Birth Cohortc
    Median Initial Benefits
    for Retired Workers by Benefits by Payroll Taxes by
    Median Lifetime Median Lifetime

    Reduce COLAs by 0.5 Percentage
    Points

    Base COLAs on the Chained CPI-U
    Index the FRA to Changes in
    Longevity

    http://www.cbo.gov/doc.cfm?index=10457

    http://www.cbo.gov/ftpdocs/115xx/doc11559/

    Appendix:
    Distributional Effects of Options with

    Similar Effects on the System’s Finances

    The 30 policy options discussed in the main portion
    of this study would have a variety of effects on the Social
    Security system’s finances. The distributional trade offs
    become clearer, however, if the options are compared
    while their overall effects on the system’s finances are
    held constant. Therefore, in another exercise, the
    Congressional Budget Office compared the distributional
    effects of 8 additional policy options it derived from the
    original 30 with the objective of producing a single effect
    on the actuarial balance—each would reduce the 75 year
    actuarial deficit, relative to current law, by about one
    quarter, or by 0.15 percent of gross domestic product (see
    Table A 1 on page 49).

    B Option 1a: Increase the payroll tax rate by 0.42 per
    centage points in 2012 (Option 1 calls for an increase
    of 1 percentage point in the payroll tax).

    B Option 5a: Raise the taxable maximum to cover
    87 percent of earnings (Option 5 would raise the
    taxable maximum to cover 90 percent of earnings).

    B Option 7a: Apply the payroll tax to covered earnings
    between the taxable maximum and $136,000 with no
    additional benefits (Option 7 would cap earnings
    subject to tax at $250,000).

    B Option 8a: Apply a 1.9 percent tax to all covered earn
    ings above the taxable maximum with no additional
    benefits (Option 8 would apply a 4.0 percent tax).

    B Option 12a: Reduce all of the primary insurance
    amount (PIA) factors by 4 percent (Option 12 would
    reduce them by 15 percent).

    B Option 14a: Reduce the top PIA factor from 15 per
    cent to 4 percent (Option 14 would reduce the top
    factor from 15 percent to 10 percent).

    B Option 26a: Increase the full retirement age to
    68 years and 1 month (Option 26 would increase
    the age to 68 years).

    B Option 29a: Reduce cost of living adjustments
    (COLAs) by 0.25 percentage points (Option 29
    would reduce them by 0.5 percentage points).

    The first four options listed here (Options 1a, 5a, 7a, and
    8a) would primarily affect payroll taxes. (The increase in
    the taxable maximum also results in higher benefits.) In
    general, increasing taxes in 2012 would have less of an
    effect on workers born before the 1980s than on workers
    born in the 1980s and later because most of the younger
    groups’ earnings would be subject to higher taxes. Raising
    the payroll tax rate (Option 1a) would increase lifetime
    taxes by a similar proportion for all workers with earnings
    below the taxable maximum (in 2010, $106,800). The
    other three payroll options, by contrast, would raise life
    time taxes mainly for high earners, and the effects of the
    tax on all earnings above the taxable maximum would be
    more concentrated among the very highest earners.

    The remaining four options (Options 12a, 14a, 26a, and
    29a) would affect benefits but not tax rates. Reducing all
    of the PIA factors in various ways or reducing COLAs
    would have proportionately similar effects on lifetime
    benefits, regardless of when people were born or how
    much they earned. The lower PIA factors would reduce
    initial benefits; lower COLAs would diminish benefits
    over time and therefore cause greater reductions in

    CBO

    48 SOCIAL SECURITY POLICY OPTIONS

    CBO

    benefits for people who receive benefits for long periods.
    In addition, changes in COLAs would reduce benefits for
    existing beneficiaries; changes to the benefit formula
    would affect future beneficiaries only. An increase in the
    full retirement age, phased in over time, would lead to

    a greater reduction in benefits for people born later. By
    contrast, reducing just the top PIA factor would reduce
    benefits only for high earners and would result in similar
    reductions for everyone who was born after 1954 and has
    sufficiently high earnings.

    APPENDIX SOCIAL SECURITY POLICY OPTIONS 49

    Table A-1.

    Changes to Social Security’s Scheduled Benefits and Payroll Taxes for
    Different Groups Under Various Options That Have Similar Effects on the
    System’s Finances

    Continued

    Lifetime
    Household
    Earnings
    Quintilea 1960 1980 2000 1960 1980 2000

    Low 110 130 180 90 110 140
    Middle 250 300 420 320 370 490
    High 400 500 680 670 780 1,070

    Change Taxation of Earnings

    1a Low 0 0 0 * 3 3
    Middle 0 0 0 * 3 3
    High 0 0 0 * 3 3

    5a Low * * * * * *
    Middle * * * * * *
    High 3 3 6 3 9 9

    7a Low 0 0 0 * * *
    Middle 0 0 0 * * *
    High 0 0 0 3 6 6

    8a Low 0 0 0 * * *
    Middle 0 0 0 * * *
    High 0 0 0 3 3 3

    Tax All Earnings Above the Taxable
    Maximum at 1.9%; Do Not Increase
    Benefits

    Increase the Payroll Tax Rate by 0.42
    Percentage Points in 2012

    Raise the Taxable Maximum to Cover
    87% of Earnings

    Tax Covered Earnings Up to $136,000;
    Do Not Increase Benefits

    10-Year Birth Cohortb
    Median Lifetime Payroll Taxes byMedian Lifetime Benefits by

    10-Year Birth Cohortb

    Current Lawc (Thousands of 2010 dollars)

    Percentage Change from Current Lawc

    CBO

    50 SOCIAL SECURITY POLICY OPTIONS

    CBO

    Table A-1. Continued

    Changes to Social Security’s Scheduled Benefits and Payroll Taxes for
    Different Groups Under Various Options That Have Similar Effects on the
    System’s Finances
    Source: Congressional Budget Office.
    Notes: Scheduled benefits are full benefits as calculated under current law, regardless of the amounts available in the Social Security trust
    funds. Percentage changes are rounded to 3 percentage points to give a sense of the likely effects on benefits and payroll taxes
    without showing numerous small differences in outcomes that are not analytically meaningful. Median values are within a group; half
    of the people in each group (defined by lifetime household earnings category and birth cohort) would have a lower value and half
    would have a higher value. Details of specific options are contained in the text.

    PIA = primary insurance amount; FRA = full retirement age; COLA = cost-of-living adjustment; * = between -1.5 percent and
    1.5 percent, but not exactly zero; 0 = exactly zero, with no rounding.

    a. The lowest fifth, middle fifth, and highest fifth of people ranked by lifetime household earnings, within a 10-year birth cohort.

    b. Lifetime benefits and lifetime taxes are present values discounted to age 62.

    c. “Current law” refers to current Social Security provisions for calculating benefits and payroll taxes. See Congressional Budget Office,
    The Long-Term Budget Outlook (June 2010).

    Lifetime
    Household
    Earnings
    Quintilea 1960 1980 2000 1960 1980 2000
    Change the Benefit Formula

    12a Low -3 -3 -3 0 0 0
    Middle -3 -3 -3 0 0 0
    High -3 -3 -3 0 0 0

    14a Low * * * 0 0 0
    Middle * * * 0 0 0
    High -12 -9 -12 0 0 0

    26a Low -3 -6 -6 0 0 0
    Middle -3 -6 -6 0 0 0
    High -3 -6 -6 0 0 0

    29a Low -3 -3 -3 0 0 0
    Middle -3 -3 -3 0 0 0
    High -3 -3 -3 0 0 0

    10-Year Birth Cohortb 10-Year Birth Cohortb

    Reduce the Top PIA Factor from 15%
    to 4%

    Raise the FRA to 68 and 1 month

    Reduce COLAs by 0.25 Percentage
    Points

    Reduce All PIA Factors by 4.0%

    Percentage Change from Current Lawc (Continued)

    Median Lifetime Benefits by Median Lifetime Payroll Taxes by

    http://www.cbo.gov/doc.cfm?index=10457

    http://www.cbo.gov/ftpdocs/115xx/doc11559/

    Glossary

    actuarial balance: The present value over a specified
    period of the stream of projected trust fund revenues plus
    the trust funds’ initial balance minus the stream of
    projected outlays minus the value of a year’s worth of
    benefits as a reserve at the end of the period, expressed as
    a percentage of the present value of gross domestic
    product or taxable payroll over the same period.

    average indexed monthly earnings (AIME): For retired
    workers who attain age 62 after 1990, the AIME is
    calculated on the basis of the highest 35 years of earnings
    on which someone paid Social Security taxes (up to the
    taxable maximum, which is $106,800 in 2010). Earnings
    before age 60 are indexed to compensate both for
    inflation and for real (inflation adjusted) growth in
    earnings; earnings after age 59 enter the computations at
    actual amounts. (For disabled workers, earnings in the
    two years before the initial benefit computation enter at
    their actual amounts, and earlier earnings are indexed.)
    Dividing the total earnings (after indexing) by 420
    (35 years multiplied by 12 months) yields the AIME for
    retired workers. For disabled workers, total earnings are
    divided by a number of months that is linked to the age
    at which benefits begin.

    average wage index (AWI): The average amount of total
    wages in the United States in a year, including earnings in
    employment not covered by Social Security. Several
    automatic adjustments in Social Security are based on the
    AWI.

    baby boom generation: People born between 1946 and
    1964.

    bend point: An element in the formula for calculating
    initial benefits—namely, the threshold at which a PIA
    (primary insurance amount) factor changes. Under
    current law, there are two: in 2010, $761 and $4,568.

    Bend points change each year to keep pace with changes
    in the average earnings of the workforce as a whole.
    Therefore, bend points occur at approximately the same
    place in the distribution of average indexed monthly
    earnings each year and average initial benefits rise at a
    pace that matches the increase in average earnings over
    time.

    birth cohort: A group of people born during a given
    period. This analysis places people into 10 year birth
    cohorts: The 1960s birth cohort consists of people born
    between 1960 and 1969, the 1980s cohort includes those
    born between 1980 and 1989, and so on.

    cost of living adjustment (COLA): An annual increase
    in benefits tied to the increase in the cost of living. Under
    current law, the COLA for Social Security benefits is
    equal to the percentage increase in the consumer price
    index for urban wage earners and clerical workers from
    the third calendar quarter of the prior year to the third
    calendar quarter of the current year, provided that there is
    an increase.

    covered earnings: Total earnings (from wages and
    self employment income) for employment covered by
    Social Security.

    Disability Insurance Trust Fund: One of two Social
    Security trust funds, it is used to finance the activities of
    the Disability Insurance (DI) program. See trust funds.

    full retirement age (FRA): Also called the normal
    retirement age. The age at which a person becomes
    entitled to unreduced retirement benefits (benefits that
    are equal to the primary insurance amount). Currently
    age 66, the FRA is being increased gradually so it will be
    67 for people born in 1960 or later.

    CBO

    52 SOCIAL SECURITY POLICY OPTIONS

    CBO

    gross domestic product (GDP): The total market value
    of goods and services produced domestically in a given
    period.

    initial benefits for retired workers: Benefits that would
    be received by workers eligible to claim Old Age
    Insurance benefits at age 62 who have not yet claimed any
    other benefit. In this study, benefits are computed
    assuming that all workers claim benefits at age 65 and are
    based only on earnings through age 61. Values are net of
    income taxes paid on benefits and credited to the Social
    Security trust funds.

    initial replacement rate: The initial benefit as a
    percentage of average career annual earnings.

    lifetime benefits: In this study, the present value at age 62
    of benefits received by a person over a lifetime, net of
    income taxes paid on those benefits and credited to the
    Social Security trust funds. Lifetime benefits include
    payments received by people in the following beneficiary
    classes: old age workers, disabled workers, old age
    spouses, and old age widows. Because there are
    insufficient historical data on benefits for young widows
    and children for years before 1984, young widows,
    spouses of disabled workers, and child beneficiaries are
    not considered in this study.

    lifetime household earnings: For someone who is single
    in all years, the sum of real (inflation adjusted) earnings
    over a lifetime. In any year a person is married, the
    earnings measure is a function of his or her earnings plus
    those of his or her spouse (adjusted for economies of scale
    in household consumption). A person’s lifetime earnings
    consist of the present value of those annual amounts. In
    this study, for the initial benefits for retired workers and
    for the present value of lifetime benefits and payroll taxes,
    the values shown are changes in benefits or taxes for
    people in the lowest, middle, and highest one fifth
    (quintile) of lifetime household earnings.

    lifetime payroll taxes: The present value at age 62 of Old
    Age, Survivors, and Disability Insurance taxes paid by the
    employer and the employee over a lifetime; under current
    law, the tax is 12.4 percent of taxable earnings. This
    measure includes taxes paid by people who receive
    benefits from the Old Age and Survivors Insurance

    program (except young widows, spouses of disabled
    workers, and child beneficiaries).

    Old Age and Survivors Insurance Trust Fund: One of
    two Social Security trust funds, it is used to finance the
    activities of the Old Age and Survivors Insurance (OASI)
    program. See trust funds.

    payable benefits: Benefits as calculated under current law,
    reduced as necessary to make outlays equal the Social
    Security system’s revenues. Upon exhaustion of the Social
    Security trust funds, the Social Security Administration
    would reduce all scheduled benefits—those paid to
    existing beneficiaries and to new beneficiaries—by the
    percentage necessary to make the program’s total annual
    outlays equal its total available revenues. That percentage
    would vary each year.

    present value: A single amount that expresses a flow of
    current and future revenues or outlays in terms of an
    equivalent lump sum received or spent at one time,
    calculated by discounting future cash flows using a given
    interest rate. (The Congressional Budget Office projects a
    long term interest rate of 3 percent above price growth,
    which is used as the discount rate.)

    primary insurance amount (PIA): The monthly amount
    payable to a worker who begins receiving Social Security
    retirement benefits at the age at which he or she is eligible
    for full benefits, or the amount payable to a disabled
    worker who has never received a retirement benefit
    reduced for age. For workers who turn 62 or become
    disabled in 2010, for all of their dependents, and for
    dependents of workers who die in 2010, the PIA formula
    is 90 percent of the first $761 of the average indexed
    monthly earnings (AIME), plus 32 percent of the AIME
    between $761 and $4,586, plus 15 percent of the AIME
    above $4,586.

    primary insurance amount (PIA) factor: The percentage
    of the average indexed monthly earnings replaced in the
    PIA formula. Under current law, the PIA factors are
    90 percent below the first bend point, 32 percent
    between the two bend points, and 15 percent above the
    second bend point.

    quarter of coverage: The basic unit of measurement for
    determining insured status. In 2010, a worker receives

    GLOSSARY SOCIAL SECURITY POLICY OPTIONS 53

    one quarter of coverage (up to a total of four quarters in
    the year) for each $1,120 of annual covered earnings. The
    basic amount of earnings required for a quarter of
    coverage is increased annually at the same rate as the
    increase in the average wage index.

    replacement rate: The percentage of a worker’s past
    average earnings that his or her benefits represent.

    scheduled benefits: Full benefits as calculated under
    current law, regardless of the amounts available in the
    Social Security trust funds.

    sustainable solvency: A condition under which positive
    trust fund ratios are maintained throughout the 75 year
    projection period and ratios are stable or rising at the end
    of the period.

    taxable maximum: The maximum covered earnings
    upon which the Social Security payroll tax is levied each
    year. In 2010, that amount is $106,800. The taxable
    maximum amount is increased annually at the same rate
    as the increase in the average wage index.

    taxable payroll: The total earnings (from wages and self
    employment income) for employment covered by Social
    Security that is below the applicable annual taxable
    maximum.

    trust funds: Accounts to which Social Security taxes are
    credited. Interest on the balances in the funds also is
    credited to the trust funds, and Social Security benefits
    and administrative expenses are drawn from the funds.
    Social Security has two trust funds: the Old Age and
    Survivors Insurance (OASI) Trust Fund and the
    Disability Insurance (DI) Trust Fund. They are often
    treated collectively as the OASDI trust funds.

    trust fund balance: The amount credited to the Social
    Security trust funds; the balance determines the
    program’s current spending authority. The balance is held
    in the form of special Treasury securities, and the cash
    that generates the balance is used by the Treasury for
    other operations and activities of the government.

    trust fund exhaustion: The combined OASDI trust
    funds are exhausted if outlays in any given year are greater
    than the balance (including interest credited to the trust
    funds) at the beginning of the year.

    trust fund ratio: The balance in the Social Security trust
    funds at the beginning of the year, divided by projected
    outlays in that year.

    trust fund solvency: The combined OASDI trust funds
    are said to be solvent if the actuarial balance, calculated
    over 75 years, is greater than zero.

    CBO

      Notes
      Preface
      Contents
      Summary
      Social Security Policy Options
      Introduction
      An Overview of Social Security
      Social Security Projections
      Assessing Options for Changing Social Security
      Key Elements of Social Security
      Scope of the Options
      Effects of the Options on the System’s Finances
      Effects of the Options on Payroll Taxes Paid and Benefits Received by Various Groups
      Effects of the Options on Work and Saving
      Options That Would Change the Taxation of Earnings
      Options That Would Change the Benefit Formula
      Options That Would Increase Benefits for Low Earners
      Options That Would Raise the Full Retirement Age
      Options That Would Reduce Cost-of-Living Adjustments

    • Appendix: Distributional Effects of Options with Similar Effects on the System’s Finances
    • Glossary
      Tables
      1. Social Security’s Revenues and Outlays Under Current Law with Scheduled Benefits
      2. Changes to Social Security’s Finances Under Various Options with Scheduled Benefits
      3. Changes to Social Security’s Scheduled Benefits and Payroll Taxes for Different Groups Under Various Options
      4. Changes to Social Security’s Payable Benefits and Payroll Taxes for Different Groups Under Various Options
      A-1. Changes to Social Security’s Scheduled Benefits and Payroll Taxes for Different Groups Under Various Options That Have Similar Effects on the System’s Finances
      Figures
      1. Effects of the Policy Options on the OASDI Trust Fund Actuarial Balance
      1. Distribution of Social Security Beneficiaries, by Type of Benefits Received, 2010
      2. U.S. Population Age 65 or Older as a Percentage of the Population Ages 20 to 64, 1962 to 2080
      3. Social Security’s Revenues and Outlays with Scheduled and Payable Benefits
      4. Projected Outlays for Social Security Under Current Law and with a Gradual Reduction in Benefits Starting in 2012
      5. Effect of Delaying a Payroll Tax Increase or Benefit Reduction on Social Security’s Finances
      6. Calculating the PIA in 2010 Under the Current Social Security System
      7. Calculating Initial Benefits with Progressive Price Indexing
      8. Calculating Initial Benefits with Indexing of Bend Points to Prices
      Options
      Option 1: Increase the Payroll Tax Rate by 1 Percentage Point in 2012
      Option 2: Increase the Payroll Tax Rate by 2 Percentage Points Over 20 Years
      Option 3: Increase the Payroll Tax Rate by 3 Percentage Points Over 60 Years
      Option 4: Eliminate the Taxable Maximum
      Option 5: Raise the Taxable Maximum to Cover 90 Percent of Earnings
      Option 6: Tax Covered Earnings Above the Taxable Maximum; Do Not Increase Benefits
      Option 7: Tax Covered Earnings Up to $250,000; Do Not Increase Benefits
      Option 8: Tax All Earnings Above the Taxable Maximum at 4 Percent; Do Not Increase Benefits
      Option 9: Tax All Earnings Above $250,000 at 4 Percent; Do Not Increase Benefits
      Option 10: Raise from 35 to 38 the Years of Earnings Included in the AIME
      Option 11: Index Earnings in the AIME Formula to Prices
      Option 12: Reduce All PIA Factors by 15 Percent
      Option 13: Reduce the Top Two PIA Factors by Roughly One-Third
      Option 14: Reduce the Top PIA Factor by One-Third
      Option 15: Reduce All PIA Factors by 0.5 Percent Annually
      Option 16: Index Initial Benefits to Changes in Longevity
      Option 17: Reduce PIA Factors to Index Initial Benefits to Prices Rather Than Earnings
      Option 18: Lower Initial Benefits for the Top 70 Percent of Earners
      Option 19: Lower Initial Benefits for the Top 50 Percent of Earners
      Option 20: Index the Bend Points in the PIA Formula to Prices
      Option 21: Index Earnings in the AIME and Bend Points in the PIA Formula to Prices
      Option 22: Replace the Current PIA Formula with a New Two-Part Formula
      Option 23: Modify the Special Minimum Benefit and Index It to Growth in Earnings
      Option 24: Introduce a New Poverty-Related Minimum Benefit
      Option 25: Enhance Low-Earners’ Benefits on the Basis of Years Worked
      Option 26: Raise the FRA to 68
      Option 27: Raise the FRA to 70
      Option 28: Index the FRA to Changes in Longevity
      Option 29: Reduce COLAs by 0.5 Percentage Points
      Option 30: Base COLAs on the Chained CPI-U

    << /ASCII85EncodePages false /AllowTransparency false /AutoPositionEPSFiles true /AutoRotatePages /All /Binding /Left /CalGrayProfile (Gray Gamma 2.2) /CalRGBProfile (sRGB IEC61966-2.1) /CalCMYKProfile (U.S. Web Coated \050SWOP\051 v2) /sRGBProfile (sRGB IEC61966-2.1) /CannotEmbedFontPolicy /Warning /CompatibilityLevel 1.6 /CompressObjects /Tags /CompressPages true /ConvertImagesToIndexed true /PassThroughJPEGImages true /CreateJobTicket false /DefaultRenderingIntent /Default /DetectBlends true /DetectCurves 0.1000 /ColorConversionStrategy /LeaveColorUnchanged /DoThumbnails false /EmbedAllFonts true /EmbedOpenType false /ParseICCProfilesInComments true /EmbedJobOptions true /DSCReportingLevel 0 /EmitDSCWarnings false /EndPage -1 /ImageMemory 1048576 /LockDistillerParams false /MaxSubsetPct 100 /Optimize true /OPM 1 /ParseDSCComments true /ParseDSCCommentsForDocInfo true /PreserveCopyPage true /PreserveDICMYKValues true /PreserveEPSInfo false /PreserveFlatness true /PreserveHalftoneInfo false /PreserveOPIComments false /PreserveOverprintSettings true /StartPage 1 /SubsetFonts true /TransferFunctionInfo /Apply /UCRandBGInfo /Remove /UsePrologue true /ColorSettingsFile () /AlwaysEmbed [ true ] /NeverEmbed [ true /Arial-Black /Arial-BlackItalic /Arial-BoldItalicMT /Arial-BoldMT /Arial-ItalicMT /ArialMT /ArialNarrow /ArialNarrow-Bold /ArialNarrow-BoldItalic /ArialNarrow-Italic /ArialUnicodeMS /CenturyGothic /CenturyGothic-Bold /CenturyGothic-BoldItalic /CenturyGothic-Italic /CourierNewPS-BoldItalicMT /CourierNewPS-BoldMT /CourierNewPS-ItalicMT /CourierNewPSMT /Georgia /Georgia-Bold /Georgia-BoldItalic /Georgia-Italic /Impact /LucidaConsole /Tahoma /Tahoma-Bold /TimesNewRomanMT-ExtraBold /TimesNewRomanPS-BoldItalicMT /TimesNewRomanPS-BoldMT /TimesNewRomanPS-ItalicMT /TimesNewRomanPSMT /Trebuchet-BoldItalic /TrebuchetMS /TrebuchetMS-Bold /TrebuchetMS-Italic /Verdana /Verdana-Bold /Verdana-BoldItalic /Verdana-Italic ] /AntiAliasColorImages false /CropColorImages true /ColorImageMinResolution 150 /ColorImageMinResolutionPolicy /OK /DownsampleColorImages true /ColorImageDownsampleType /Bicubic /ColorImageResolution 150 /ColorImageDepth -1 /ColorImageMinDownsampleDepth 1 /ColorImageDownsampleThreshold 1.50000 /EncodeColorImages true /ColorImageFilter /DCTEncode /AutoFilterColorImages true /ColorImageAutoFilterStrategy /JPEG /ColorACSImageDict << /QFactor 0.76 /HSamples [2 1 1 2] /VSamples [2 1 1 2] >>
    /ColorImageDict << /QFactor 0.76 /HSamples [2 1 1 2] /VSamples [2 1 1 2] >>
    /JPEG2000ColorACSImageDict << /TileWidth 256 /TileHeight 256 /Quality 15 >>
    /JPEG2000ColorImageDict << /TileWidth 256 /TileHeight 256 /Quality 15 >>
    /AntiAliasGrayImages false
    /CropGrayImages true
    /GrayImageMinResolution 150
    /GrayImageMinResolutionPolicy /OK
    /DownsampleGrayImages true
    /GrayImageDownsampleType /Bicubic
    /GrayImageResolution 150
    /GrayImageDepth -1
    /GrayImageMinDownsampleDepth 2
    /GrayImageDownsampleThreshold 1.50000
    /EncodeGrayImages true
    /GrayImageFilter /DCTEncode
    /AutoFilterGrayImages true
    /GrayImageAutoFilterStrategy /JPEG
    /GrayACSImageDict << /QFactor 0.76 /HSamples [2 1 1 2] /VSamples [2 1 1 2] >>
    /GrayImageDict << /QFactor 0.76 /HSamples [2 1 1 2] /VSamples [2 1 1 2] >>
    /JPEG2000GrayACSImageDict << /TileWidth 256 /TileHeight 256 /Quality 15 >>
    /JPEG2000GrayImageDict << /TileWidth 256 /TileHeight 256 /Quality 15 >>
    /AntiAliasMonoImages false
    /CropMonoImages true
    /MonoImageMinResolution 1200
    /MonoImageMinResolutionPolicy /OK
    /DownsampleMonoImages true
    /MonoImageDownsampleType /Bicubic
    /MonoImageResolution 300
    /MonoImageDepth -1
    /MonoImageDownsampleThreshold 1.50000
    /EncodeMonoImages true
    /MonoImageFilter /CCITTFaxEncode
    /MonoImageDict << /K -1 >>
    /AllowPSXObjects true
    /CheckCompliance [
    /None
    ]
    /PDFX1aCheck false
    /PDFX3Check false
    /PDFXCompliantPDFOnly false
    /PDFXNoTrimBoxError true
    /PDFXTrimBoxToMediaBoxOffset [
    0.00000
    0.00000
    0.00000
    0.00000
    ]
    /PDFXSetBleedBoxToMediaBox true
    /PDFXBleedBoxToTrimBoxOffset [
    0.00000
    0.00000
    0.00000
    0.00000
    ]
    /PDFXOutputIntentProfile (None)
    /PDFXOutputConditionIdentifier ()
    /PDFXOutputCondition ()
    /PDFXRegistryName ()
    /PDFXTrapped /False
    /CreateJDFFile false
    /Description << /ARA
    /CHS
    /CHT
    /CZE
    /DAN
    /DEU
    /ESP
    /FRA
    /GRE
    /HEB
    /HRV (Za stvaranje Adobe PDF dokumenata pogodnih za pouzdani prikaz i ispis poslovnih dokumenata koristite ove postavke. Stvoreni PDF dokumenti mogu se otvoriti Acrobat i Adobe Reader 5.0 i kasnijim verzijama.)
    /HUN
    /ITA (Utilizzare queste impostazioni per creare documenti Adobe PDF adatti per visualizzare e stampare documenti aziendali in modo affidabile. I documenti PDF creati possono essere aperti con Acrobat e Adobe Reader 5.0 e versioni successive.)
    /JPN
    /KOR
    /NLD (Gebruik deze instellingen om Adobe PDF-documenten te maken waarmee zakelijke documenten betrouwbaar kunnen worden weergegeven en afgedrukt. De gemaakte PDF-documenten kunnen worden geopend met Acrobat en Adobe Reader 5.0 en hoger.)
    /NOR
    /POL
    /PTB
    /RUM
    /RUS
    /SLV
    /SUO
    /SVE
    /TUR
    /ENU (Use these settings to create Adobe PDF documents suitable for reliable viewing and printing of business documents. Created PDF documents can be opened with Acrobat and Adobe Reader 5.0 and later.)
    >>
    >> setdistillerparams
    << /HWResolution [600 600] /PageSize [612.000 792.000] >> setpagedevice

    What Will You Get?

    We provide professional writing services to help you score straight A’s by submitting custom written assignments that mirror your guidelines.

    Premium Quality

    Get result-oriented writing and never worry about grades anymore. We follow the highest quality standards to make sure that you get perfect assignments.

    Experienced Writers

    Our writers have experience in dealing with papers of every educational level. You can surely rely on the expertise of our qualified professionals.

    On-Time Delivery

    Your deadline is our threshold for success and we take it very seriously. We make sure you receive your papers before your predefined time.

    24/7 Customer Support

    Someone from our customer support team is always here to respond to your questions. So, hit us up if you have got any ambiguity or concern.

    Complete Confidentiality

    Sit back and relax while we help you out with writing your papers. We have an ultimate policy for keeping your personal and order-related details a secret.

    Authentic Sources

    We assure you that your document will be thoroughly checked for plagiarism and grammatical errors as we use highly authentic and licit sources.

    Moneyback Guarantee

    Still reluctant about placing an order? Our 100% Moneyback Guarantee backs you up on rare occasions where you aren’t satisfied with the writing.

    Order Tracking

    You don’t have to wait for an update for hours; you can track the progress of your order any time you want. We share the status after each step.

    image

    Areas of Expertise

    Although you can leverage our expertise for any writing task, we have a knack for creating flawless papers for the following document types.

    Areas of Expertise

    Although you can leverage our expertise for any writing task, we have a knack for creating flawless papers for the following document types.

    image

    Trusted Partner of 9650+ Students for Writing

    From brainstorming your paper's outline to perfecting its grammar, we perform every step carefully to make your paper worthy of A grade.

    Preferred Writer

    Hire your preferred writer anytime. Simply specify if you want your preferred expert to write your paper and we’ll make that happen.

    Grammar Check Report

    Get an elaborate and authentic grammar check report with your work to have the grammar goodness sealed in your document.

    One Page Summary

    You can purchase this feature if you want our writers to sum up your paper in the form of a concise and well-articulated summary.

    Plagiarism Report

    You don’t have to worry about plagiarism anymore. Get a plagiarism report to certify the uniqueness of your work.

    Free Features $66FREE

    • Most Qualified Writer $10FREE
    • Plagiarism Scan Report $10FREE
    • Unlimited Revisions $08FREE
    • Paper Formatting $05FREE
    • Cover Page $05FREE
    • Referencing & Bibliography $10FREE
    • Dedicated User Area $08FREE
    • 24/7 Order Tracking $05FREE
    • Periodic Email Alerts $05FREE
    image

    Our Services

    Join us for the best experience while seeking writing assistance in your college life. A good grade is all you need to boost up your academic excellence and we are all about it.

    • On-time Delivery
    • 24/7 Order Tracking
    • Access to Authentic Sources
    Academic Writing

    We create perfect papers according to the guidelines.

    Professional Editing

    We seamlessly edit out errors from your papers.

    Thorough Proofreading

    We thoroughly read your final draft to identify errors.

    image

    Delegate Your Challenging Writing Tasks to Experienced Professionals

    Work with ultimate peace of mind because we ensure that your academic work is our responsibility and your grades are a top concern for us!

    Check Out Our Sample Work

    Dedication. Quality. Commitment. Punctuality

    Categories
    All samples
    Essay (any type)
    Essay (any type)
    The Value of a Nursing Degree
    Undergrad. (yrs 3-4)
    Nursing
    2
    View this sample

    It May Not Be Much, but It’s Honest Work!

    Here is what we have achieved so far. These numbers are evidence that we go the extra mile to make your college journey successful.

    0+

    Happy Clients

    0+

    Words Written This Week

    0+

    Ongoing Orders

    0%

    Customer Satisfaction Rate
    image

    Process as Fine as Brewed Coffee

    We have the most intuitive and minimalistic process so that you can easily place an order. Just follow a few steps to unlock success.

    See How We Helped 9000+ Students Achieve Success

    image

    We Analyze Your Problem and Offer Customized Writing

    We understand your guidelines first before delivering any writing service. You can discuss your writing needs and we will have them evaluated by our dedicated team.

    • Clear elicitation of your requirements.
    • Customized writing as per your needs.

    We Mirror Your Guidelines to Deliver Quality Services

    We write your papers in a standardized way. We complete your work in such a way that it turns out to be a perfect description of your guidelines.

    • Proactive analysis of your writing.
    • Active communication to understand requirements.
    image
    image

    We Handle Your Writing Tasks to Ensure Excellent Grades

    We promise you excellent grades and academic excellence that you always longed for. Our writers stay in touch with you via email.

    • Thorough research and analysis for every order.
    • Deliverance of reliable writing service to improve your grades.
    Place an Order Start Chat Now
    image

    Order your essay today and save 30% with the discount code Happy